Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Efficiency analysis in the presence of uncertainty

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a stochastic decision environment, differences in information can lead rational decision makers facing the same stochastic technology and the same markets to make different production choices. Efficiency and productivity measurement in such a setting can be seriously and systematically biased by the manner in which the stochastic technology is represented. For example, conventional production frontiers implicitly impose the restriction that information differences have no effect on the way risk-neutral decision makers utilize the same input bundle. The result is that rational and efficient ex ante production choices can be mistakenly characterized as inefficient—informational differences are mistaken for differences in technical efficiency. This paper uses simulation methods to illustrate the type and magnitude of empirical errors that can emerge in efficiency analysis as a result of overly restrictive representations of production technologies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. More precisely, they are intended to represent nonstochastic frontiers. Banker (1993) has shown how the imposition of proper distributional assumptions on inefficiency yields a statistical interpretation of DEA models.

  2. In particular, Ω can be either finite or infinite. In practice, the only change in what follows is in terms of the derivative concepts used.

  3. As Chambers and Quiggin (2004) point out, this condition holds for any individual who strictly prefers more 0 period income to less, more period 1 income to less, and faces a financial market in which there exists a riskless asset. Therefore, as a practical matter it is more general than the net-returns formulation might suggest.

  4. This presumes, of course, that individuals formulate unique probability measures. It is well recognized that otherwise rational individuals can behave as though they are not probabilistically sophisticated.

  5. This condition may also be described by saying that the cost function is generalized Schur-concave with respect to the probability vector (0.75, 0.25).

  6. We take 10 to be the highest plausible level of relative risk aversion. However, some researchers view levels of relative risk aversion as plausible if they lie in the range 1–4. These researchers would characterize 5 as extremely risk averse.

  7. Strictly speaking, the term ‘predictor’ should be used if inferences are being drawn using a random effects stochastic frontier model. In that case, the object of inference (firm efficiency) is a random variable, not a parameter. However, for simplicity, we use the term ‘estimator’ in both contexts.

  8. All results were generated using the SHAZAM software. The monotonicity constraint was not binding for these 25 data points. However, in a simulation experiment reported later in this section, the monotonicity constraint was binding in approximately 15% of replications.

  9. That firm will also have an input-oriented DEA efficiency score of \( 0.5x^{-1}<1.\)

  10. We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this discussion to us.

References

  • Arrow K (1953) Le rôle des valeurs boursiers pour la repartition la meillure des risques. 53. CNRS, Paris. Cahiers du Seminair d’Economie

  • Banker RD (1993) Maximum likelihood, consistency and data envelopment analysis: a statistical foundation. Manag Sci 39(10):1265–1273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers RG, Quiggin J (1998) Cost functions and duality for stochastic technologies. Am J Agric Econ 80:288–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers RG, Quiggin J (2000) Uncertainty, production, choice and agency: the state-contingent approach. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Chavas JP (2008) A cost approach to economic analysis under state-contingent production uncertainty. Am J Agric Econ 90:435–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battese GE, Rambaldi AN, Wan GH (1997) A Stochastic frontier production function with flexible risk properties. J Prod Anal 8:269–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli TJ, Rao DSP, O’Donnell CJ, Battese GE (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis, 2nd edn. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G (1952) A social equilibrium existence theorem. Proc Natl Acad Sci 38:86–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doran H (1993) Testing nonnested models. Am J Agric Econ 75(1):95–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK (1994) Production frontiers. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gong L, Sun B (1995) Efficiency measurement of production operations under uncertainty. Int J Prod Econ 39:55–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene W (2002) Alternative panel data estimators for stochastic frontier models. NYU Stern School of Business Department of Economics Working Paper.

  • Greene W (2004) Distinguishing between heterogeneity and inefficiency: stochastic frontier analysis of the World Health Organization’s panel data on national health care systems. Health Econ 13(10):959–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardy G, Littlewood J, Pólya G (1934) Inequalities. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC (2002) Specification and estimation of production risk, risk preferences and technical efficiency. Am J Agric Econ 84(1):8–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Lovell CAK (2000) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Land KC, Lovell CAK, Thore S, (1994) Chance constrained data envelopment analysis. Manag Decis Econ 14:541–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nauges C, O’Donnell C, Quiggin J (2009) Uncertainty and technical efficiency in Finnish agriculture. Risk and Sustainable Management Group, University of Queensland

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell CJ, Griffiths WE (2006) Estimating state-contingent production frontiers. Am J Agric Econ 88(1):249–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olesen OB, Petersen NC (1995) Chance constrained efficiency evaluation. Manag Sci 41:442–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Post T, Cherchye L, Kuosmanen T (2002) Nonparametric efficiency measurement in stochastic environments. Oper Res 50:645–655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell AA, Gruen FH (1967) The estimation of production frontiers: the Australian livestock/cereals complex. Aust J Agric Econ 11(1):63–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Savage LJ (1954) Foundations of statistics. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Earlier versions of this paper have been presented at several conferences and seminars. We would like to thank all participants, as well as the editors and reviewers of this Journal, for their contributions to our work.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert G. Chambers.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

O’Donnell, C.J., Chambers, R.G. & Quiggin, J. Efficiency analysis in the presence of uncertainty. J Prod Anal 33, 1–17 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-009-0143-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-009-0143-9

Keywords

JEL Classifiaction

Navigation