Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Does Incapacitation Reduce Crime?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Criminology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Questions and answers about incapacitation abound in all discussions about criminal justice policy. They are among the most pressing of all research issues, yet estimates about the incapacitation effect on crime vary considerably, and most are based on very old and incomplete estimates of the longitudinal pattern of criminal careers. This paper provides an overview of the incapacitation issue, highlights information on recent estimates of criminal careers that are useful to the incapacitation model, and outlines an ambitious research agenda for continued and expanded work on incapacitation and crime that centers on developing better estimates of the characteristics of criminal careers and their relevance to policy choices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Because neither approach inherently dominates the other, the combined use of both approaches is likely to be more useful (Zimring and Hawkins 1995).

  2. I can be thought of as the percentage increase in crime that would result if all offenders (or all offenders of a certain type) were released. Also, I must be adjusted downwards to account for the fact that, when co-offenders commit a crime, imprisoning both will only save one offense (Weatherburn et al. 2006, p. 3).

  3. E also has to be adjusted for co-offending.

  4. To be sure, criminologists have spent considerable effort tracking individual patterns of offending by many other offenders over the life course, using a number of recent and important methodological advances. We return to this point later.

  5. The high and low estimates of the average resulted from applying two different consistency standards to classify unreliable estimates.

  6. Texas had a much higher rate of imprisonment so that high-rate offenders made up a larger proportion of the California prison population than of the Texas prison population. California’s estimates are so high because they are a function of the relatively low level of imprisonment; Texas mixes in a greater number of low-rate offenders; but there is a phenomenon of diminishing marginal returns: as long as most high-rate offenders are already in prison, then offenders at the margin of imprisonment will have much lower average crime rates than those already in prison (Zimring and Hawkins 1988, p. 432).

  7. Greenberg (1990) also noted that Zedlewski overestimated the benefits of imprisonment because he assumed the estimate of 187 crimes was true for everyone, when in fact, it should have pertained only to that fraction of the subject population that reported committing the particular felonies under consideration. Yet, 53.3% of the prison inmates said that they had not committed any of those crimes (these inmates had committed crimes that were not among those listed). Thus, according to Greenberg, the appropriate mean offense rate for the prison sample is not 187 offenses per year, but (187)(0.467) = 87.3 property offenses per year (see also Rolph and Chaiken 1987).

  8. Using official arrest rates, Blumstein and Cohen (1979, p. 582) found λ for index crimes to be 13.2, while Cohen (1983) provided an estimate of 8.7 and Greenberg an estimate of 3. Shinnar and Shinnar reported a λ between 6 and 14 for reported crimes. These estimates are smaller than those from self-reports because of the survey instrument used, the assumptions underlying calculations of arrest probabilities, and the sample differences.

  9. The problem is that a sample of inmates arriving in prison is likely to display a higher mean frequency of offending than is the population of all offenders. Zedlewski used the λ estimates derived from prisoner samples to represent offending by unincarcerated offenders without recognition of the potentially severe distortion that introduces. Especially in light of the high skewness of the λ distribution, high-λ offenders distort the mean considerably, and since these individuals are a much smaller fraction of the total population of offenders, it is misleading to use the mean λ of prisoners to represent the mean for the total population of offenders.

  10. This is a specific example where knowledge about individual offending careers can help understand the potential impact of incarceration policies.

  11. The incapacitation model also has a number of other important input quantities including the probability of being apprehended and convicted, the probability of receiving a prison sentence, and the average time spent in prison. While information on incarceration given arrest is likely easier to obtain, information on individual estimates of risk of arrest per offense committed does not exist, within offenders, over time, and by crime type. Longitudinal studies with data on both self-reports of crime and of arrest are needed for such an assessment.

  12. A related point concerns the assumption that career length is exponentially distributed. There has been only very limited work concerning the extent to which career lengths do in fact follow an exponential distribution.

  13. This raises another caution about using aggregate data to arrive at incapacitation estimates because the probability of arrest varies across crime type and jurisdictions (and over time) as does the probability of incarceration which is constrained by local jail and prison conditions (Cohen 1986, p. 409). For example, Spelman (2000a, pp. 473–476) shows that states differ considerably in the strategies they pursue. Some states incarcerate a small proportion of their offenders but do so for long terms, while other states incarcerate more offenders for shorter terms (Spelman 2000a, p. 473). Moreover, states may alter these strategies and decisions over time, by making selections to give prison sentences differentially according to crime type. As Blumstein et al. (1986, pp. 148–149) show, not only do crime rates and prison use vary by states and over time, but so too does the probability of prison given crime, and the median time served in prison. These, of course, influence the cost/benefit ratios from incapacitation and yield different elasticity estimates.

  14. It should also be recognized that λ is not merely a scalar value, but a vector representing the offending frequency over a mixture of crime types. If one took it over six crime types (murder, robbery, rape, assault, burglary, and larceny), one would cover over three quarters of the non-drug offenders in US prisons. We have omitted drug offenses here because we recognize that their incapacitation effect is likely to be nullified through the recruitment of replacements in the community.

  15. In their critique of the incapacitation approach, the main issue raised by Miles and Ludwig is that it offers no useful information to policymakers because of “insurmountable” practical and conceptual problems. They argue that the primary policy implication of the measurement of λ is selective incapacitation, and that even if estimates of λ accurately identified the highest risk offenders with sufficient speed to permit the justice system to prevent the commission of crimes, λ estimates would still have limited use to decision-makers because few criminal justice policies have selective incapacitation as their goal. They fail to acknowledge that incapacitation research is focused largely on “collective incapacitation” and has largely ignored selective incapacitation, recognizing that “stochastic selectivity” achieves many of the same goals without incurring the problems. Noting that criminal justice policies include deterrence and replacement in addition to incapacitation, they conclude that micro-parameter estimates are unlikely to provide useful guides about the combined effects of deterrence, incapacitation, and replacement effects from a particular change, since the bundle of effects produced is likely to be specific to the policy change in question. A single estimate of λ would provide incomplete and potentially even misleading information for policymakers forced to choose among these different policy options. Policy is not typically driven by any single value of λ, but rather a range and by the insights derived from the various relevant parameters. Additionally, Miles and Ludwig write as if policymakers are more likely to consider and adopt information from the aggregate approach. They claim that the aggregate approach is straightforward and ultimately more useful to criminal justice policymakers because it encourages lawmakers to consider changes in sanction policy to look for rigorous evaluations of the net effects of similar policy changes implemented in other jurisdictions. But experience with policymakers makes it clear that they do not want “take-it-or-leave-it” parameter estimates; rather, they need the insights that derive from a complex area of research. Further, Miles and Ludwig make it seem as if a policymaker would adopt the econometric approach and resultant estimates because they are based on a single policy experiment, but they do not fully appreciate that what may work in one jurisdiction may not work in another. On this score, recall that results from the original domestic experiment in Minneapolis showed that arrest deterred subsequent domestic violence. In the six replications that followed however, arrest deterred in certain jurisdictions but backfired in others, and the effect of arrest was contingent on particular offender characteristics. Given that policy experiments of the sort advocated by Miles and Ludwig are likely to have particular effects in particular jurisdictions, because each jurisdiction has a unique makeup of crime types and offender characteristics, it is unclear how the aggregate level information will be any more influential or better than micro-level information.

References

  • Avi-Itzhak B, Shinnar R (1973) Quantitative models in crime control. J Criminal Justice 1:185–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blokland AAJ, Nagin DS, Nieuwbeerta P (2005) Life span offending trajectories of a Dutch conviction cohort. Criminology 43:919–954

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A (1983) Incapacitation. In: Kadish SH (ed) Encyclopedia of crime and justice, vol 3. The Free Press, New York, pp 873–880

    Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A (1993) Making rationality relevant – the American society of criminology presidential address. Criminology 31:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A (2005) An overview of the symposium and some next steps. Annal Am Acad Political Soc Sci 602:242–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A, Beck AJ (2000) Population growth in US prisons, 1980–1996. In: Tonry M, Petersilia J (eds) Crime and justice: a review of research 26:17–62

  • Blumstein A, Beck AJ (2005) Reentry as a transient state between liberty and recommitment. In: Travis J, Visher C (eds) Prisoner reentry and crime in America. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A, Cohen J (1979) Estimation of individual crime rates from arrest records. J Criminal Law Criminol 70:561–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A, Cohen J, Hsieh P (1982) The duration of adult criminal careers. (Final report submitted to National Institute of Justice). Carnegie-Mellon University School of Urban and Public Affairs, Pittsburgh, PA

  • Blumstein A, Cohen J, Roth JA, Visher CA (eds) (1986) Criminal careers and career criminals, vol 1. National Academy Press, Washington, DC

  • Brame R, Fagan J, Piquero AR, Schubert CA, Steinberg L (2004) Criminal careers of serious delinquents in two cities. Youth Violence Juvenile Justice 2:256–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canela-Cacho JA, Blumstein A, Cohen J (1997) Relationship between the offending frequency (λ) of imprisoned and free offenders. Criminology 35:133–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaiken JM, Chaiken MR (1982) Varieties of criminal behavior. Rand, Santa Monica, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen J (1978) The incapacitative effect of imprisonment: a critical review of the literature. In: Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin DS (eds) Deterrence and incapacitation: estimating the effects of criminal sanctions on crime rates. National Academy Press, Washington, DC, pp 187–243

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen J (1983) Incapacitation as a strategy for crime control: possibilities and pitfalls. In: Tonry M, Morris N (eds) Crime and justice: an annual review of research, vol 5. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 1–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen J (1986) Research on criminal careers: individual frequency rates and offense seriousness. In: Blumstein A, Cohen J, Roth JA, Visher CA (eds) Criminal careers and career criminals, vol 1. National Academy Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook PJ (1986) Criminal incapacitation effects considered in an adaptive choice framework. In: Cornish DB, Clarke RV (eds) The reasoning criminal: rational choice perspectives on offending. Springer-Verlag, New York, pp 202–216

    Google Scholar 

  • DiIulio JJ Jr, Piehl AM (1991) Does prison pay? The stormy national debate over the cost-effectiveness of imprisonment. Brookings Rev 9(4):28–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Donohue JJ, Siegelman P (1998) Allocating resources among prisons and social programs in the battle against crime. J Legal Stud 27:1–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • English K, Mande MJ (1992) Measuring crime rates of prisoners, final report, NCJ 142430. United States Department of Justice, National Institute of Justice, Washington, DC

  • Greene MA, Stollmack S (1981) Estimating the number of criminals. In: Fox JA (ed) Models in quantitative criminology. Academic Press, New York, pp 1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg DF (1975) The incapacitative effect of imprisonment: some estimates. Law Soc Rev 9:541–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg DF (1990) The cost-benefit analysis of imprisonment. Soc Justice 17:49–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood PW (1982) Selective incapacitation. Rand, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Haapanen RA (1990) Selective incapacitation and the serious offender: a longitudinal study of criminal career patterns. Springer-Verlag, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Horney J, Marshall IH (1991) Measuring lambda through self-reports. Criminology 29:471–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kazemian L, Farrington DP (2006) Exploring residual career length and residual number of offenses for two generations of repeat offenders. J Res Crime Delinquency 43:89–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kruttschnitt C, Gartner R (2005) Making time in the golden state: women’s imprisonment in California. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Laub JH, Sampson RJ (2003) Shared beginnings, divergent lives: delinquent boys to age 70. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD (1996) The effect of prison population size on crime rates: evidence from prison overcrowding litigation. Quart J Econ 111:319–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loeber R, Snyder HN (1990) Rate of offending in juvenile careers: findings of constancy and change in lambda. Criminology 28:97–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marvell TB, Moody CE Jr (1994) Prison population growth and crime reduction. J Quant Criminol 10:109–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauer M (1999) The crisis of the young African American male and the criminal justice system. The Sentencing Project, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Miranne AC, Geerken MR (1991) The New Orleans inmate survey: a test of Greenwood’s predictive scale. Criminology 29:497–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miles T, Ludwig J (2007) The silence of the lambdas: deterring incapacitation research. J Quant Criminol, this issue

  • Mulvey EP, Steinberg L, Fagan J, Cauffman E, Piquero AR, Chassin L, Knight G, Brame R, Schubert C, Hecker T, Lasoya S (2004) Theory and research on desistance from antisocial activity among serious juvenile offenders. Youth Violence Juvenile Justice 2:213–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Institute of Justice (2000) Departing thoughts from an NIJ Director. National Institute of Justice Journal, 243 (April) 1–8

  • Petersilia J, Greenwood PW, Lavin M (1978) Criminal careers of habitual felons. Rand, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersilia J, Braiker HB, Polich SM (1980) Doing crime: a survey of California prison inmates. Rand, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersilia J, Chaiken J, Ebener P, Honig P (1981) Survey of prison and jail inmates: background and method. Rand, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Piehl AM, DiIulio JJ Jr (1995) Does prison pay revisited. Brookings Rev Winter:21–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Piquero AR, Paternoster R, Mazerolle P, Brame R, Dean CW (1999) Onset age and offense specialization. J Res Crime Delinquency 36:275–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero AR, Blumstein A, Farrington DP (2003) The criminal career paradigm. In: Tonry M (ed) Crime and justice: a review of research, vol 30. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 359–506

    Google Scholar 

  • Piquero AR, Brame R, Lynam D (2004) Studying the factors related to career length. Crime Delinquency 50:412–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero AR, Farrington DP, Blumstein A (2007) Key issues in criminal careers research: new analyses from the Cambridge study in delinquent development. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pogarsky G, Piquero AR (2003) Why punishment may encourage offending and lower perceived sanction threats: investigating the resetting and selection explanations. J Res Crime Delinquency 40:95–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pogarsky G, Piquero AR, Paternoster R (2004) Modeling change and perceptions about sanction threats: the neglected linkage in deterrence theory. J Quant Criminol 20:343–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reiss AJ Jr (1980) Understanding changes in crime rates. In: Feinberg SE, Reiss AJ Jr (eds) Indicators of crime and justice. Bureau of Justice Statistics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Rolph JE, Chaiken JM (1987) Identifying high-rate serious criminals from official records. Rand, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossmo DK, Routledge R (1990) Estimating the size of criminal populations. J Quant Criminol 6:293–314

    Google Scholar 

  • Shinnar S, Shinnar R (1975) The effects of the criminal justice system on the control of crime: a quantitative approach. Law Soc Rev 9:581–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith DW (2006) Do batters learn during a game? Baseball Res J 50–52

  • Spelman W (1994) Criminal incapacitation. Plenum, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Spelman W (2000a) What recent studies do (and don’t) tell us about imprisonment and crime. In: Tonry M (ed) Crime and justice: an annual review of research, vol 27. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, pp 419–494

    Google Scholar 

  • Spelman W (2000b) The limited importance of prison expansion. In: Blumstein A, Wallman J (eds) The crime drop in America. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 97–129

    Google Scholar 

  • Tillman R (1987) The size of the ‘Criminal Population’: the prevalence and incidence of adult arrest. Criminology 25:561–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tonry M (1995) Malign neglect. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Visher CA (1986) Rand inmate survey: a re-analysis. In: Blumstein A, Cohen J, Roth JA, Visher CA (eds) Criminal careers and “Career Criminals”, vol 2. National Academy Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Visher CA (1987) Incapacitation and crime control: does a “lock ‘em up’” strategy reduce crime? Justice Quart 4:513–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weatherburn D, Hua J, Moffatt S (2006) How much crime does prison stop? The incapacitation effect of prison on burglary. Crime and Justice Bulletin (Number 93). New South Wales Bureau of Crime Statistics and Research. Sydney, Australia

  • Zedlewski EW (1985) When have we punished enough? Public Administr Rev November:771–779

  • Zedlewski EW (1987) Making confinement decisions. Research in brief. National Institute of Justice, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimring FE, Hawkins G (1988) The new mathematics of imprisonment. Crime Delinquency 34:425–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimring FE, Hawkins G (1995) Incapacitation. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alex R. Piquero.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Piquero, A.R., Blumstein, A. Does Incapacitation Reduce Crime?. J Quant Criminol 23, 267–285 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-007-9030-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-007-9030-6

Keywords

Navigation