Skip to main content
Log in

On the political economics of tax reforms: survey and empirical assessment

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Political constraints and incentives are the true driver of tax reforms. This paper reviews the political economics literature on personal income tax systems and reforms to see how political mechanisms help explain tax reforms. We take some of the implications of these theories to the data using LABREF, a database that identifies labor tax reforms in the European Union for the period 2000–2007, and control for economic and labor market factors. We find that political variables carry more weight than economic variables, and we show empirical regularities that support political economy theories. We also find that governments tended to reform more in better economic times, engaging in pro-cyclical behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a survey of the normative side of the literature, i.e., optimal taxation, see Castanheira et al. (2011). For contributions related to the political economy of optimal taxation, see Acemoglu et al. (2010, 2011) and the empirical analysis of Gruber and Saez (2002).

  2. See Persson and Tabellini (2000, Chap., p. 2) for a review of some sufficiency conditions.

  3. This partly biases the results: a rich individual who retires and benefits from a generous public pension will be perceived as receiving a large transfer. We thus focus on the results that leave pensions out.

  4. Several authors worked on narrowing down the set of policies that could be proposed in a mixed strategy equilibrium (see, for instance, Davis et al. 1972; Schofield 1983; Laver and Shepsle 1996).

  5. See also Calvert (1985), Wittman (1983) and Roemer (2001) for models in which the politicians’ ideology prevents platform convergence.

  6. “Net” means the difference between the taxes paid and the subsidies received.

  7. Interestingly, this means that the entry of a new party, say on the right-end side of the political spectrum, should induce the other parties to propose lower taxes for the rich than before the entry of this new party.

  8. The typical equilibrium of such a game can only be represented by a Lorenz curve, which identifies how many percents p(x) of the population pays less taxes (or benefits from larger transfers) than some level x and how many percents 1−p(x) receives less (or pays more) than x. See Myerson (1993), Lizzeri and Persico (2001, 2005), and Crutzen and Sahuguet (2009) for more detail.

  9. For a more in-depth discussion of these processes, see Castanheira et al. (2010) who accompany their review of the economic literature with an illustration of the political economy of flat tax reform in Estonia.

  10. Calculated as (54−18)/54.

  11. See Roland (2000) for an in-depth analysis that focuses on transition countries and Valenduc (2006) for an application to Belgium.

  12. Note that efficiency gains are a necessary, but not sufficient, condition to satisfying both the ex ante and the ex post constraint.

  13. Rodrik (1996) challenges the latter theory on the ground that it is “unfalsifiable”: if a reform takes place, it is normally meant to address some problem but is it necessarily a “crisis”? Alternatively, if no reform takes places, would it mean that the crisis was not serious enough?

  14. Notice that there is no information for reforms in social security contributions in Bulgaria between 2000 and 2002.

  15. Instead, the political economics of indirect and corporate taxes is likely driven by special interest politics (see, e.g., Grossman and Helpman 2001).

  16. A question is whether these reforms are meant to increase economic efficiency or primarily to target voting groups. In an ideal world, one would solve for the optimal tax system conditional on the socioeconomic and political conditions in each country and check whether a given reform goes in that direction or not. But this is much beyond current feasibility constraints. To proxy for potential efficiency enhancements, we identify a subset of targeted reforms which we call “Lisbon.” These are the reforms targeted on older workers, female workers, job seekers, or low income taxpayers that decrease either their (tax or social contribution) rate or the base. The “Lisbon strategy” (now: Europe2020) specifically targets these categories to boost economic growth, employment, and social progress in Europe. There are 65 reforms of that type.

  17. In an unreported regression, we jointly used time and country fixed effects. Including these effects does not affect the signs and magnitude of our coefficients but reduces their significance: they pick up a large part of the influence of political systems that we aim to study. Because of this and because of the relatively short timeframe that limits the variance of some variables, we chose not to include them.

  18. To test further the hypothesis of political competition, we ran several additional unreported regressions. Replacing the Herfindahl indexes by a global Herfindahl index for all parties does not affect the results, nor does removing them altogether. We also checked for the effect of the mean district magnitude for the Parliament, a variable taken from the World Bank DPI database that represents the degree of proportionality in the electoral system: this variable takes a negative and significant (at 5 % level) sign, indicating that, ceteris paribus, proportional representation tends to hinder reform, which is consistent with Persson et al. (1997), Milesi-Ferretti et al. (2002), and Persson and Tabellini (2003). The effect that broader coalitions reform more is thus a feature of the reform tactics chosen by the government, and not of the electoral system itself. In this regression, all the other variables keep their sign but only execoalition maintains its significance.

  19. Unfortunately, our data do not allow us to disentangle international information spillovers from the timing of elections (see Sect. 5).

  20. To confirm this, we substitute the unemployment rate for the output gap (unreported regression). Its coefficient is negative and significant at 10 %, indicating that high unemployment hinders reforms. A one percentage point increase in the unemployment rate decreases the likelihood of tax reform by 2.1 %.

  21. We can only identify 4 “Lisbon” reforms that are specifically targeted to women. This prevents us from testing if the effect of the gender employment gap is directly related to gender-specific measures. The effect of the gap on the reforms targeted to low income is not statistically significant.

  22. The interactions between labor tax reforms and labor markets legislation reforms are potentially important, in particular whether they are substitute or complement. To the best of our knowledge, there is no empirical study on this particular issue, and the lack of significance in our regression leaves the question open.

  23. As unreported robustness checks, we used variables on the number of strikes, the number of workers involved in these strikes and the number of days lost in strikes (data from the International Labor Organization), which we divided by the working-age population. These variables are very correlated with each other. Only the relative number of workers involved in strikes turns significant. Its marginal effect is positive.

  24. As indicated above, most targeted reforms are of Lisbon type. Regressing only on Lisbon reforms provides similar results (unreported). This suggests that even reforms that aim at increasing efficiency are mainly driven by political economy considerations more than by economic factors.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Golosov, M., & Tsyvinski, A. (2010). Dynamic Mirrlees taxation under political economy constraints. The Review of Economic Studies, 77, 841–881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Golosov, M., & Tsyvinski, A. (2011). Political economy of Ramsey taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 467–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 651–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1988). Macroeconomics and politics. In S. Fischer (Ed.), NBER macroeconomics annual Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review, 81(5), 1170–1188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bassett, W. F., Burkett, J. P., & Putterman, L. (1999). Income distribution, government transfers, and the problem of unequal influence. European Journal of Political Economy, 15(2), 207–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou, R. (1996). Inequality and growth. In B. Bernanke & J. Rotemberg (Eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual (pp. 11–74). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Case, A. (1995a). Incumbent behaviour: vote seeking, tax setting and yardstick competition. American Economic Review, 85(1), 25–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Case, A. (1995b). Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? Evidence from gubernatorial terms limits. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 10(3), 769–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boeri, T., Castanheira, M., Faini, R., & Galasso, V. (2006). Structural reforms without prejudice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Borck, R. (2007). Voting, inequality and redistribution. Journal of Economic Surveys, 21(1), 90–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., Revelli, F., & Cerniglia, F. (2003). In search of yardstick competition: a spatial analysis of Italian municipality property tax setting. Journal of Urban Economics, 54, 199–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvert, R. L. (1985). Robustness of the multidimensional voting model: candidate motivations, uncertainty, and convergence. American Journal of Political Science, 29(1), 69–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castanheira, M., Nicodeme, G., & Profeta, P. (2010). On the political economics of taxation. In A. Petretto & F. Padovano (Eds.), Public choice and political economy (pp. 76–102). Milan: Franco Angeli editions.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castanheira, M., Nicodeme, G., & Profeta, P. (2011). On the political economics of tax reforms. CESifo Working Paper, 3538.

  • Castanheira, M., & Valenduc, C. (2006). Economie politique de la taxation. Reflets et Perspectives de la Vie Economique, 45(3), 19–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CIA (2007). The World Factbook. https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/.

  • Crutzen, B., & Sahuguet, N. (2009). Redistributive politics with distortionary taxation. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(1), 264–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998). When does it take a Nixon to go to China? American Economic Review, 88(1), 180–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, O., DeGroot, M., & Hinich, M. (1972). Social preference orderings and majority rule. Econometrica, 40(1), 147–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Mooij, R. A., & Nicodème, G. (2008). Corporate tax policy and incorporation in the EU. International Tax and Public Finance, 15, 478–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont, M., & Roland, G. (1992). Economic reform and dynamic political constraints. Review of Economic Studies, 59(4), 703–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont, M., & Roland, G. (1995). The design of reform packages under uncertainty. American Economic Review, 85(5), 1207–1223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1998). Fiscal federalism and redistributive politics. Journal of Public Economics, 68(2), 153–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of political action in a democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 135–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (1996). The political economy of delayed reform. Policy Reform.

  • Edmark, K., & Agren, H. (2007). Identifying strategic interactions in Swedish local income tax policies. Journal of Urban Economics, 63(3), 849–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Oxford: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Schnellenbach, J. (2007). Still a director’s law? On the political economy of income redistribution. IREF mimeo.

  • Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: status quo bias in the presence of individual specific uncertainty. American Economic Review, 81, 1146–1155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galli, E., & Profeta, P. (2009). The political economy of tax complexity. Public Finance and Management, 9(2), 331–348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gouveia, M., & Masia, N. A. (1998). Does the median voter model explain the size of Government? Evidence from the States. Public Choice, 97(1–2), 159–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special interest politics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J., & Saez, E. (2002). The elasticity of taxable income: evidence and implications. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyndels, B., & Vuchelen, J. (1998). Tax mimicking among Belgian municipalities. National Tax Journal, 51(1), 89–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. (2007). DPI2006: database of political institutions. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Shepsle, K. (1996). Making and breaking governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Le Grand, J. (1982). The strategy of equality: redistribution and the social services. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, W. W. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52, 273–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91(1), 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2005). A drawback of electoral competition. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(6), 1318–1348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long, J.S. & Freese, J. (2006). Regression models of categorical dependent variables using Stata. College Station: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinelli, C., & Tommasi, M. (1997). Sequencing of economic reforms in the presence of political constraints. Economics and Politics, 9(2), 115–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A., & Richard, S. (1981). A rational theory of the size of Government. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 914–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A., & Richard, S. (1983). Tests of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B. (2000). The median-voter hypothesis, income inequality, and income redistribution: an empirical test with the required data. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(3), 367–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., & Rostagno, M. (2002). Electoral systems and public spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 609–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1993). Incentives to cultivate favored minorities under alternative electoral systems. American Political Science Review, 87, 856–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, R. (1993). Political equilibrium, income distribution, and growth. Review of Economic Studies, 60(4), 755–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, R. (1996). Growth, income distribution, and democracy: What the data say. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(2), 149–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (1997). Separation of powers and political accountability. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1163–1202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Profeta, P. (2007). Political Support and tax reforms with an application to Italy. Public Choice, 131, 141–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Profeta, P. (2008). “Income tax reforms in Italy” CESifo Dice Report, Spring 2008.

  • Ramsey, F. P. (1927). A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 37, 47–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli, F. (2002). Local taxes, national politics and spatial interactions in English district election results. European Journal of Political Economy, 18, 281–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, K. W. S. (1977). Voting over income tax schedules. Journal of Public Economics, 8(3), 329–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1996). Understanding economic policy reform. Journal of Economic Literature, 24, 9–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 55, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roland, G. (2000). Transition and economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. E. (2001). Political competition. Harvard: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T. (1975). Individual welfare, majority voting, and the properties of a linear income tax. Journal of Public Economics, 4(2), 163–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2010). The conscription of wealth: mass warfare and the demand for progressive taxation. International Organization, 64, 529–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (1983). Generic instability of majority rule. Review of Economic Studies, 50(4), 695–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, C. (2008). Information, polarization and term length in democracy. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1078–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1970). The director’s law of public income redistribution. Journal of Law & Economics, 13(1), 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of income redistribution. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valenduc, C. (2006). Une flat tax en Belgique? Quelques éclairages sur les principes et les conséquences d’une telle réforme. Reflets et Perspectives de la Vie Economique, 45(3), 19–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warskett, G., Winer, S., & Hettich, W. (1998). The complexity of the tax structure in competitive political systems. International Tax and Public Finance, 5, 123–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winer, S. (2001). Normative Public Finance for Political Economists. Handbook of Public Finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternative theories. American Political Science Review, 77(1), 142–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Micael Castanheira has received funding from the European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2009-2013) under Grant Agreement No. 244725 (GRASP).

The authors thank Jean-Pierre De Laet, Benjamin Rausch, Laurent Bouton, Ruud de Mooij (the editor), two anonymous referees, and participants to the Political Economy Discussion Group at Harvard University and to the 2011 IIPF congress for valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Micael Castanheira.

Additional information

The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper, as well as possible errors and omissions, are entirely those of the authors. They should not be attributed to their institutions.

Appendix: Variable definitions and data sources

Appendix: Variable definitions and data sources

Variable

Definition

Source

Reform

Dummy indicating the occurrence of a reform in labor taxation

LABREF (European Commission) and own calculations

Targeted

Dummy indicating the occurrence of a targeted reform in labor taxation

LABREF (European Commission) and own calculations

Execoalition

Number of parties in the governing coalition

CIA Factbooks and own calculations

Herfgov

Herfindahl index for the governing coalition (in % of seats)

DPI (World Bank)

Herfopp

Herfindahl index for the opposition (in % of seats)

DPI (World Bank)

Maj

Percentage of majority in seats

DPI (World Bank)

Right

Dummy indicating a right-wing government

DPI (World Bank)

Left

Dummy indicating a left-wing government

DPI (World Bank)

Parliamentterm

Length in years of the parliamentary term

DPI (World Bank)

Parlyterm

Number of years left in the current term divided by the length of the term

DPI (World Bank) and own calculations

Govspec

Dummy variable indicating whether a member of the ruling coalition has specific political (nationalist, regional, religious or rural) interest

DPI (World Bank)

Pop65

Share of the total population aged 65 or more

CIA Factbooks

Ethnic

Herfindahl index of the various ethnic

CIA Factbooks and own calculations

Outputgap

Output gap of the economy (a positive index indicates GDP above potential GDP)

AMECO (European Commission)

Complgovempl

Compensation of employees of government in % GDP

AMECO (European Commission) and own calculations

Unemplr

Unemployment rate

AMECO (European Commission) and own calculations

Lagitrlabor

Lag of the Implicit tax rate on labor (computed as labor taxes collected on their own base)

Taxation Trends (European Commission)

EPL

Strictness of Employment Protection Legislation. The indicator varies between 1 (less strict) and 6 (stricter). The OECD indicators of employment protection measure the procedures and costs involved in dismissing individuals or groups of workers and the procedures involved in hiring workers on fixed-term or temporary work agency contracts

OECD

Emplgendergap

Difference in employment rates between men and women in percentage points

LIME (European Commission)

Actrateolder

Share of employed and unemployed in age groups 15–64, as a proportion of total population in the same age group

LIME (European Commission)

Uniondensity

Ratio of wage and salary earners that are trade union members, divided by the total number of wage and salary earners

OECD Labor Force Statistics

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Castanheira, M., Nicodème, G. & Profeta, P. On the political economics of tax reforms: survey and empirical assessment. Int Tax Public Finance 19, 598–624 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-012-9226-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-012-9226-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation