Skip to main content
Log in

Under pressure: community water systems in the United States—a production model with water quality and organization type effects

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the interaction of productive efficiency, water quality and organizational type. A water quality index is constructed employing various contaminants which are then treated together with variables including organizational type as endogenous in an input distance function model. The cost of drinking water quality and inefficiency are derived and hypothesis tests estimated concerning their variation by location, organization type and water quality. The key findings are that more technically efficient water utilities deliver higher quality drinking water and that private firms distribute higher quality water at a higher price and at a higher implicit cost than public utilities despite no overall inefficiency differences between the two organizational types.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other examples of these indexes are found in Färe et al. (2010), air pollution; Freeman et al. (2008), water quality.

  2. Nitrate results from fertilizer use runoff, and leaking from septic tanks and sewage as well as erosion of natural deposits. Infants below 6 months of age who drink water containing nitrate concentrations above the MCL could face serious illness, such as the so-called blue baby syndrome (very rare), and if untreated could die. Turbidity measures water cloudiness, and it results mainly from soil runoff. A high level of turbidity points to micro-organisms that can cause stomach problems and headaches. Chlorine employed to control microbes in drinking water, can cause eyes and nose irritation and stomach discomfort. Long-term exposure to total trihalomethanes (TTHMs), a drinking water disinfection byproduct, above MCL results in a potential increase in cancer risk, as well as in kidney, liver and central nervous system problems (EPA 2013).

  3. This short run cost function corresponds to that employed by Morrison (1999) to characterize short run and long run dynamics.

  4. This follows Coelli et al. (2008).

  5. See Christensen et al. (1973).

  6. Destandau and Garcia S (2014) have a forthcoming article also uses 1996 AWWA data.

  7. The author consulted energy sources employed by CWSs with AWWA engineers.

  8. Refer to http://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/state/ (EIA-861).

  9. This will produce a bias measure of capital if a firm is not earning a zero or "normal profit" and/or if it is not using capital in a cost minimizing ratio with other inputs. This bias could be significant given the large number of public firms.

  10. For the primary, enforceable, and secondary list, offered as guidance, of contaminants that EPA regulates or recommends see http://water.epa.gov/drink/contaminants/index.cfm#List.

  11. The limitation of this approach is that the firm, as noted by Morrison (1999), does “revalue its capital stock.” In addition, consistency with the distance function assumptions, would involved an observed price of capital and a shadow quantity.

References

  • Abbasi T, Abbasi SA (2012) Water quality indices. Elsevier, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson SE, Dorfman JH (2005) Bayesian measurement of productivity and efficiency in the presence of undesirable outputs: crediting electric utilities for reducing air pollution. J Econom 126:445–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson SE, Primont D (2002) Stochastic estimation of firm technology, inefficiency, and productivity growth using shadow cost and distance functions. J Econom 108:203–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aubert C, Reynaud A (2005) The impact of regulation on cost efficiency: an empirical analysis of Wisconsin water utilities. J Prod Anal 23(3):383–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Averch H, Johnson LL (1962) Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. Am Econ Rev 52(5):1052–1069

    Google Scholar 

  • AWWA (1996) WATER:/STATS: the water utility database. AWWA, Denver

    Google Scholar 

  • Balk BM, Färe R, Grosskopf S (2004) The theory of economic price and quantity indicators. Econ Theory 23(1):149–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battese GE, Coelli TJ (1992) Frontier production functions, technical efficiency and panel data: with application to paddy farmers in India. J Prod Anal 3:153–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battese GE, Coelli TJ (1995) A model for technical inefficiency effects in a stochastic frontier production function for panel data. Empir Econ 20(2):325–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battese GE, Corra G (1977) Estimation of a production frontier model with application to the pastoral zone of eastern Australia. Aust J Agric Econ 21:167–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya A, Parker E, Raffiee K (1994) An examination of the effect of ownership on the relative efficiency of public and private water utilities. Land Econ 70(2):197–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya A, Harris TR, Narayanan R, Raffiee K (1995) Specification and estimation of the effect of ownership on the economic efficiency of the water utilities. Reg Sci Urban Econ 25:759–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrnes P, Grosskopf S, Hayes K (1986) Efficiency and ownership: further evidence. Rev Econ Stat 68(2):337–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves DW, Christensen LR (1980) Global properties of flexible functional forms. Am Econ Rev 70(3):422–432

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves DW, Christensen LR, Swanson JA (1981) Productivity growth, scale economies, and capacity utilization in U.S. railroads, 1955–74. Am Econ Rev 71(5):994–1002

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiang AC (1984) Fundamental methods of mathematical economics, 3rd edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen LR, Jorgenson DW, Lau LJ (1973) Transcendental logarithmic production frontiers. Rev Econ Stat 55(1):28–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli TJ (1996) A guide to FRONTIER version 4.1: a computer program for frontier production function estimation. CEPA Working Paper 96/07, Department of Econometrics, University of New England, Armidale, Australia

  • Coelli TJ, Estache A, Perelman S, Trujillo L (2003) A primer on efficiency measurement for utilities and transport regulators. World Bank Institute, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Coelli TJ, Hajargasht G, Lovell CAK (2008) Econometric estimation of an input distance function in a system of equations. No. WP01/2008. Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis. St Lucia, Queensland, Australia

  • Crittenden J et al (2005) Water treatment: principles and design, 2nd edn. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • del Rodriguez-Alvarez A, Rosal I, Baños-Pino J (2007) The cost of strikes in the Spanish mining sector: modeling an undesirable input with a distance function. J Prod Anal 27(1):73–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebenstein A (2012) The consequences of industrialization: evidence from water pollution and digestive cancers in China. Rev Econ Stat 94(1):186–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EIA (2013) Average price by state by provider (EIA-861). http://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/state/. Accessed 24 March 2013

  • Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) (2013) Drinking water contaminants. http://water.epa.gov/drink/contaminants/index.cfm. Accessed 24 March 2013

  • Estache A, Rossi M (2002) How different is the efficiency of public and private water companies in Asia. World Bank Econ Rev 16(1):139–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-Output production and duality: theory and applications. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Margaritis D (2008) Efficiency and productivity and more. In: Fried HO, Lovell CAK, Schmidt SS (eds) The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity growth. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 522–622

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Pasurka C (2010) Toxic releases: an environmental performance index for coal-fired power plants. Energy Econ 32(1):158–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faust AK, Baranzani A (2014) The economic performance of Swiss drinking water utilities. J Prod Anal 41(3):383–397

  • Feigenbaum S, Teeples R (1983) Public versus private water delivery: a hedonic cost approach. Rev Econ Stat 65:672–678

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman J, Madsen R, Hart K (2008) Statistical analysis of drinking water treatment plant costs, source water quality, and land cover characteristics. Trust for Public Land white paper. http://www.forestsforwatersheds.org/forests-and-drinking-water/. 24 March 2013

  • Garcia S, Thomas A (2001) The structure of municipal water supply costs: application to a panel of French local communities. J Prod Anal 16(1):5–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2008) The econometric approach to efficiency analysis. In: Fried HO, Lovell CAK, Schmidt SS (eds) The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity growth. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 92–250

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gross AC, Richardson MB (2003) Water treatment chemicals. Bus Econ 38(2):61–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez RG, Carter S, Drukker DM (2001) On boundary-value likelihood-ratio tests. In: Stata Technical Bulletin. Stata Press, College Station, TX, pp 15–18

  • Hailu A, Veeman TS (2000) Environmentally sensitive productivity analysis of the canadian pulp and paper industry, 1959–1994: an input distance function approach. J Environ Econ Manag 40(3):251–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris R, Marston F, Mishra D, O’Brien T (2003) Ex Ante cost of equity estimates of S&P 500 firms: the choice between global and domestic CAPM. Financ Manag 32(3):51–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmes TP (1988) The offsite impact of soil erosion on the water treatment industry. Land Econ 64:356–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan PD, Peterson JD (1998) Full-information industry betas. Financ Manag 27(2):85–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Lovell CAK (2000) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Landwehr JM (1979) A statiscal view of a class of water quality indices. Water Resour Res 15(2):460–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrison CJ (1999) Scale economy measures and subequilibrium impacts. J Prod Anal 11(1):55–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pestieau P, Tulkens H (1993) Assessing and explaining the performance of public enterprises. Finanz Arch 50(3):293–323

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME (1991) America’s green strategy. Scientific American, April

  • Saal D, Parker D, Weyman-Jones T (2007) Determining the contribution of technical change, efficiency change and scale change to productivity growth in the privatized English and Welsh water and sewerage industry: 1985–2000. J Prod Anal 28(1–2):127–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt P, Lovell CAK (1979) Estimating technical and allocative inefficiency relative to stochastic production and cost frontiers. J Econom 9(3):343–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shephard R (1953) Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Souza G, Faria R, Moreira T (2008) Efficiency of Brazilian public and private water utilities. Estud Econ (São Paulo) [online] 38(4):905–917

    Google Scholar 

  • Teeples RK, Glyer D (1987) Cost of water delivery systems: specification and ownership effects. Rev Econ Stat 69(3):399–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zivin JG, Neidell M, Schlenker W (2011) Water quality violations and avoidance behavior: evidence from bottled water consumption. Am Econ Rev 101(3):448–453

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank the editor and four referees for their advice with this article. In addition, I would like to thank Knox Lovell, Rolf Färe and Robert Russell for their feedback, and Laura Moore for her editorial and other help. All remaining mistakes are my responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Roberto Mosheim.

Additional information

The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Economic Research Service or the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Appendix

Appendix

Following Caves et al. (1981) and Atkinson and Primont (2002), scale economies for a short run distance function is derived by assuming the existence of the short run transformation function:

$$ F(\ln Y_{1} , \ldots ,\ln Y_{m} ,\ln X_{1} , \ldots ,\ln X_{n - q} ,\ln Z_{n - q + 1} , \ldots ,\ln Z_{q} ,t) = 1 $$
(40)

where Y i are outputs; X i , inputs; Z i , quasifixed inputs and t represents time. The total differential is:

$$ \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{m} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Y_{i} }}d\ln Y_{i} } + \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n - q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln X_{i} }}d\ln X_{i} + \sum\limits_{i = n - q + 1}^{q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Z_{i} }}d\ln Z_{i} + } \frac{\partial F}{\partial t}} dt = 0. $$
(41)

For dt = 0, it follows that:

$$ \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{m} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Y_{i} }}d\ln Y_{i} } + \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n - q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln X_{i} }}d\ln X_{i} + \sum\limits_{i = n - q + 1}^{q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Z_{i} }}d\ln Z_{i} } } = 0. $$
(42)
$$ \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{m} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Y_{i} }}d\ln Y_{i} } = - \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n - q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln X_{i} }}d\ln X_{i} - \sum\limits_{i = n - q + 1}^{q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Z_{i} }}d\ln Z_{i} } } $$
(43)

Applying rule III of differentials in (Chiang 1984):

$$ \frac{{d\ln Y_{i} }}{{(d\ln X_{i} + d\ln Z_{i} )}} = - \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n - q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln X_{i} }}} + \sum\nolimits_{i = n - q + 1}^{q} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Z_{i} }}} }}{{\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{m} {\frac{\partial F}{{\partial \ln Y_{i} }}} }} = RTS^{R} $$
(44)

This expression for scale economies following Caves et al. (1981, pp. 995–996) is defined as the proportional increase in all outputs resulting from the proportional increase in all variable inputs holding time fixed and conditional on the levels of the quasifixed inputs.

Using the duality of the variable cost function, \( VC = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n - q} {W_{i} X_{i} } , \) with (44) by substituting Eqs. (8a), (8b) and (9) into equation (11) of Caves et al. (1981) in p. 996, Eq. (44) can also be derived [see also the scale elasticity expression, Eqs. (8a), (8b), where the Z variable represents fixed capital, in Garcia and Thomas (2001, p. 15):

$$ SCE = \left.\left( 1 - \sum\nolimits_{{i = n - q + 1}}^{q} \partial\ln VC / {\ln Z_{i} } \right)\right/ {\sum\nolimits_{{i = 1}}^{m}{{{\partial \ln VC}/{\ln Y_{i} }}} }=- \frac{ {\sum\nolimits_{{i =1}}^{{n - q}} {\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial \ln X_{i} }}} }\left/{\sum\nolimits_{{i = 1}}^{{n - q}} {\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial\ln X_{i} }}} } \right. + {\sum\nolimits_{{i = n - q + 1}}^{q}{\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial \ln Z_{i} }}} } \left/{\sum\nolimits_{{i = 1}}^{{n - q}} {\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial\ln X_{i} }}} } \right. } { {\sum\nolimits_{{i= 1}}^{m} {\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial \ln Y_{i} }}} } \left/{\sum\nolimits_{{i = 1}}^{{n - q}} {\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial\ln X_{i} }}} } \right.} $$
(45)

In terms of distance functions (Atkinson and Primont 2002) Eq. (45) becomes:

$$ RTS^{R} = - \frac{{1 + \sum\nolimits_{i = n - q + 1}^{q} {\frac{{\partial \ln D^{I} }}{{\partial \ln Z_{i} }}} }}{{\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{m} {\frac{{\partial \ln D^{I} }}{{\partial \ln Y_{i} }}} }} $$
(46)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mosheim, R. Under pressure: community water systems in the United States—a production model with water quality and organization type effects. J Prod Anal 42, 277–292 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0406-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0406-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation