Skip to main content
Log in

Inter-regional redistribution through infrastructure investment: tactical or programmatic?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we study the political economy of the inter-regional allocation of investment in infrastructure, in an effort to disentangle tactical and programmatic motives, where tactical politics refers to the discretionary allocation of investment to districts with more ‘political clout’ and programmatic politics refers to the allocation of investment according to certain ‘objective’ criteria (e.g., income level). We use a panel of data from the Spanish electoral districts for the period 1964–2004 to estimate an equation in which investment depends both on economic and political variables. The results show that tactical politics do matter since the districts receiving the most funds are those in which: (i) the incumbent’s vote margin is low, (ii) few votes are needed to win an additional seat in the legislature, (iii) the central and regional governments are controlled by the same party, and (iv) regional parties play a pivotal role in the legislature. However, the results also show that programmatic politics matter, since inter-regional redistribution is shown to increase: (i) with the arrival of democracy and European Union funds, (ii) under leftist governments, and (iii) the weaker the correlation is between ‘political clout’ and regional income.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is also the focus of many other papers studying the political determinants of intergovernmental grants (e.g., Levitt and Snyder 1995; Case 2001; Dahlberg and Johansson 2002; Johansson 2003).

  2. The US literature on the cross-state or cross-county distribution of federal funds is considerably wider, including much more work on the New Deal (e.g., Wallis 1987; Anderson and Tollison 1991; Couch and Shughart 1998, and Strömberg 2004), disaster relief (e.g., Shughart 2006; Garrett and Sobel 2003; Boettke et al. 2007) and more recently, economic “stimulus” programs (e.g., Young and Sobel 2011).

  3. Spain operates a quasi-bipartisan system, with two main national parties, and many smaller regional parties. To date, the party obtaining the most votes in national legislative elections has been able to govern alone, be it with a parliamentary majority or not. Indeed, some minority governments have been quite strong, since the fragmentation among opposition parties meant that their votes could be bought quite cheaply. In a number of instances, the regional governments have been pivotal and thus more able to extract funds from the center.

  4. The VEC is a very flexible dynamic specification, which allows us to differentiate between short- and long-run effects and which use has become quite common among political economists (see De Boef and Keele 2008). See Solé-Ollé (2010) for an analysis of the stationarity of the dependent variable and a discussion of the appropriateness of this specification.

  5. In Spain, as elsewhere, investment is planned long before the budget year. However, plans are executed in line with each government’s fiscal decisions. It is well known that even though a project has started there might be long delays in the actual building of the infrastructure. This means that governments can influence yearly investment allocations; these are included in the budget document and, as such, are not part of the formulas that determine the allocations in many years.

  6. These results were obtained using the full sample. In the working paper version we present the non-parametric estimates and show that the results are roughly the same for the different incumbent parties involved and for all the terms analyzed (see Solé-Ollé 2010).

  7. Note that these variables are not included in all the terms-of-office, the reason being that these phenomena are specific to the periods considered (i.e., it makes little sense to speak of alignment before 1983 and there are only two terms in which pivotal regional parties have been important).

  8. See Boix (1998) for a study of the role of infrastructure investment in the ideological program of the PSOE.

References

  • Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G. M., & Tollison, R. D. (1991). Congressional influence and patterns of New Deal spending, 1933–1939. Journal of Law and Economics, 34, 161–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atlas, C. M., Gilligan, T. W., Hendershott, R. J., & Zupan, M. A. (1995). Slicing the Federal government pie: who wins, who loses and why. American Economic Review, 85, 624–629.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi, T., & Masson, P. (1995). Fiscal flows in the United States and Canada. Lessons for monetary union in Europe. European Economic Review, 39, 253–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodenstein, M., & Ursprung, H. (2005). Political yardstick competition, economic integration, and constitutional choice in a Federation. Public Choice, 124(3), 329–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P., Chamlee-Wright, E., Gordon, P., Ikeda, S., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). The political, economic, and social aspects of Katrina. Southern Economic Journal, 74(2), 363–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (1998). Political parties, growth and equality: conservative and social democratic economic strategies in the world economies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosch, N., & Espasa, M. (1999). Con qué criterios invierte el Sector Público central. In A. Castells & N. Bosch (Eds.), Desequilibrios territoriales en España y en Europa. Madrid: Ariel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosch, N., Espasa, M., & Sorribas, P. (2003). The redistributive, stabiliser and insurance effects at the territorial level of ‘Federal’ government budgets. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 21(4), 597–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cadot, O., Röller, L., & Stephan, A. (2006). Contribution to productivity or pork barrel? The two faces of infrastructure investment. Journal of Public Economics, 90(6–7), 1133–1153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, A. (2001). Election goals and income distribution: recent evidence from Albania. European Economic Review, 45, 405–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castells, A., & Solé-Ollé, A. (2005). The regional allocation of infrastructure investment: the role of equity, efficiency and political factors. European Economic Review, 49, 1165–1205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castells, A., Montolio, D., & Solé-Ollé, A. (2006). La inversión en infraestructuras en las CCAA: determinantes y cálculo de un índice de necesidades de gasto. Hacienda Pública Española/Revista de Economía Pública, 178(3), 23–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Couch, J. F., & Shughart, W. F. (1998). The political economy of the New Deal. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. (1986). Electoral politics as a redistributive game. Journal of Politics, 48(2), 379–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlberg, M., & Johansson, E. (2002). On the vote purchasing behaviour of incumbent governments. American Political Science Review, 96, 27–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Boef, S., & Keele, L. (2008). Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 184–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De La Fuente, A. (2002). On the sources of convergence: a close look at the Spanish regions. European Economic Review, 46(3), 569–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De La Fuente, A. (2004). Second-best redistribution though public investment: a characterization, an empirical test and an application to the case of Spain. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 34, 489–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De La Fuente, A., & Vives, X. (1995). Infrastructure and education as instruments of regional policy: evidence from Spain. Economic Policy, 20, 13–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denemark, D. (2000). Partisan pork barrel in parliamentary systems: Australian constituency-level grants. Journal of Politics, 62(3), 896–915.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1996). The determinants of success of special interests in redistributive politics. Journal of Politics, 58(4), 1132–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1998). Ideology, tactics, and efficiency in redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2), 497–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1974). Pork barrel politics. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, T. A., & Sobel, R. S. (2003). The political economy of FEMA disaster payments. Economic Inquiry, 41(3), 496–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hauk, W., & Wacziarg, R. (2007). Small States, big pork. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2, 95–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joanis, M. (2007). The road to power: partisan loyalty and the centralized provision of local infrastructures. Public Choice, 146(1), 17–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson, E. (2003). Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: some empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 883–915.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemmerling, A., & Stephan, A. (2002). The contribution of local public infrastructure to private productivity and its political economy: evidence from a panel of large German cities. Public Choice, 113(3–4), 403–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, B. (2002). Endogenous Federal grants and crowd-out of State government spending: theory and evidence from the Federal Highway Aid Program. American Economic Review, 92(1), 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, B. (2004). Parochial interests and the centralized provision of local public goods: evidence from congressional voting on transportation projects. Journal of Public Economics, 88(3–4), 845–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larcinese, V., Rizzo, L., & Testa, C. (2006). Allocating the U.S. Federal Budget to the States: the impact of the President. Journal of Politics, 68(2), 447–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & Snyder, J. M. (1995). Political parties and the distribution of Federal outlays. American Journal of Political Science, 39, 958–980.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52, 272–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D. (1974). Congress: the electoral connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 914–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1996). Federal fiscal constitutions: risk sharing and redistribution. Journal of Political Economy, 104(5), 979–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics. Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. (2009). Federalism and inter-regional redistribution. In N. Bosch, M. Espasa, & A. Solé-Ollé (Eds.), The political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows: measurement, determinants, and effects on country stability. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F. (2006). Katrinanomics: the politics and economics of disaster relief. Public Choice, 127(1), 31–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, J. M. (1989). Election goals and the allocation of campaign resources. Econometrica, 57, 637–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A., & Sorribas-Navarro, P. (2008). The effects of partisan alignment on the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. Difference-in-differences estimates for Spain. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 625–671.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A. (2010). Inter-regional redistribution through infrastructure investment: tactical or programmatic? IEB Working Paper 2009/32, http://www.ieb.ub.edu/.

  • Spolaore, E. (2009). Federalism, regional redistribution and country stability. In N. Bosch, M. Espasa, & A. Solé-Ollé (Eds.), The political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows: measurement, determinants, and effects on country stability Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein, R., & Bickers, K. (1994). Congressional elections and the pork barrel. Journal of Politics, 56(2), 377–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, A., & Kemmerling, A. (2009). Determinants of regional transport investment across Europe. In N. Bosch, M. Espasa, & A. Solé-Ollé (Eds.), The political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows: measurement, determinants, and effects on country stability. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strömberg, D. (2004). Radio’s impact on public spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 2004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strömberg, D. (2008). How the electoral college influences campaigns and policy: the probability of being Florida. American Economic Review, 98(3), 769–807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, J. J. (1987). Employment, politics, and economic recovery in the Great Depression. Review of Economics and Statistics, 59, 516–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wibbels, E. (2005). Decentralized governance, constitution formation, and redistribution. Constitutional Political Economy, 16(2), 161–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, G. (1974). The political economy of New Deal Spending: an econometric analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 56(1), 30–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamano, N., & Ohkawara, T. (2000). The regional allocation of public investment: efficiency or equity? Journal of Regional Science, 40(2), 205–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. T., & Sobel, R. S. (2011). Recovery and Reinvestment Act spending at the State level: Keynesian stimulus or distributive politics? Public Choice, Online first, doi:10.1007/s11127-011-9876-x.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge comments received by Jonathan Rodden, Massimo Bordignon, Vincenzo Galasso, Germà Bel, and participants at the European Public Choice Conference (Izmir, Turkey, April 2009) and at the 5th IEB Symposium on Fiscal Federalism (Barcelona, Spain, June 2008). This research has received funding from projects ECO2009-12680/ECON (Ministerio de Educación y Ciencia) and 2009SGR102 (Generalitat de Catalunya).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Albert Solé-Ollé.

Appendix

Appendix

A model of tactical redistribution

In this case, the incumbents’ problem can be written as:

(A.1)

where \(\overline{i}\) is the (exogenous) amount of resources available, i j is the per capita investment allocated to region j, and n j and e j are the population and the number of representatives of that region j in the legislature. The First Order Condition (FOC) of this problem are

(A.2)

where v j =n j F j (θ j u j ) are the number of votes obtained in j, F j being an incumbent’s vote distribution function with density f j ; u j is the utility of a resident in j, depending on per capita resident income y j , which is in turn influenced by the per resident infrastructure capital stock of the region, c j ; θ j is an indicator of the productivity of the efforts of the incumbent party in district j; and λ is the Lagrange multiplier. Now, we assume, firstly, that F j is uniform with support |−η j ,η j |. Secondly, we assume that \(u_{j}=k+((1+\varepsilon)y_{j}^{1+\varepsilon} )\), with ε≤0 to reflect diminishing marginal utility of income. Finally, we also assume that \(y_{j} = a_{j}c_{j}^{\alpha _{j}}\), with a j being a district-specific productivity shifter and α j ≥0 the coefficient of infrastructure capital in the production function. Using all this information, knowing that ∂c j /∂i j =1, and defining μ j =∂e j /∂v j , we can rewrite (B.2):

(A.3)

Now, after taking logs and rearranging, we can provide the following expression for the amount of infrastructure capital desired by the incumbent for district j:

(A.4)

where β j =lnα j −lnλ, σ=1+ε and lnψ j =lnμ j +lnθ j +lnη j .

A model ofconstitutionalprogrammatic redistribution

The incumbent allocates investment across districts to maximize the following social welfare function:

(A.5)

where n j is the population of district j. This is a Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) social welfare function that allows varying degrees of relative regional inequality aversion. The ϕ parameter quantifies the aversion to regional output inequality, and ranges from −∞ to one. As ϕ becomes more negative, inequality aversion increases. When ϕ→−∞, the function approaches pure equity. In the intermediate Cobb-Douglas case ϕ is zero. And if ϕ is equal to one, then the government is exclusively worried about efficiency. In this case, w equals the country’s aggregate utility, which is reduced to aggregate output when using the above utility function with ε=0. Note that we assume that the ϕ parameter depends on a vector of variables (ς) which pick up what we have termed as ‘constitutional’ influences on aversion to regional inequality. The FOC of (B.5) are:

(A.6)

Using the same functional forms as above for the utility and production functions, and taking logs, the expression for the desired amount of infrastructure capital for district j is:

(A.7)

A model ofelectoralprogrammatic redistribution

The constitution constrains investment allocation using a formulation such as \(i_{j} = \pi y_{j}^{\phi}\), where π is a parameter which depends on the overall amount of investment funds available (which we consider fixed) and ϕ is the ‘taste-for-redistribution’ parameter, which now is the decision variable. Taking into account the production function above, after various calculations, the effect of ϕ on y j is:

(A.8)

If we assume, for the sake of simplicity, equal productivity parameters across districts (α j =α) and instantaneous depreciation (meaning that c j =i j ), expression (B.8) reduces to παy j lny j , indicating that an increase in the efficiency orientation of public investment benefits rich regions. The incumbent’s problem can now be stated as:

(A.9)

The FOC is now

(A.10)

Setting ε=0 in the utility function, and defining the political weights Ψ j as in previous sections, the FOC in (B.10) can now be expressed as:

(A.11)

where λ =λπ/α is a constant that can be assumed to be equal to one, for ease of exposition. Expression (B.11) says that, in equilibrium, ϕ should be set in order to ensure that the resulting weights applied to the different income classes (i.e., \(1/y_{j}^{1 - \phi} \)) match the income pattern of political weights (i.e., the correlation between Ψ j and y j ). Note that as ϕ moves towards zero the weights approach inverse income (i.e., 1/y j ) while when ϕ=1 all income classes receive the same unit weight. So, if rich regions become more powerful (i.e., the correlation between Ψ j and y j increases) ϕ should rise in order to make the weights less correlated with inverse income. Following this result, the equation relating the levels of capital stock and income can be written as:

(A.12)

where ρ=corr(ψ j ,y j ) is the correlation between ‘political clout’ and per capita income.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Solé-Ollé, A. Inter-regional redistribution through infrastructure investment: tactical or programmatic?. Public Choice 156, 229–252 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9896-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9896-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation