Skip to main content
Log in

Uncovered Interest Parity and Monetary Policy Near and Far from the Zero Lower Bound

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Relying upon a standard New Keynesian DSGE, we propose an explanation for two empirical findings in the international finance literature. First, the unbiasedness hypothesis — the proposition that expost exchange rate depreciation matches interest differentials — is rejected much more strongly at short horizons than at long. Second, even at long horizons, the unbiasedness hypothesis tends to be rejected when one of the currencies has experienced a long period of low interest rates, such as in Japan and Switzerland. Using a calibrated New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, we show how a monetary policy rule can induce the negative (positive) correlation between depreciation and interest differentials at short (long) horizons. The tendency to reject unbiasedness for Japan and Switzerland even at long horizons we attribute to the interaction of the monetary reaction function and the zero lower bound.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Similar results are cited in surveys by Macdonald and Taylor (1992) and Isard (1995). Meese and Rogoff (1983) show that the forward rate is outpredicted by a random walk, which is consistent with the failure of the unbiasedness hypothesis.

  2. Flood and Rose (1996, 2002) note that including currency crises and devaluations, one finds more evidence for the unbiasedness hypothesis.

  3. There is an alternative approach that involves using survey-based data to measure exchange rate expectations. Chinn and Frankel (1994) document that it is difficult to reject UIP for a broad set of currencies when using survey based forecasts. Similar results are obtained by Chinn (2014), when extending the data up to 2009. These results echo early findings by Froot and Frankel (1989). While we do not pursue this avenue in this paper (long horizon expectations being difficult to obtain), it is useful to recall these findings when interpreting rejections of the joint hypothesis of UIP and rational expectations.

  4. In order to simplify the notation, variables without a k-index are used to refer to the small open economy being modeled. i.e., the Home country. Variables with a k ∈ [0, 1] subscript refer to economy k other than the Home country, one among the continuum of economies making up the world economy. Finally, variables with an asterisk superscript * correspond to the world economy as a whole.

  5. For conciseness, in this paper we only specify technology for the Home country.

  6. The home country is of measure zero.

  7. See Galí and Monacelli (2005) for derivation.

  8. We can also match the moments for other macroeconomic variables; e.g., output by imposing habit persistence structure. We do not impose such structure because it brings unnecessary complication without helping us understand the nature of ZLB.

  9. Following Chinn and Meredith (2004), Chinn and Quayyum (2013).

  10. Both the depreciation rate and the interest rate are expressed at annual rate.

  11. Because of symmetry, 𝜃 and ξ do not enter the VAR system in Section 3.11. Hence we do not specify their values in Table 2. We will discuss \(\bar {i}\) in Section 6, when the interest rate is near ZLB.

  12. In those graphs, i_2 refers to interest rate with 6-month (2-quarter) maturity. ds_2 refers to depreciation rate over two quarters. Similar definitions apply for other variables.

  13. For conciseness, we do not include IRFs for all horizons.

  14. From Fig. 3, it is straightforward to see \(\frac {\partial (i_{t}-i_{t}^{*})}{\partial e_{it}}std(e_{it})= 0.004\). Since std(e i t ) = 0.02, it is straightforward to see \(c_{1}=\frac {\partial (i_{t}-i_{t}^{*})}{\partial e_{it}}= 0.2\).

  15. Figures 6 and 9 show \(\frac {\partial (i_{t}-i_{t}^{*})}{\partial e_{ct}}std(e_{ct})= 0.0039\) and \(\frac {\partial (i_{t}-i_{t}^{*})}{\partial e_{mt}}std(e_{mt})=-0.000131826\). Since std(e c t ) = std(e m t ) = 0.002, we have \(c_{2}=\frac {\partial (i_{t}-i_{t}^{*})}{\partial e_{ct}}= 1.95\) and \(c_{3}=\frac {\partial (i_{t}-i_{t}^{*})}{\partial e_{mt}}=-0.0655\).

  16. Note in our simulation, the depreciation rate and interest rate are quarterly rate, i.e., percent per quarter. Hence, variances derived from Eqs. (44) and (45) should be multiplied by 16 to compare with the empirical moments in Table 1.

  17. N is the horizon/maturity of the long term bond.

  18. A common mistake is to write the solution as \(i_{t}-i_{t}^{*}=max\{0,c_{1}u_{it}+c_{2}u_{ct}+c_{3}u_{mt}\}\) and \(E_{t}s_{t + 1}-s_{t}=i_{t}-i_{t}^{*}-u_{it}\). This is wrong because it does not take into account the fact that the households are able to anticipate ZLB ahead of time. Actually, a closed-form solution does not exist when the interest rate is near ZLB.

  19. The so-defined \(\bar {i}\) also includes other constants omitted by log-linearization. Hence it does not necessarily equal \(\frac {1}{\beta }-1\). For conciseness, it is still referred to as “the steady state level of i t ”.

  20. Since our model has a complete asset market (see Section 3.5), this budget constraint is an abbreviated version. We only use (63) to derive the IS curve. In fact, the household is subject to a complete set of assets against all sorts of risks.

  21. If such an Arrow security does not exist, we can always construct an identical portfolio from existing assets. This is guaranteed by the definition of complete asset markets.

References

  • Alexius A (2001) Uncovered interest parity revisited. Rev Int Econ 9(3):505–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alexius A, Sellin P (2012) Exchange rates and long term bonds. Scand J Econ 114(3):974–990

    Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R, Dahlquist M (2000) The forward premium puzzle: different tales from developed and emerging economies. J Int Econ 51:115–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braun RA, Körber LM (2011) New keynesian dynamics in a low interest rate environment. J Econ Dyn Control 35:2213–2227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA (1983) Staggered prices in a Utility-Maximizing framework. J Monet Econ 12:383–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chinn MD (2014) (Almost) A quarter century of currency expectations data: interest rate parity and the risk premium. Unpublished working paper

  • Chinn MD, Frankel JA (1994) Patterns in exchange rate forecasts for 25 currencies. J Money Credit Bank 26(4):759–770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chinn MD, Meredith G (2004) Monetary policy and Long-Horizon uncovered interest parity. IMF Staff Pap 51(3):409–430

    Google Scholar 

  • Chinn MD, Quayyum S (2013) Long horizon uncovered interest parity re-assessed. Unpublished working paper

  • Engel C (2015) Exchange rates and interest parity. In: Handbook of international economics, vol 4. Elsevier, North Holland, pp 453–522

  • Erceg C, Lindé J (2014) Is there a fiscal free lunch in a liquidity trap?. J Eur Econ Assoc 12(1):73–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama E (1984) Forward and spot exchange rate. J Monet Econ 14:319–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flood RP, Rose AK (1996) Fixes: of the forward discount puzzle. Rev Econ Stat 78(4):748–752

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flood RP, Rose AK (2002) Uncovered interest parity in crisis. IMF Staff Pap 49:252–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Flood RP, Taylor MP (1997) Exchange rate economics: what’s wrong with the conventional macro approach?. In: The microstructure of foreign exchange markets. U.Chicago for NBER, Chicago, pp 262–301

  • Frankel JA, Poonawala J (2010) The forward market in emerging currencies: Less biased than in major currencies. J Int Money Financ 29(3):585–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froot KA, Frankel JA (1989) Forward discount bias: is it an exchange risk premium?. Q J Econ 104(1):139–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froot KA, Thaler RH (1990) Foreign exchange. J Econ Perspect 4 (3):(Summer) 179–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J (2008) Monetary policy, inflation and the business cycle: an introduction to the new keynesian framework. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, Monacelli T (2005) Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Rev Econ Stud 72:707–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holden T, Paetz M (2012) Efficient simulation of DSGE models with inequality constraints. Unpublished working paper

  • Isard P (1995) Exchange rate economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Macdonald R, Taylor MP (1992) Exchange rate economics: a survey. IMF Staff Pap 39(1):1–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum BT (1994) A reconsideration of the uncovered interest parity relationship. J Monet Econ 33:105–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meese R, Rogoff K (1983) Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: do they fit out of sample?. J Int Econ 14:3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez DA (2005) Inflation dynamics in Japan: the calvo model and wage rigidity. Unpublished working paper

  • Walsh CE (2010) Monetary theory and policy. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yi Zhang.

Additional information

We thank Charles Engel, Kenneth D. West, Kurt G. Lunsford, and Chenxin Liu for helpful comments, and faculty research funds of the University of Wisconsin for financial support. All remaining errors are solely our responsibility.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Households

Consumption preferences in the Home economy are described by the following composite index of domestic and imported bundles of goods:

$$ C_{t}\equiv[(1-\gamma)^{\frac{1}{a}}({C_{t}^{h}})^{\frac{a-1}{a}}+\gamma^{\frac{1}{a}}({C_{t}^{f}})^{\frac{a-1}{a}}]^{\frac{a}{a-1}} $$
(49)

where a > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between domestically produced and imported goods. \({C_{t}^{h}}\) (and \({C_{t}^{f}}\)) are Dixit-Stiglitz aggregates of domestically produced and imported goods.

$$ {C_{t}^{h}}\equiv\left[{\int}_{0}^{1}{C_{t}^{h}}(j)^{\frac{\theta-1}{\theta}}dj\right]^{\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}} $$
(50)

where j ∈ [0,1] denotes the good variety. \({C_{t}^{f}}\) is an index of imported goods given by

$$ {C_{t}^{f}}\equiv\left[{\int}_{0}^{1}\left( C_{k,t}\right)^{\frac{\xi-1}{\xi}}dk\right]^{\frac{\xi}{\xi-1}} $$
(51)

where Ck,t is, in turn, an index of the quantity of goods imported from country k and consumed by domestic households. It is given by an analogous CES function

$$ C_{k,t}\equiv\left[{\int}_{0}^{1}C_{k,t}(j)^{\frac{\theta-1}{\theta}}dj\right]^{\frac{\theta}{\theta-1}} $$
(52)

The optimal allocation of any given expenditure within each category of goods yields the demand functions

$$ {C_{t}^{h}}(j)=\left[\frac{{P_{t}^{h}}(j)}{{P_{t}^{h}}}\right]^{-\theta}{C_{t}^{h}} $$
(53)
$$ C_{k,t}(j)=\left[\frac{P_{k,t}(j)}{P_{k,t}}\right]^{-\theta}C_{k,t} $$
(54)

for all j,k ∈ [0,1], where \({P_{t}^{h}}\) is the Home price index (i.e., the index of prices of domestically produced goods) defined as

$$ {P_{t}^{h}}\equiv\left[{\int}_{0}^{1}{P_{t}^{h}}(j)^{1-\theta}dj\right]^{\frac{1}{1-\theta}} $$
(55)

and Pk,t is a price index for goods imported from country k (expressed in Home currency) for all k ∈ [0,1]

$$ P_{k,t}\equiv\left[{\int}_{0}^{1}P_{k,t}(j)^{1-\theta}dj\right]^{\frac{1}{1-\theta}} $$
(56)

We derive the price index for imported goods (also expressed in Home currency)

$$ {P_{t}^{f}}\equiv\left[{\int}_{0}^{1}P_{k,t}^{1-\xi}dk\right]^{\frac{1}{1-\xi}} $$
(57)

The Home households’s relative demand for \({C_{t}^{h}}\) and \({C_{t}^{f}}\) depends on their relative prices \({P_{t}^{h}}\) and \({P_{t}^{f}}\). It is easy to derive:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {C_{t}^{h}}&=&(1-\gamma)(\frac{{P_{t}^{h}}}{{P_{t}^{c}}})^{-a}C_{t} \end{array} $$
(58)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {C_{t}^{f}}&=&\gamma(\frac{{P_{t}^{f}}}{{P_{t}^{c}}})^{-a}C_{t} \end{array} $$
(59)

where \({P_{t}^{c}}\) is the composite consumer price index defined as

$$ {P_{t}^{c}}\equiv[(1-\gamma)({P_{t}^{h}})^{1-a}+\gamma({P_{t}^{f}})^{1-a}]^{\frac{1}{1-a}} $$
(60)

The representative household maximizes the following expected discounted sum of utilities over possible paths of consumption and labor:

$$ E_{0}\{\sum\limits_{t = 0}^{\infty}\beta^{t} U(C_{t},N_{t})\} $$
(61)

where the period utility is defined as

$$ U(C_{t},N_{t})=\frac{C_{t}^{1-\sigma}}{1-\sigma}-\frac{N_{t}^{1+\eta}}{1+\eta} $$
(62)

By considering the optimal expenditure conditions (58) and (59), the sequence of budget constraints assumes the following form:

$$ C_{t}+B_{t}=\frac{{P_{t}^{h}}}{{P_{t}^{c}}}Y_{t}+B_{t-1}\frac{1+i_{t-1}}{1+{\pi_{t}^{c}}}+T_{t} $$
(63)

where B t is the bond holdings of representative home household,Footnote 20 and T t is the lump-sum profit transfer from the firms.

The representative household chooses processes \(\{C_{t},N_{t}\}_{t = 0}^{\infty }\) and asset portfolio to maximize (61) subject to (63). For any given state of the world, the following set of efficiency conditions must hold:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} C_{t}^{-\sigma}&=&\beta E_{t}[(1+i_{t})(\frac{{P_{t}^{c}}}{P_{t + 1}^{c}})C_{t + 1}^{-\sigma}] \end{array} $$
(64)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{N_{t}^{\eta}}{C_{t}^{-\sigma}}&=&\frac{W_{t}}{{P_{t}^{c}}} \end{array} $$
(65)

Equation (64) takes the form of a familiar consumption Euler equation. Notice that following large part of the recent literature, we do not introduce money explicitly.

1.2 A.2 Asset Markets

The household is subject to a complete set of assets against all sorts of risks. For any state s of the economy at Period t + 1, there exists a corresponding Arrow security with price v t that pays one unit of Home currency in period t + 1 if and only if state s occurs.Footnote 21

Assume state s occurs with probability τ(s). Then for the Home households, intertemporal substitution yields:

$$ \frac{v_{t}U^{\prime}(C_{t})}{{P_{t}^{c}}}=\frac{\beta U^{\prime}(C_{t + 1}(s))\tau(s)}{P_{t + 1}^{c}(s)} $$
(66)

where s in the parentheses means it is state dependent.

Substituting U(⋅) with its functional form, and a little tranformation, we can get

$$ \beta\left[\frac{C_{t + 1}(s)^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{-\sigma}}\cdot\frac{{P_{t}^{c}}}{P_{t + 1}^{c}(s)}\right]=\frac{v_{t}}{\tau(s)} $$
(67)

The foreign households also have access to this Arrow security, and their intertemporal substitution yields:

$$ \frac{v_{t}U^{\prime}(C_{t}^{*})}{S_{t}P_{t}^{*}}=\frac{\beta U^{\prime}(C_{t + 1}^{*}(s))\tau(s)}{S_{t + 1}(s)P_{t + 1}^{*}(s)} $$
(68)

That is,

$$ \beta\left[\frac{C_{t + 1}^{*}(s)^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{*-\sigma}}\cdot\frac{S_{t}P_{t}^{*}}{S_{t + 1}(s)P_{t + 1}^{*}(s)}\right]=\frac{v_{t}}{\tau(s)} $$
(69)

i.e.,

$$ \beta\left[\frac{C_{t + 1}^{*}(s)^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{*-\sigma}}\cdot\frac{Q_{t}}{Q_{t + 1}(s)}\cdot\frac{{P_{t}^{c}}}{P_{t + 1}^{c}(s)}\right]=\frac{v_{t}}{\tau(s)} $$
(70)

Comparing (67) and (70), we can get

$$ \frac{C_{t + 1}(s)^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{-\sigma}}=\frac{C_{t + 1}^{*}(s)^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{*-\sigma}}\cdot\frac{Q_{t}}{Q_{t + 1}(s)} $$
(71)

i.e.,

$$ \frac{C_{t + 1}(s)^{-\sigma}}{C_{t + 1}^{*}(s)^{-\sigma}}Q_{t + 1}(s)=\frac{C_{t}^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{*-\sigma}}Q_{t} $$
(72)

The right hand side of the above equation is independent of state s, hence for any state s, we must have

$$ \frac{C_{t + 1}^{-\sigma}}{C_{t + 1}^{*-\sigma}}Q_{t + 1}=\frac{C_{t}^{-\sigma}}{C_{t}^{*-\sigma}}Q_{t} $$
(73)

This equation indicates \(\frac {C_{t}^{-\sigma }}{C_{t}^{*-\sigma }}Q_{t}\) is a constant for any t. For convenience, normalize this constant to be unity. This is consistent with a symmetric initial condition with zero net foreign asset holdings. Hence we get

$$ C_{t}=Q_{t}^{\frac{1}{\sigma}}C_{t}^{*} $$
(74)

and its log-linearized version

$$ c_{t}=c_{t}^{*}+\left( \frac{1}{\sigma}\right)q_{t}=c_{t}^{*}+\left( \frac{1-\gamma}{\sigma}\right)\delta_{t} $$
(75)

The last equation employs the fact that

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} q_{t}&=&s_{t}+p_{t}^{*}-{p_{t}^{c}}\\ &=&(s_{t}+p_{t}^{*}-{p_{t}^{h}})+({p_{t}^{h}}-{p_{t}^{c}})\\ &=&\delta_{t}+({p_{t}^{h}}-{p_{t}^{c}})\\ &=&\delta_{t}-\gamma\delta_{t}\\ &=&(1-\gamma)\delta_{t} \end{array} $$
(76)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chinn, M.D., Zhang, Y. Uncovered Interest Parity and Monetary Policy Near and Far from the Zero Lower Bound. Open Econ Rev 29, 1–30 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9474-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9474-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation