Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Productivity, Trade, and Relative Prices in a Ricardian World

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In an extended Ricardian model of trade, we study the effects of improving trade deficits on relative prices, and the relation between productivity improvements and real exchange rates. An improvement in the trade balance induces relative wages to overshoot their long-run value, placing downward pressure on the terms of trade of the same order of magnitude found in Armington type models. Once the pattern of specialization changes, some of the decline is reversed with a smaller value of depreciation. We find that persistent productivity differentials do not cause distinct trends in the terms of trade. The result depends on the size of the non-tradable sector and the variability of industry-specific efficiencies. We also find that self-selection into export markets causes the relative price of non-tradable goods to respond to exogenous shift, giving birth to an endogenous Balassa-Samuelson effect. The model also suggests that in the long-run the variation of the real exchange rate is dominated by the volatility of the terms of trade.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995), Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2004), Galstyan and Lane (2007), Obstfeld and Rogoff (2007), Galstyan (2014).

  2. See Krugman (1989), Galstyan and Lane (2008), Corsetti et al. (2013).

  3. See Hummels and Klenow (2005), Debaere and Lee (2003).

  4. An endogenous tradable sector eliminates this result.

  5. These authors also find important welfare implications associated with the long-term adjustment process. Similarly, Choudhri and Marasco (2013) study welfare gains from openness in a monopolistic-competition model with heterogeneous productivity.

  6. For any variable x appearing directly in the text we use exp[x] = e x.

  7. The same expression can be derived if one combines the cut-off condition for the foreign specialization pattern with Eq. 6

  8. Our estimations of T s for different time periods reveal a relatively stable pattern of absolute advantage. For this reason we do not consider movements in T s.

  9. It is important to mention that throughout the text we deal with average price levels as defined in the text. These are different from the prices, where the increased availability of goods drives down the price index due to the love for variety effect. See for instance Feenstra (1994), Broda and Weinstein (2006), Galstyan and Lane (2008), Corsetti et al. (2013) to mention a few.

  10. We have also constructed the real exchange rate based on GDP deflators. The response of this exchange rate is similar to the response of the CPI based real exchange rate. For this reason the GDP deflator based real exchange rate has been omitted from the text.

  11. To show this, use the relative productivity schedule A(z) to substitute for a h (i) in the average productivity of the non-tradable sector, then integrate. The rest follows from the definition of relative prices.

  12. See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996).

  13. Leftward shifts would require re-writing the formulas.

  14. Using equations (1a) and (1b) from Table 1 we explicitly solve for z h in terms of z f . Substituting this solution into equation (2a) and combining the latter with the equilibrium condition (1b) we derive a non-linear equation with one endogenous variable, z f . The equation is then solved numerically using the Newton–Raphson procedure. Finally, z h and relative wage rate (equal to B(z) in equilibrium) are then easily calculated.

  15. The aggregate trade share of the countries is 83 %. The set of countries with normalized trade weights in parentheses includes Canada (17.9), Japan (15.3), Mexico (14.1), Germany (8.2), China (8.0), United Kingdom (5.5), Korea, Rep. (4.6), France (4.5), Italy (3.3), Singapore (2.3), Malaysia (2.1), Brazil (2.1), Netherlands (1.9), Belgium (1.6), Thailand (1.5), Australia (1.3), Spain (1.2), Sweden (1.1), India (1.0), Austria (0.6), Finland (0.5), Denmark (0.5), Norway (0.3), Portugal (0.3), New Zealand (0.3), and Greece (0.2).

  16. The data are taken from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators.

  17. This is regardless of the value of μ.

  18. They estimate the parameters equal to 3.6, 8.28 and 12.9. The estimates vary with data and methodology of estimation.

  19. We have also tried μ = 3.7 and d fh  = d hf  = 2.2. The results are very similar.

  20. The self-selection result is in line with the findings of Ghironi and Melitz (2003), but these authors do not analyze trade re-balancing.

  21. These results are similar to the ones obtained by Obstfeld and Rogoff (2007) in a specialization by origin model.

  22. In this static framework welfare change is equivalent to a change in per capita consumption.

  23. Acemoglu and Ventura (2002) find some support for the thesis that faster growing countries experience worsening terms of trade.

  24. Recently Ceglowski (2014) has estimated long-run income elasticity of US imports and found evidence of parameter instability.

  25. It should be mentioned that the 45° line does not hold in this model.

  26. The same effect works in a model of endogenous varieties. When the fixed cost is modeled in terms of labour, both wages and the terms of trade decline. When the fixed cost is modeled in terms of output, wages rise while the unit labour requirement declines. The composite effect is unaltered terms of trade. See Appendix A for details.

  27. Authors calculations based on BACI (Base pour l’Analyse du Commerce International) and KILM (Key Indicators of the Labour Market) data.

  28. Alternatively, one can introduce demand side shifts directly into the model. See Galstyan and Lane (2009).

  29. No doubt, this will “over-fit” the scatter-plot.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Ventura J (2002) The World Income Distribution. Q J Econ 117:659–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson J, van Wincoop E (2004) Trade Costs. J Econ Lit 42:691–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armington P (1969) A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production. IMF Staff Pap 16:159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Lee J, Jayanthi S (2005) New Rates from New Weights. IMF Working Paper No. 05/99

  • Benigno G, Thoenissen C (2003) Equilibrium Exchange Rate and Supply-Side Performance. Econ J 113:103–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergin P (2006) How Well Can the New Open Economy Macroeconomics Explain the Exchange Rate and Current Account? J Int Money Financ 25:675–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broda C, Weinstein D (2006) Globalization and the Gains from Variety. Q J Econ 121:541–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceglowski J (2014) Has Trade Become More Responsive to Income? Assessing the Evidence for U. S. Imports. Open Econ Rev 25:225–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choudhri E, Marasco A (2013) Heterogeneous Productivity and the Gains From Trade and FDI. Open Econ Rev 24:339–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Martin P, Pesenti P (2013) Varieties and the Transfer Problem. J Int Econ 89:1–12

  • Debaere P, Lee H (2003) The Real-Side Determinants of Countries’ Terms of Trade: A Panel Data Analysis. mimeo, University of Texas.

  • Dekle R, Eaton J, Kortum S (2007a) Unblanced Trade. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 97:351–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekle R, Eaton J, Kortum S (2007b) Unblanced Trade. NBER Working Paper 13035.

  • Dornbusch R, Fischer S, Samuelson P (1977) Comparative Advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods. Am Econ Rev 67:823–839

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton J, Kortum S (2002) Technology, Geography and Trade. Econometrica 70:1741–1779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C (1999) Accounting for U.S. Real Exchange Rate Changes. J Polit Econ 107:507–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R (1994) New Product Varieties and the Measurement of International Prices. Am Econ Rev 84:157–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Galstyan V (2014) Country Size and the Transfer Effect. Economica forthcoming.

  • Galstyan V, Lane P (2008) External Imbalances and the Extensive Margin of Trade. Econ Notes 37:241–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galstyan V, Lane P (2009) The Composition of Government Spending and the Real Exchange Rate. J Money Credit Bank 41:1233–1249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghironi F, Melitz M (2005) International Trade and Macroeconomic Dynamic With Heterogenous Firms. Q J Econ 120:865–915

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D, Klenow P (2005) The Variety and Quality of a Nation’s Exports. Am Econ Rev 95:704–723

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker H, Magee S (1969) Income and Price Elasticities in World Trade. Rev of Econ Stat 51:111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1989) Differences in Income Elasticities and Trends in Real Exchange Rates. Eur Econ Rev 33:1031–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane P, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2004) The Transfer Problem Revisited: Net Foreign Assets and Real Exchange Rates. Rev Econ Stat 86:841–857

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (1995) The Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account. In: Grossman G, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3. Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (1996) Foundations of International Macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (2007) The Unsustainable US Current Account Position Revisited. In: Clarida R (ed) G7 Current Account Imbalances: Sustainability and Adjustment. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1954) The Transfer Problem and Transport Costs, II: Analysis of Effects of Trade Impediments. Econ J 64:264–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Philip Lane, Kevin O’Rourke, Michael Wycherley, the editor and the referee for helpful comments. I gratefully acknowledge the feedback received from the Trinity International Macroeconomics Group and TCD Economics Graduate Seminar. Adnan Velic provided excellent research assistance. E-mail: v.galstyan@tcd.ie.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vahagn Galstyan.

Appendix: Increasing returns, productivity and the terms of trade

Appendix: Increasing returns, productivity and the terms of trade

There are two countries, Home and Foreign. The number of goods produced in the world is endogenously determined. The representative agent in country k maximizes the utility function \( {C}_k={\left({\displaystyle {\sum}_z}{c}_k^{\frac{\eta -1}{\eta }}(z)\right)}^{\frac{\eta }{\eta -1}} \). The domestic agent’s demand for a Home produced good i is c h (i) = (p h (i)/P h )− η C h , while the demand for a Foreign produced good j is c h (j) = (p h (j)/P h )− η C h . Similar demand equations are derived for the foreign agent.

There exists a pool of firms that can produce and export. To produce, a potential entrant must incur fixed costs. Output is produced using labor as the only input in production: y k (z) = A k (L k (z) − α k ). Under these assumptions, the monopolist charges a price that is marked-up over the marginal cost of production: p k (z) = η(η − 1)− 1 w k A − 1 k , where w and A denote wages and productivity respectively.

The zero-profit condition pins down output per firm, y k (z) = α k A k (η − 1). Moreover, equilibrium in the labor market identifies the number of firms producing in domestic and foreign countries, n k  = L k (α k η)− 1. Finally, equilibrium in the goods market identifies relative wages, ω = (A h /A f )1 − η(α h /α f )− η. The terms of trade is then given by τ = ω(A h /A f )− 1.

Higher productivity raises average output per firm, leaving the number of firms unaltered. Following a hike in domestic productivity, wages decline by more than the fall in the relative unit labour requirement. The composite effect is a decline in relative marginal costs, and a deterioration in the terms of trade.

If fixed costs take a form of output instead of labour (that is α k  = β k /A k in the above), then higher domestic productivity increases the number of firms, leaving output per firm unaffected: y k (z) = β k (η − 1), n k  = A k L k (ηβ k )− 1. Rising productivity increases relative wages by the same amount, ω = (A h /A f )(β h /β f )− η. Furthermore, the unit labour requirement declines by the same magnitude. As a result, the terms of trade does not deteriorate: τ = (β h /β f )− η.

The addition of a non-tradable sector will influence the results as inter-sectoral labor reallocation will also tend to affect relative wages.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Galstyan, V. Productivity, Trade, and Relative Prices in a Ricardian World. Open Econ Rev 26, 817–838 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-014-9340-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-014-9340-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation