Skip to main content
Log in

Biased beliefs and retrospective voting: why democracies choose mediocre policies

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There are two well-established empirical regularities about voters. First, they entertain systematically biased beliefs about how public policies affect economic outcomes. Second, voters vote retrospectively: they punish the incumbent for poor and reward him for good macroeconomic performance. Thus, political parties face a trade-off: offering popular yet economically harmful policies increases the chance of being elected today, but decreases the chance of re-election. We provide the first rigorous game-theoretical analysis of the trade-off. The model addresses two questions: How can biased beliefs and retrospective voting be explained consistently? What policy outcomes emerge in party competition? To micro-found persistently biased beliefs we introduce the psychological concept of mental models. Deviating from earlier studies, we allow parties to choose strategic mixtures of populist (i.e., bad yet popular) and good (but less popular) platforms. We show that retrospective voting provides a self-correction mechanism, so that parties offer strategic mixtures of policies in equilibrium rather than purely populist or purely good policy platforms. Thus, democracy is characterized by mediocre policy choices and half-hearted reforms. An incumbent bias or unclear responsibilities weaken the self-correction mechanism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Terms like cognitive maps, folks theory or naive theory refer to the same basic concept (e.g., Dutke 1994: 12).

  2. Schofield (2004) points at the fact that Israel’s military is a powerful group. Arguably, Ariel Scharon was considered a competent politician because his links to the military allowed him to make commitments in negotiations with Palestinian representatives that are more credible than commitments of politicians lacking these links.

  3. Borgonovi et al. (2010) find a positive link between years of schooling and information acquisition on politics and current affairs. In democracy, in turn, the level of schooling is comparatively high (Helliwell 1994; Barro 1996: 12). This supports the notion that the level of politically relevant information among voters in democracies is generally sufficient to differentiate between poor and good economic results.

  4. In the policy vector each row represents a certain policy field and the value of η t in this row states which policy instrument is applied. For instance, one row could represent personal income taxation and the value of η t in this row states whether the current government applies a dual income tax, or some other concept. Another row may represent wage policy and the value states whether or not there is a minimum wage.

  5. This can be backed with at least three arguments: (i) election t+2 is located eight to ten years in the future where party leaders are likely to have lost their leading position; (ii) given the VP function literature, the next terms’ policy is unlikely to significantly determine the valence perceptions of the voters in t+2; (iii) the incumbent in some democracies, for instance the U.S. President, loses power after two terms due to term limits.

References

  • Achen, C. H., & Bartels, L. M. (2004). Blind retrospection: electoral responses to droughts, flu, and shark attacks. UCLA Working Paper 2004/199.

  • Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2000). Valence politics and equilibrium in spatial election models. Public Choice, 103(1–2), 327–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aragonès, E., Palfrey, T., & Postlewaite, A. (2007). Political reputations and campaign promises. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(4), 846–884.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1996). Democracy and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beilharz, H.-J. (2005). Democracy, crises, and misconceptions. Ruprecht-Karls-University at Heidelberg. http://www.ub.uni-heidelberg.de/archiv/6140/, accessed July 17, 2008.

  • Beilharz, H.-J., & Gersbach, H. (2004). General equilibrium effects and voting into a crisis. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4454. London.

  • Bischoff, I. (2007). Mentale Modelle, politisches Lernen und demokratische Wirtschaftspolitik. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.

  • Borgonovi, F., d’Hombres, B., & Hoskins, B. (2010). Voter turnout, information acquisition and education: evidence from 15 European countries. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 10, 1 (Contributions), Article 90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruter, M., Erikson, R. S., & Strauss, A. B. (2010). Uncertain candidates, valence, and the dynamics of candidate position-taking. Public Choice, 144(1), 153–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter. Why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, J., & Goren, A. (2007). Cognitive dissonance theory. In R. F. Baumeister & K. D. Vohs (Eds.), Encyclopedia of social psychology 1 (pp. 149–153). Los Angeles: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Kleer, J., & Brown, J. S. (1983). Assumptions and ambiguities in mechanistic mental models. In D. Gentner & A. Stevens (Eds.), Mental models (pp. 155–191). Hillsdale: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. T., & North, D. C. (1994). Shared mental models: ideologies and institutions. Kyklos, 47, 3–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiSessa, A. (1982). Unlearning Aristotelian physics: a study of knowledge-based learning. Cognitive Science, 6, 37–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doyle, J. K., & Ford, D. N. (1998). Mental models concepts for system dynamic research. System Dynamics Review, 14, 3–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutke, S. (1994). Mentale Modelle: Konstrukte des Wissens und Verstehens. Göttingen: Verlag für die Angewandte Psychologie.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J. M., & Hinich, M. J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (2005). Designing democracy—ideas for better rules. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (2004). Competition of politicians for incentive contracts and elections. Public Choice, 121, 157–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H., & Liessem, V. (2008). Reelection thresholds in politics. Social Choice and Welfare, 31(2), 233–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. W., McManus, I. C., & Derrick, B. J. (1998). Cognitive structural models of unemployment and employment. British Journal of Social Psychology, 37, 415–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. (2001). A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 862–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healy, A. J., Malhotra, N., & Mo, C. H. (2010). Irrelevant events affect voters’ evaluation of governmental performance. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107(29), 12804–12809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. F. (1994). Empirical linkages between democracy and economic growth. British Journal of Political Science, 24(2), 225–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson-Laird, P. N. (1983). Mental models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, D. R. (2000). Economic retrospective voting and incentives for policy-making. Electoral Studies, 19(2–3), 427–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Legrenzi, P., & Girotto, V. (1996). Mental models in reasoning and decision making processes. In J. Oakhill & A. Garnham (Eds.), Mental models in cognitive science (pp. 95–118). Hove: Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leigh, A. (2009). Does the world economy swing national elections? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(2), 163–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiser, D., & Drori, S. (2005). Naive understanding of inflation. Journal of Socio-Economics, 34, 179–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiser, D., Azar, O. H., & Hadar, L. (2008). Psychological construal of economic behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 29(5), 762–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liessem, V. (2008). Electoral competition, incentive contracts for politicians and unknown preferences. Social Choice and Welfare, 30(1), 13–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, A. H., & Wattenberg, M. P. (1985). Throwing the rascals out: policy and performance evaluations of presidential candidates, 1952–1980. American Political Science Review, 79(2), 359–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, M. (2007). Motivation of politicians and long-term policies. Public Choice, 132(3–4), 273–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nannestad, P., & Paldam, M. (1994). The VP-function: a survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years. Public Choice, 79, 213–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oden, G. C. (1987). Concept, knowledge, and thought. Annual Review of Psychology, 38, 203–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, M. (2004). Are vote and popularity functions economically correct? In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The Encyclopedia of Public Choice 1 (pp. 49–59). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pennington, N., & Hastie, R. (1993). Reasoning in explanation-based decision making. Cognition, 49, 123–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rinne, H. (2003). Taschenbuch der Statistik (3rd ed.). Frankfurt am Main: Harri Deutsch Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, D. (2003). Misconceptions and political outcomes. Economic Journal, 113(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (2004). Equilibrium in spatial valence models of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16, 447–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F. II, & Tollison, R. D. (2005). Public Choice in the new century. Public Choice, 124(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. A. II, & Razzolini, L. (Eds.) (2001). The Elgar companion to Public Choice. Cheltenham: Edgar Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stehn, S. J., & Fedelino, A. (2009). Fiscal incentive effects of the German equalization system. IMF Working Paper 09/124. Washington: IMF.

  • Stokes, D. E. (1963). Spatial models of party competition. American Political Science Review, 57, 368–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokes, D. E. (1992). Valence politics. In D. Kavanagh (Ed.), Electoral politics (pp. 141–162). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swank, O., & Eisinga, R. (1999). Economic outcomes and voting behaviour in a multi-party system: an application to the Netherlands. Public Choice, 101, 195–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tetlock, P. E. (1989). Structure and function in political belief systems. In A. R. Pratkanis, S. J. Breckler, & A. G. Greenwald (Eds.), Attitude structure and function (pp. 129–151). Hillsdale: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tetlock, P. E. (1999). Theory-driven reasoning about plausible pasts and probable futures in world politics: are we prisoners of our preconceptions? American Journal of Political Science, 43(2), 335–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zakharov, A. V. (2009). A model of candidate location with endogenous valence. Public Choice, 138(3–4), 347–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank John Ashworth, Pierre-Guillaume Méon, Jochen Michaelis, Markus Müller, Richard Pepper, Eva Söbbeke, James Vreeland, the participants of the 2008 and 2009 Annual Meetings of the EPCS in Jena and Athens, the 2009 Annual Congress of the European Economic Association (EEA) in Barcelona, the 2009 Annual Meeting of the Verein für Socialpolitik in Magdeburg as well as of the 2008 Beyond Basic Questions (BBQ) Conference in Göttingen and two anonymous referees for very helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ivo Bischoff.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Based on (20) the first-order condition for the optimal choice of \(\beta_{1}^{A}\) is given by:

(24)

It follows:

(25)

Therefore, \(\beta_{1}^{A} = 0\) if f<δv(1+2v 0)/(1+2δv) and \(\beta_{1}^{A} = 1\) iffδv(1+2v 0)/(1−2δv). For the optimal choice of party B we simply have to substitute \(+ v_{0}^{j} = + v_{0}^{A}\) for \(+ v_{0}^{B} = - v_{0}^{A} <0\) in (20). Therefore, \(\beta_{1}^{B} = \frac{1}{2} +\frac{1}{4} \cdot\bigl[ \frac{f - \delta v( 1 - 2v_{0}^{A} )}{f\delta v} \bigr]\) with \(\beta_{1}^{B} = 0\) if f<δv(1−2v 0)/(1+2δv) and \(\beta_{1}^{B} = 1\) if fδv(1−2v 0)/(1−2δv). □

Lemma A.1

Assume a discrete number of n voters with an identical probability of voting for party j in period t given by \(\pi_{it}^{j} = \varPi_{t}^{j} = p\), for all i=1,…,n. Then, function M(Π t ) is very well approximated by:

(26)

Proof of Lemma A.1 by simulation

Assuming identical probabilities, and knowing that a party will only be the incumbent when at least n/2+1 voters support the party, we use the Bernoulli distribution (Rinne 2003: 253) to obtain as conditional vote share:

(27)

It is possible to derive the first and second derivative for M(p). Yet, the resulting expressions do not allow for a general conclusion with respect to their sign. We simulated the function and its first and second derivative for p=0 to p=1 applying n=1 000 000. Plotting the simulation results (Fig. 1) we obtain a figure depicting a functional form very close to Eq. (26). This result holds for realistic values for the number of eligible voters n.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Simulated form of (a) M(p), given by (27), and (b) the corresponding M′(p) (for n=1 000 000)

 □

Proof of Proposition 2

Based on (21) the first-order condition for the optimal choice of \(\beta_{1}^{A}\) is given by:

(28)

where \(\varepsilon_{M( x_{t} ),x_{t}}\) is the elasticity of function M(⋅) at location x t ={Π t ,1−Π t }. The Implicit Function Theorem applied to (28) reveals

(29)

where A represents \(\frac{\partial \varTheta _{t}^{A}( \cdot )}{\partial \beta _{t}^{A}}\) in the optimum, that is, where A=0. We obtain:

(30)

While the sign of the nominator of (29) is clearly positive, the sign of the denominator is open a priori. Applying Lemma A.1 in (21), it is easy to show that:

(31)

Analogously, we obtain the same expression for party B, with the only difference that the term with \(v_{0}^{A}\) has an opposite sign. Comparing (31) and (25), it turns out that with incumbent bias ρ Inc the expression increases for both parties by \(\frac{1}{4}\frac{\rho}{v}\) if the party is expecting to lose the election (\(\varPi_{t} < \frac{1}{2}\)), or even by \(\frac{1}{2}\frac{\rho}{v}\) if the party expects to win (\(\varPi_{t}\ge\frac{1}{2}\)). Consequently, we obtain \(\frac{\partial \beta _{t}^{j}}{\partial \rho ^{\mathit{Inc}}} > 0\). □

Proof of Proposition 3

Using (23) we get \(\frac{\partial \beta _{t}^{A}}{\partial k} = \frac{1}{4} \cdot[ 4\delta v \cdot E( \beta^{\mathit{ex}}) - 1 - 2\delta v ] \cdot\frac{1}{\delta vk^{2}}\). Thus,

(32)

Given that δ<1 and v<1/2, the latter restriction is fulfilled by definition. Next, we can deduce \(\frac{\partial \beta _{t}^{A}}{\partial E( \beta ^{\mathit{ex}} )} = - ( \frac{1 - k}{k} ) < 0\), for all 0<k<1. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bischoff, I., Siemers, LH.R. Biased beliefs and retrospective voting: why democracies choose mediocre policies. Public Choice 156, 163–180 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9889-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9889-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation