1 Introduction

The 2008–2009 global financial crisis severely affected the world economy and triggered a lively debate on the stability of the financial system and the related regulation policies that could limit the contagion effect of such crises on the real economy. In recent years, a major source of worldwide concern has become the relation between the structure of the credit market and its financial stability. Both theoretical and empirical studies on credit markets have investigated the effects of concentration on banking stability (Allen and Gale, 2004; Boyd and De Nicoló, 2005; Beck et al., 2006b; Fu and Heffernan, 2009; Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al., 2009; Fang et al., 2011). However, these studies offer ambiguous predictions.

Therefore, this study aims to contribute to the literature on the relation between market structure and financial stability, both from a theoretical and an empirical point of view, with a focus on the difference between mutual cooperative banks and profit-oriented banks in the context of Italy. In particular, we test whether an increase in concentration positively affects the stability of the financial system.

On the theoretical side, some models, such as Allen and Gale (2004), predict that an increase in competition will result in a higher risk of bank failure that indicates banks could invest high monopoly rents in safe assets. The so-called “concentration-stability view” argues that in concentrated banking systems, larger (monopolistic) banks can enhance profits and thus increase financial stability by providing higher “capital buffers” that protect them against external macroeconomic and liquidity shocks (Boyd et al., 2006).

However, some studies argue that lower concentration can bolster stability as it identifies, condenses, and uses dispersed or latent information that thus overcomes divided knowledge (Canvoy et al., 2001; see also Carletti and Hartmann 2003). Furthermore, others, like Boyd and De Nicoló (2005), find that lower concentration reduces the interest rate of a borrowing firm that leads the borrower to choose a safer project that in turn makes the bank more stable. Repullo et al.’s (2010) model predicts a nonlinear effect of concentration on bank risk: lower concentration first increases the risk-taking of banks and then reduces it.

On the empirical side, De Nicoló et al. (2004) provide evidence of increased risk profiles for the five largest conglomerate financial firms and of a higher level of potential systemic risk for more concentrated banking systems. Schaeck and Čihák (2007) and Schaeck et al. (2009) examine the effects of market competition and concentration on systemic stability for more than 2600 banks in the EU-10 plus Switzerland for the period from 1999 to 2004. They find no evidence of a trade-off between concentration and competition and banks’ risk-taking.

Since the 2008–2009 financial crisis, studies have shown that mutual cooperative banks (stakeholder banks) play a stabilizing role in the banking system. In fact, Coco and Ferri (2010) argue that a lack of financial stability derives mostly from bank owners’ incentives and the conflict between owners and depositors. Therefore, in mutual cooperative banks, where the owner-members are also depositors, this problem is less severe, and therefore they have fewer incentives to increase risk. Moreover, they find that the effect of the crisis has shown the sustainability of the stakeholder model with respect to the profit-orientated (shareholder) model of a financial intermediary. De Santis and Surico (2013) argue that mutual cooperative banks and savings banks protect their customers from monetary policy shocks and that mutual cooperative banks’ lending is less procyclical than that of profit-orientated banks. Ayadi et al. (2010) argue that the economy is thus exposed to intertemporal risk because of a lack of reserves since profit-orientated banks are less likely to collect reserves for future losses than mutual cooperative banks. Olszak et al. (2017) use data from 27 EU countries from 1996 to 2011 to show that Western European mutual cooperative banks have less cyclical loan loss provisions (LLP) than their profit-orientated counterparts. A similar result is shown by Alessi, di Colli and Lopez (2014) who find that the LLPs of Italian mutual cooperative banks are less cyclical than those of Italian profit-orientated banks from 2006 to 2012.

Rajan (1994) identifies an incentive in the cooperative business model to undertake less risky investments; moreover, as shown by Hesse and Čihák (2007), mutual cooperatives banks have a lower income volatility that leads to a rise in z-scores and greater stability in this category of banks and in the financial system in which they operate. These settings are also confirmed by other authors (Ayadi et al., 2010; Stefancic, 2010; Groeneveld, 2011).

Cioli and Giannuozzi (2014) study the effect on the riskiness of the different banks’ business models. They use the z-score as a proxy for financial stability and refer to financial statements of Italian mutual cooperative banks from 2006 to 2011 and compare the results with Italian profit-orientated banks.

The findings are in line with other studies performed in other countries and show that mutual cooperative banks have a greater degree of financial stability. In particular, they are better capitalized and invest less in derivatives. Therefore, these financial institutions can play a role in stabilizing a financial system during a financial crisis. However, there are also studies that adopt the opposite approach. For instance, Goodhart (2004) confirms the peculiarities of the cooperative credit union but shows that these institutions contribute to the instability of the financial system for two reasons: first, they push profit-orientated banks to turn to riskier assets to increase profit margins; second, they are also more affected by credit shocks because they are primarily focused on intermediation activities and have a low level of diversification in their assets.

To the best of our knowledge, very few studies have been aimed at verifying, both theoretically and empirically, the relation between market structure and financial stability by considering the differences between profit-oriented banks (PBs) and mutual cooperative banks (MBs).

Thus, we follow the structure-conduct-performance approach (Mason 1939; Bain 1956) to concentrate on the strategic interaction of banks and on the effect of a change in the number of competitors on their stability as a measure of concentration (and competition). In order to take into account, the polymorphism that still characterizes the banking systems in Europe (Ayadi et al., 2010), we consider banks’ strategic interaction in a mixed oligopoly setting that accounts for the presence of two types of agents: profit-oriented banks (that we define as PBs) and mutual cooperative banks (that we define as MBs). The model adapts the Klein-Monti approach (Klein, 1971) of a monopolistic bank to a case of imperfect mixed Cournot strategic interaction between MBs and PBs in the lending market. Following Allen and Gale (2004) and Martinez-Miera and Repullo (2010), we include a form of credit risk, but unlike them, we assume that credit risk is dependent on the quality of the information gathered by banks. We do so to capture the effect of the competition between different groups of agents and within each group on bank performance.

We find that when MBs are not dominated by borrowers, a decrease in concentration in a heterogeneous financial market increases stability. On the other hand, when MBs are dominated by borrowers, a decrease in concentration has an ambiguous effect on the stability of the financial system.

To empirically investigate the relation between concentration and financial stability, we use an Italian banking data set that covers the period from 1994 to 2015. This dataset makes it possible to consider PBs and MBs separately. In the empirical analysis, we use a parametric approach by applying the recent model by Kumbhakar et al. (2014). Specifically, we assess the effects of market structure by using the Herfindahl-Hirschman indicator and market share on the inefficiency of stability.Footnote 1 The empirical evidence identifies an inverted U-shaped relation between market concentration and the stability of banks in which a lower concentration increases stability, but a higher concentration reduces stability.Footnote 2

This study is organized as follows: The next Section briefly surveys the literature on the relation between market structure and financial stability. In Section 3, we present a mixed oligopoly model of bank strategic interaction. Section 4 presents the empirical strategy and data, and some stylized facts are discussed. In Section 5, we illustrate and discuss the findings of the theoretical model. We describe the results of the empirical analysis in Section 6. Section 7 concludes and provides suggestions in terms of policy decisions.

2 Related Studies: Market Structure and Financial Stability

Economic theory offers differing hypotheses about the relation between market structure and the stability of the banking system. Studies on the relation between market concentration and financial stability generally find that in more concentrated and collusive credit markets, larger (monopolistic) banks can have higher profit premiums that then provide higher “capital buffers” and reduce the incentives to take risks (Hellman et al., 2000; Boyd et al., 2006). Nevertheless, by referring to the “too big to fail” hypothesis, other studies show that more concentrated markets with the presence of a few relatively large banks could have a destabilizing effect on financial systems. Indeed, when concentration is particularly strong, some banks have so much weight and market power that their failure would result in the collapse of the entire financial system. Therefore, anticipating the unwillingness of the regulator to let them fail in the event of insolvency problems, they might have an incentive to increase their risk exposure (Hughes and Mester, 1998). Thus, the implicit or explicit assurance of rescue in the case of bankruptcy encourages risk-taking by banks, which will ultimately increase systemic risk (Mishkin, 1999).

Some theoretical contributions analyze the effects of competition on banks’ vulnerability to systemic risk on the liability side. For instance, Smith (1984) finds that competition for deposits reduces banks’ stability. Other contributions focus on the competition for loans but also consider liquidity shocks on the liability side by using a differentiated oligopoly for the loan market. These analyses show that the effect of competition increases banks’ stability (Carletti and Hartmann 2003). Some authors extended the Klein-Monti model to show that increased competition induces banks to choose riskier portfolio strategies, and they find a negative relation between the level of a bank’s credit risk and that of its market share through deposits (Dermine, 1986; Broecker, 1990; Besanko and Thakor, 1993). Conversely, some contributions find a positive relation between competition and bank stability (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981; Boyd and De Nicoló, 2005).

Exploring the traditional “concentration-stability” view, Hellmann et al. (2000) show that a reduction in concentration in the deposits market lowers the profitability of banks. Allen and Gale (2004) also affirm that the increased risk might be due to increased exposure to contagion in less concentrated markets. Recent research by Martinez-Miera and Repullo (2010) allows for a nonlinear relation between measures of bank risk and market structure. When banks charge lower rates, their borrowers have an incentive to choose safer investments, so they will in turn be safer. However, this argument does not account for the fact that lower rates also reduce the banks’ revenues from performing loans. They show that when this effect is accounted for, a U-shaped relation between competition and stability arises.

Studies have also empirically explored the relation between the structure of the credit market and the stability of the financial system but with ambiguous results. Some studies find a negative relation between market concentration and financial stability. De Nicoló and Loukoianova (2007) consider the z-score index and find that it decreases with the market concentration of banks as measured by the Herfindahl-Hirschman index (or HHI). This finding indicates that the risk of bank failure increases in more concentrated markets.

Similarly, using panel data from across the EU-25 for the period from 1997 to 2005, Uhde and Heimeshoff (2009) provide empirical evidence that the national concentration of the banking market has a negative effect on European banks’ financial soundness. They measure this concentration with the z-score while controlling for macroeconomic, bank-specific, regulatory, and institutional factors. Furthermore, their analysis indicates that Eastern European banking markets have a lower level of competitive pressure, fewer diversification opportunities, and a higher fraction of government-owned banks. These factors mean they are more prone to financial instability, while capital regulations have supported financial stability across the entire European Union. Later, based on Italian local data, Barra and Zotti (2019) find that the higher market concentration of MBs affects systemic stability by reducing the z-scores of PBs. This finding supports the hypothesis that the presence of non-profit-maximizing entities can pull down the stability of other financial institutions.

Some other studies that analyze the link between low concentration and instability find the same nexus. For instance, Schaeck et al. (2009) find that the less concentrated banking systems (measured using the Panzar and Rosse H-statistic) have lower likelihoods of bank failure and take a longer time to reach a crisis and hence are more stable than monopolistic systems. Conversely, empirical research also offers evidence of a positive relation between concentration and stability in credit markets. Empirical findings show that more concentrated markets have a positive effect on the stability of the banking system by generating a lower level of failure among banks. On the other hand, Keeley (1990) shows that a reduction in concentration have caused bank charter values to decline that in turn, has caused banks to increase default risk through increases in asset risk and reductions in capital. Also inconsistent with the concentration-fragility views are the results of Beck et al. (2006a). Their analyses indicate that national bank concentration reduces the likelihood that a country will suffer a systemic banking crisis. The results also hold when controlling for a wide array of macroeconomic, regulatory, and institutional factors, when using different definitions of crisis and concentration, and when examining different subsamples of countries. But, while their findings hold for the subsample of developing countries, they cannot confirm or reject these results when restricting the sample to high-income countries – not surprising given the limited number of countries and crises. Further, other empirical cross-country analyses on the relation between the concentration and instability of the banking system have ambiguous results. For instance, Berger et al. (2009) use three proxies for financial stability: a measure of overall bank risk, a measure of loan risk, and the capital ratio as an indicator of effort to control overall bank risk.Footnote 3 They also separately consider and compute several alternative measures of bank competition, such as the Lerner index. The results show that – in line with the traditional “competition-fragility” view – banks with a higher degree of market power also have less overall exposure to risk. The data also provide some support for one element of the “concentration-fragility” view – that market share increases loan portfolio risk. They show that this risk may be offset in part by higher ratios of equity capital. After controlling for macroeconomic conditions and bank characteristics, they use standard measures of market concentration and find support for a nonlinear relation between bank competition and risk-taking in both the loan and deposit markets. When direct measures of market share, such as Lerner indices, are used, the empirical results are more supportive of the original franchise value hypothesis,Footnote 4 but only in the loan market. Overall, the results highlight the empirical relevance of the Martinez-Miera and Repullo (MMR, 2010) model, although further analysis across other banking markets is needed.

To conclude, an important part of the literature, focusing on thrift institutions mutually owned by depositors (Maksimovic and Unal 1993, Unal 1997) argue that a conversion from a mutual to a stock association allows firms to raise equity capital, reducing the probability of insolvency by providing a cushion against failure. Moreover, analyzing risk management activities when multiple risks are bundled within a firm’s assets or liabilities, Schrand and Unal (1998) show that mutual thrifts which convert to stock institutions reduce interest-rate risk and this leads to a slower growth in credit risk. Masulis (1987), focusing on the economic causes and consequences of the organizational change by mutual savings and loan associations, when decide to convert to stock charter, finds that the conversion yields organizational efficiency gains. In particular, the organizational change is associated with an increase of equity capital and a decreased risk of insolvency. What more, results show that mutual institutions are more likely to convert to stock associations in markets that exhibit greater competition and growth.

3 A Mixed Oligopoly Model of Bank Strategic Interaction

In this Section, we theoretically investigate the relation between the structure and instability of the credit (local) market when different types of banks operate in that market. The market structure is measured by the number of competitors, as a proxy for the (local) market concentration degree. To do so we extend the Klein-Monti model (Klein 1971) of a monopolistic bank to a case of mixed Cournot interaction between two types of agents in the market – MBs and PBs. To simplify our analysis, we assume that there are M identical PBs and N identical MBs in the market that respectively supply loans Lj and Li (with i = 1, …, N and j = 1, …, M). Following Repullo et al. (2008) and Boyd and De Nicoló (2005), we assume that they have fully insured deposits, have no capital, and invest in a portfolio of entrepreneurial loans. The supply of deposits is perfectly elastic at an interest rate that is normalized to zero, and there are no intermediation costs.

The PBs maximize a profit function that competes with the other PBs and MBs in the loan market. Following Allen and Gale (2004), we assume that a fraction ρ of a bank’s loans defaults in which case it loses the interest and a fraction λ of the total amount. On the other hand, the bank gets Lj(1 + r) from the fraction (1 − ρ) of the loans that do not default and recovers Lj(1 − λ) from the fraction ρ of defaulted loans and has to pay back Lj to the depositors.

The PBs j pay-off is thus represented by the following profit function:

$$ {\pi}_j\left(\overline{L}\right)={L}_j\left(1+r\left(\overline{L}\right)\right)\left(1-\rho \right)+{L}_j\left(1-\lambda \right)\rho -{L}_j $$
(1)

where \( r\left(\overline{L}\right)=a-\overline{L} \) (with \( \overline{L}={\sum}_{i=1}^N{L}_i+{\sum}_{j=1}^M{L}_j \)) that represents the inverse demand for loans in the market.

A number of researchers have argued that PBs (often larger than local banks) are less capable of processing and transmitting the relational (soft) information through their hierarchical structures that is typical of MBs (Boot, 2000; Ghatak, 2000; Stein, 2002; Elyasiani and Goldberg 2004). As a consequence, PBs gather a kind of information (hard) that can be separated from its actual use, since it is standardized and based on data collection. On the other hand, MBs hold an information advantage (soft information) given by their proximity to customers. For sake of simplicity, we do not make distinctions between the kind of information the two types of banks can achieve.

The term  ρ can be thought of as an inverse measure of information accuracy through its specific effect on credit risk by assuming that the PB fails when \( {\pi}_j\left(\overline{L}\right)<0 \).Footnote 5 This circumstance happens if

$$ \rho >\frac{r}{r+\lambda}\equiv \hat{\rho} $$
(2)

We can consider \( \hat{\rho} \) as the maximum level of nonperforming loans that a PB is able to accept over which it is in a state of failure. In other words, if the fraction of nonperforming loans ρ is greater than the default rate \( \hat{\rho} \), then the bank is defaulting.

The MBs have a mutualistic feature and a regional limit to expansion. The main peculiarity that distinguishes MBs from PBs depends on their bottom-line objectives and the extent to which profit maximization is the central focus of their business models. Specifically, MBs are dual-objective institutions (Groeneveld and de Vries, 2009), since these financial institutions need to generate profits in order to survive and expand, but profit is not the sole or even primary bottom-line objective. Their primary concern is to balance the different interests of the various stakeholders in them; this means that a MB will not pursue profit maximization to the same degree, or with the same intensity, as will a PB (Llewellyn, 2005). Moreover, ownership is dispersed (along the “one head-one vote” principle), and borrowers are typically members of the cooperative.

The MBs’ primary mission is to promote economic benefits for their members, who are also their customers; for this reason, the specification of the objective function should focus on the value of the banks’ participation to the members. Like Emmons and Schmid (2002), we describe the MBs’ objective function as the weighted sum of members’ surplus S(Li) and the banks’ profits. We consider only the fraction of members who are also borrowersFootnote 6 from the bank (θ) since we focus on credit risk.

The MBs’ maximize the following utility function:

$$ {U}_i\left(\overline{L}\right)=\alpha \theta S\left({L}_i\right)+\left(1-\alpha \right){\pi}_i\left(\overline{L}\right) $$
(3)
$$ {U}_i\left(\overline{L}\right)=\alpha \theta S\left({L}_i\right)+\left(1-\alpha \right){L}_i\left(r-\rho \left(r+\lambda \right)\right) $$
(4)

The first component of MBs’ objective function is to increase the level of loans supplied to members. Since the second component of (Eq. 4) is to decrease the level of loans, the maximization problem of MBs is the balance of the different but interconnected interests of members and its survival.

$$ \left(\mathrm{Furthermore},\right)\ {U}_{L_i}^{\prime }>0\ if\ 0<\rho <\frac{r}{r+\lambda}\kern1em or\kern1.5em \frac{r}{r+\lambda }<\rho <1\kern0.5em and\ S^{\prime }>\frac{\left(1-\alpha \right)\left(\rho \left(r+\lambda \right)-r\right)}{\alpha \theta} $$

As Hesse and Čihák (2007) point out, MBs’ lower volatility in their returns derive directly from their ability to use their customer surplus to mitigate low profit periods. Moreover, a number of empirical studies conclude that, since stock-owned banks have higher risk-taking incentives, mutual associations have lower risk than stock institutions (Verbrugge and Goldstein, 1981; O’Hara, 1981; Cordell et al. 1993; Lamm-Tennant and Starks, 1993; Esty, 1997; Schrand and Unal, 1998).

In this regard, we assume that an MB fails when \( {U}_i\left(\overline{L}\right)<0. \) This event happens if

$$ \rho >\frac{r}{r+\lambda }+\frac{\alpha }{\left(1-\alpha \right)}\frac{\theta S\left({L}_i\right)}{L_i}\frac{1}{\left(r+\lambda \right)} $$
(5)

Since \( \hat{\rho}=\frac{r}{r+\lambda } \), we can manipulate condition (5):

$$ \rho >\hat{\rho}+\frac{\alpha }{\left(1-\alpha \right)}\frac{\theta S\left({L}_i\right)}{L_i}\frac{\hat{\rho}}{r}\ \left(\mathrm{thus},\right) $$
$$ \rho >\hat{\rho}\left(1+\frac{\alpha }{\left(1-\alpha \right)}\frac{\theta S\left({L}_i\right)}{rL_i}\right)\equiv \overset{\sim }{\rho } $$
(6)

Eq. (6) shows that the MB’s default rate is higher than the PB’s in Eq. (2) and is dependent on the balance between the two components of the utility function. In other words, MBs are able to accept a higher level of nonperforming loans, and the threshold value is greater if the mutual component is weighted more than the profits one. As for PBs, the term ρ in Eq. (5) can be thought of as an inverse measure of information accuracy. We assume that MBs and PBs compete à la Cournot on the loan market. By simultaneously maximizing Eqs. (1) and (4) with respect to (Li) for MBs and to (Lj) for PBs, we obtain the following reaction functionsFootnote 7:

$$ {RF}_j\left({L}_i\right)=\frac{\left(1-\rho \right)\left(a-N{L}_i\right)-\lambda \rho}{\left(M+1\right)\left(1-\rho \right)} $$
(7)
$$ {RF}_i\left({L}_j\right)=\frac{\left(1-\alpha \right)\left(\left(1-\rho \right)\left(a-M{L}_j\right)-\rho \lambda \right)}{\left(\left(1-\alpha \right)\left(1-\rho \right)\left(N+1\right)-\alpha \theta \right)} $$
(8)

There is a peculiarity in the two types of banks’ reaction functions that is common in a Cournot strategic interaction; the PB’s reaction function slopes downward (9). Conversely, the MB’s reaction function slope depends, as Delbono and Scarpa (1995) also noted, on the mutual component of the pay-off function (10).

$$ {RF}_j^{\prime}\left({L}_i\right)=-\frac{\frac{\partial^2{U}_j}{\partial {L}_j{L}_i}}{\frac{\partial^2{U}_j}{\partial {L_j}^2}}<0 $$
(9)
$$ {RF}_i^{\prime}\left({L}_j\right)=-\frac{\frac{\partial^2{U}_i}{\partial {L}_i{L}_j}}{\frac{\partial^2{U}_i}{\partial {L_i}^2}}\ \left\{\begin{array}{c}>0\ if\theta >\frac{\left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha}\left(1-\rho \right)\left(N+1\right)\\ {}<0\kern0.5em if\theta <\frac{\left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha}\left(1-\rho \right)\left(N+1\right)\end{array}\right. $$
(10)

The reaction function will slope upward if the fraction of members that are borrowers is greater than the threshold value (i.e., \( \frac{\left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha}\left(1-\rho \right)\left(N+1\right) \)). We can conclude that there is a critical value of the fraction of members such that if \( \theta >\overset{\sim }{\theta } \), then the MB will behave like a PB that maximizes members’ welfare, as Delbono and Rossini (1991) also noted. In this case, consistent with its main goal, the utility function of the MB will be convex for the quantity of loans.Footnote 8 Furthermore, since 0 < θ < 1, this event happens only for a range of values of α and N (e.g.\( \frac{\left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha}\left(1-\rho \right)\left(N+1\right)<1 \)for\( \kern0.5em \frac{1-\rho }{2-\rho }<\alpha <1\&0\le N\le \frac{2\alpha -1+\rho \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\left(1-\alpha \right)\left(1-\rho \right)} \)). If the second condition holds, then the MBs’ reaction function also slopes downward.

Since we are interested in changes in the market structure and their effect on stability, we consider an increase in the number of competitors and its effect on the default rate \( \hat{\rho} \) for each bank, given the equilibrium values of loans (see Appendix A.2).

We can thus consider a variation in the level of concentration as a shift from one market structure to another.

4 Results and Discussion

In this Section, we first consider the effect of an increase in the level of the interest rate on default rates: for the PBs, \( \frac{\partial \hat{\rho}}{\partial r}=\frac{\lambda }{{\left(r+\lambda \right)}^2}>0, \)and for MBs, \( \frac{\partial \overset{\sim }{\rho }}{\partial r}=\frac{S\alpha \theta +{L}_i\left(-1+\alpha \right)\lambda }{L_i\left(-1+\alpha \right){\left(r+\lambda \right)}^2}>0\ if\ S>0;{L}_i>0;0\le \theta \le \frac{L_i\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{S\alpha}\equiv \overset{\check{} }{\theta } \).

The first finding is that an increase in the level of the interest rate increases stability for PBs since it increases the default rate that is tolerable to the bank. For MBs, this effect depends on the fraction of members that are borrowing from the bank. In other words, if \( \theta <\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \), as for PBs, an increase in r increases stability. If \( \theta >\overset{\check{} }{\theta, } \) an increase in the interest rate lowers the default rate tolerable to MBs and they become less stable.

Consider now the total effect on the interest rate due to an increase in the number of competitors, through its effect on the equilibrium level of loans, \( r=\frac{\partial r}{\partial N} dN+\frac{\partial r}{\partial M} dM \) Footnote 9.

An increase in the number of MBs and PBs increases r if \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha}\equiv \frac{1-\rho }{1-\rho +\theta }<\alpha <\frac{\left(3-\rho \right)\left(1-{\rho}^2\right)}{2\theta +\left(3-\rho \right)\left(1-{\rho}^2\right)}\equiv \overset{\check{} }{\alpha}\kern0.5em \)and the interval narrows as ρ increases. In other words, a decrease in concentration increases r only for a special interval of values of the weight assigned by the MB to the members’ component of the utility. As the nonperforming loans increase, this condition becomes more stringent and lowers the range of feasible values. However, a decrease in concentration determines a reduction in the interest rate on loans if \( \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha } \).

We come to the following conclusions when we consider the effect of the number of competitors on the default rate for each type of bank:

  • L.1 A reduction in concentration (i.e., an increase in the number of competitors) increases stability for PBs, if the weight assigned by MBs to the members’ component of the utility belongs to the interval \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \) . A reduction in concentration decreases stability for PBs if \( \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha } \).

Since the default rate of PBs always increases with r, for the PBs to be more stable when concentration decreases, a positive correlation between r and the number of banks in the market needs to exist. An increase in the number of MBs and PBs increases r if \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \) and the interval narrows as ρ increases. On the other hand, if the weight assigned by the MB to the members’ component of the utility is \( \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha } \), then the interest rate decreases as concentration decreases and the level of nonperforming loans tolerated by PBs decreases that makes them less stable.

  • L.2 When the fraction of members who are borrowers in an MB is lower than the threshold value\( \left(\theta <\overset{\check{} }{\theta}\right) \), then a reduction in concentration increases stability for MBs if \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \) and members’ surplus is higher than the threshold value \( S>\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha }. \) A reduction in concentration decreases stability for MBs if \( \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha }. \)

  • L.3 When the fraction of members who are borrowers in an MB is higher than the threshold value \( \left(\theta >\overset{\check{} }{\theta}\right) \), then a reduction in concentration decreases stability for MBs, if \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \) . On the other hand, a reduction in concentration increases stability for MBs if \( \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha }. \)

For examples of L.2 and L.3, we consider the effect of an increase in the interest rate on MBs’ default rate:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\sim }{\rho }}{\partial r}>0\ if\kern0.5em S>\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha }\ and\ 0<\theta <\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{S\alpha} $$
(11)
$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\sim }{\rho }}{\partial r}<0\ ifS>\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha }\ and\ \frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{S\alpha}<\theta \le 1. $$
(12)

When concentration decreases, two situations make MBs more stable:

  1. 1)

    Either the two following conditions hold:

    1. a.

      dr > 0 \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \)

      $$ \frac{\partial \overset{\sim }{\rho }}{\partial r}>0\ S>\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha }\ and\theta <\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{S\alpha} $$
  2. 2)

    Or:

$$ dr<0\kern1em if\ \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha }. $$
$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\sim }{\rho }}{\partial r}<0\ ifS>\frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\alpha }\ and\ \frac{L\lambda \left(1-\alpha \right)}{S\alpha}<\theta $$

Thus, when concentration decreases, the weight assigned by an MB to the members’ component should be in the interval \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \), and the fraction of members’ borrowers must be lower than the threshold value\( \theta <\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \). Moreover, a condition on the surplus should be \( S>\overset{\sim }{S}. \)

Further, the effect of a lower concentration level on the interest rate may lead to a reduction in r if \( \alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha } \). In this case MBs can still be more stable if \( \frac{\partial \overset{\sim }{\rho }}{\partial r}<0, \) when \( S>\overset{\sim }{S}\ and\ \overset{\check{} }{\theta }<\theta \)such that a decrease in the interest rate increases the default rate for the MBs that lowers their risk of failure. This case does not apply to PBs.

From the results highlighted by L.1, L.2, and L.3, we can derive the following propositions:

  • P.1 When the fraction of MBs’ members who are borrowers is lower than the threshold value\( \theta <\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \) and if \( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \), then both the MBs and PBs are more stable if concentration decreases.

This proposition is verified by the results described in L.1 and L.2: namely, when \( \theta <\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \), an increase in r due to a reduction in concentration induces the same effect for both banks on the threshold value of the default rate. Both types of bank are more stable.

  • P.2 When the fraction of MBs’ members who are borrowers is higher than the threshold value\( \theta >\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \), then a reduction in concentration reduces stability for one group and increases stability for the other group. In particular, when reduction in concentration leads to an increase in the level of r (\( \overset{\sim }{\alpha }<\alpha <\overset{\check{} }{\alpha } \),), then MBs are less stable while PBs are more stable. On the other hand, when the reduction in concentration leads to a reduction in the level of r \( \left(\alpha <\overset{\sim }{\alpha}\right) \), then MBs are more stable but PBs are less stable.

P.2 is verified if we combine the results in L.1 and L.3. An increase in r due to a reduction in concentration increases stability only for PBs. On the other hand, a reduction in r increases stability only for MBs.

In conclusion, when the fraction of MBs’ members who are borrowers is lower than the threshold value\( \theta <\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \), both MBs and PBs are more stable if the market structure is less concentrated: if the level of the interest rate rises, then it increases (for both types of bank) the level of the threshold value for nonperforming loans that corresponds to a bank’s default situation.

When the fraction of MBs’ members who are borrowers is higher than the threshold value\( \theta >\overset{\check{} }{\theta } \), then a reduction in concentration reduces stability for one group and increases stability for the other group. In particular, when the reduction in concentration increases the level of r, MBs are less stable while PBs are more stable. This situation may be due to the fact that the fraction of MBs’ borrower members is higher (MBs are dominated by borrowers). However, a reduction in concentration that reduces the level of r makes MBs more stable (since borrower members are better off) but PBs are less stable (their profits are lower).

5 Empirical Design

5.1 Financial Stability and Bank Market Concentration: A Stochastic Frontier Approach

In this subsection, in order to evaluate and investigate the relation indicated by the previous theoretical model, i.e. the effect of market structure on financial stability, we perform an empirical analysis based on a parametric approach (Tabak et al., 2012) by using the recent stochastic frontier technique developed by Kumbhakar et al. (2014). This model splits the error term into four components: bank fixed effects, time-varying inefficiency, time-invariant inefficiency, and a stochastic component that captures random shocks. With this model, we capture the fact that banks can eliminate certain sources of their short-term inefficiency over time, while other sources can have a more permanent nature. The empirical model is represented by the following set of equations:

$$ {y}_{it}=f\left({x}_{it},{\upbeta}_{it}\right)+{\varepsilon}_{it} $$
(13)
$$ {\varepsilon}_{it}={v}_{it}-{u}_{it}+{\alpha}_i+E\left({u}_{it}\right)+{\alpha}_0^{\ast } $$
(14)
$$ {\alpha}_i={\mu}_i-{\eta}_i+E\left({\eta}_i\right) $$
(15)
$$ {\alpha}_0^{\ast }={\alpha}_0-E\left({\eta}_i\right)-E\left({u}_{it}\right) $$
(16)
$$ {v}_{it}\sim i.i.d.N\left(0,{\sigma}_v^2\right) $$
(17)
$$ {u}_{it}\sim i.i.d.{N}^{+}\left({\mathrm{z}}_{\mathrm{i}}\updelta, {\sigma}_u^2\right) $$
(18)
$$ {\mu}_i\sim i.i.d.N\left(0,{\sigma}_{\mu}^2\right) $$
(19)
$$ {\eta}_i\sim i.i.d.{N}^{+}\left(0,{\sigma}_{\eta}^2\right) $$
(20)

where y denotes the output of the ith bank (the z-score), xi represents the 1xk vector of input, β is the kx1 vector of unknown parameters to be estimated, ηi represents persistent inefficiency, μi captures bank effects, and vit is a stochastic component. The uit denotes the short-term inefficiency distributed by each unit as a truncation at zero, where z is a (1 x m) vector of exogenous factors associated with the technical inefficiency of production units (see Table 1 for more details about these exogenous factors)Footnote 10, and δ is a (m × 1) vector of unknown coefficients. This approach, unlike others, makes possible the consideration of how the production process of banks, and therefore the degree of allocation of resources, affects the probability of bankruptcy.

Table 1 Description of the variables. This Table presents the main variables we employ in our empirical analysis. The source is BilBank 2000 database from ABI

This model is estimated in three steps. First, Eq. (13) is estimated using a standard fixed effects estimation. Second, time-varying inefficiency uit is obtained. Third, persistent inefficiency ηi is estimated (Kumbhakar et al. 2014). Specifically, the Translog specification is described as follows:

$$ \frac{\tilde{FS}}{{\tilde{w}}_{1.}}={\sum}_j{\beta}_j\ {\tilde{y}}_{j.}+{\sum}_k{\gamma}_k\left(\frac{\ {\tilde{w}}_{k.}}{{\tilde{w}}_{1.}}\right)+{\tau}_1T+\frac{1}{2}\left[{\sum}_j{\sum}_m{\beta}_{jm}\ {\tilde{y}}_{j.}\ {\tilde{y}}_{m.}+{\sum}_k{\sum}_n{\gamma}_{kn}\left(\frac{\ {\tilde{w}}_{k.}}{{\tilde{w}}_{1.}}\right)\ast \left(\frac{\ {\tilde{w}}_{n.}}{{\tilde{w}}_{1.}}\right)+{\tau}_{11}{T}^2\right]+{\sum}_j{\sum}_k{\delta}_{jk}\ {\tilde{y}}_j\left(\frac{{\tilde{w}}_{k.}}{{\tilde{w}}_{1.}}\right) $$
(21)

where\( \tilde{FS} \) is the natural logarithm of financial stability calculated using the z-score, \( \tilde{y} \) are (the natural logs of) output quantities, \( \overset{\sim }{w} \) are (the natural logs of) input prices, and T denotes a time trend that captures changes in technology over time. The linear homogeneity in factor prices is guaranteed by dividing all input prices and total cost by one input price (in our case, labour cost, \( {\overset{\sim }{w}}_1 \)). Moreover, symmetry conditions are also imposed: βjm = βmj and γkn = γnk.

As suggested in the literature, the z-score measure is considered a good proxy of a bank’s distance from default (Rojas-Suarez, 2002), and it does not require strong assumptions about the distribution of the returns on assets (Strobel, 2011). It combines banks’ buffers (capital and profits) with the risks they face (measured by the standard deviation of returns) that reflect the number of standard deviations by which returns would have to fall from the mean in order to wipe out equity. A higher z-score value means a lower probability of insolvency risk (Unde and Heimeshoff, 2009) and greater stability (e.g., inverse of the probability of defaults) that provides a direct measure of the banking system’s stability. The z-score then increases with the banks’ profitability and capital ratio and, conversely, decreases with increases in the conditional volatility.

Because they are mathematically equivalent, the choice of the normalizing variable is innocuous (Restrepo-Tobòn and Kumbhakar, 2017). The set of parameters in the Translog function are estimated using a maximum likelihood estimator (MLE) that gives a consistent and efficient estimator, as suggested by Kumbhakar and Lovell (2000).

To examine the effect of market structure on financial stability, we include in the inefficiency component the Herfindahl index that is calculated as the sum of squared market shares in terms of total loans of all banks in the same labor market area (HHI):

$$ {HHI}_{i,t}=\sum \limits_{i=1}^N{\left({\frac{Loans_{i,t}}{Total\ Loans}}_{k,t}\right)}^2 $$
(22)

where Loansi refers to the customer loans of bank i at time t, and Total Loansk refers to the total customer loans grouped at the k labor market level at time t, because it is reasonable that banks compete with other intermediaries operating in the surrounding areas.Footnote 11 In a perfect competition market, the HHI approaches zero. The further the HHI is from zero, the closer the area’s market is to a monopoly.

We reduce the heterogeneity in our estimation because our analysis is based on a single country, thereby accounting for cultural, geographical, political, and monetary homogeneity. Moreover, the highly detailed spatial stratification enables us to capture the differences between geographical areas that result in more accurate estimates.

5.2 Data and Variables

The data come from the BilBank 2000 database distributed by the ABI (Associazione Bancaria Italiana) because of its large time extension and its rich set of information on bank balance sheets for the period from 1994 to 2015 (see Table 1 for more details on the definition of the variables).Footnote 12 We focus on the Italian context due to the availability of highly disaggregated territorial data, the financial reforms (privatization and Second Banking Directive) that occurred after 1990, and its integration of markets.

The sample of banks consists of MBs and PBs, but not Italian branches of foreign banks. In particular, we use a sample of Italian banks classified by the Bank of Italy as follows: major (average funds intermediated more than 65 billion euro), large (average funds intermediated between 27 and 65 billion euro), medium (average funds intermediated between 9 and 27 billion euro), small (average funds intermediated between 1.3 and 9 billion euro), and minor (average funds intermediated less than 1.3 billion euro). We also thus consider the different sizes of financial institutions.

Table 2 has a description of the sample used in the analysis by geographical location that emphasizes the importance of MBs to the Italian banking scene; indeed, almost 66% of financial institutions in our sample consist of MBs that makes them very important players and actors in the Italian financial environment. To obtain a complete picture of territorial and banking differences, we also have included in the table some descriptive statistics on the cost, profit and risk measures as well as having included a composite measure of the outputs, inputs, and input pricesFootnote 13.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics for the inputs, inputs prices, outputs, cost, profit and risk of banks. This Table describes the statistics on the cost, profit and risk measures as well as a composite measure of the outputs, inputs, and input prices. In particular: Y = (y1 + y2 + y3)/3; X = (x1 + x2 + x3)/3; W = (w1 + w2 + w3)/3. Cost: personnel expenses, other administrative expenses, value adjustments to tangible and intangible assets and other operating expenses and interest expenses and similar charges and commission expenses. Revenue: interest and similar income on loans to costumers, interest and similar income on debt securities and services (administrative) or non-traditional activities, i.e. commission income and other operating income and services. Profit: Revenue-Cost; ROA: return on assets. ROE: return on equity. Npll: non-performing loans to total loans (credit risk). Clea: Customer loans/earning assets. N-W: North-West. N-E: North-East. CE: Centre. SI: South-Islands. MB: mutual cooperative banks. PB: profit oriented banks (commercial and popular). The source is BilBank 2000 database from ABI. Observations with negative profits are also included in the calculation of the profitability measurements. All variables averaged between 1994 and 2015. Standard deviation in brackets. All monetary aggregates are in thousands of Euros (at 2005 prices)

According to the calculation of bank performance, our production set follows the asset model (Sealey and Lindley 1997) in which the output vector (y) comprises customer loans (y1); services (administrative) or non-traditional activities that are commission income and other operating income (y2); and securities (y3) that are bank loans, Treasury bills, and similar securities, bonds, and other debtless bonds; and debt securities held by banks and other financial institutions. Because non-traditional activities play an important role in banking output, we include a proxy to capture the effect of these activities, such as commission income and other operating income, on bank performance (e.g., Casu et al., 2004; Tortosa-Ausina et al., 2008). Instead, the input vector (x) consists of the following items: number of workers (x1); number of branches (x2); and total liabilities to customers, amounts owed to banks, and debt securities (x3). The cost vector (w) incurred by the credit institutions is composed of the labor cost (w1) that is the ratio of personnel expenses to the number of employees; cost of physical capital (w2) that is the ratio of other administrative expenses, value adjustments to tangible and intangible assets, and other operating expenses to the number of branches; and the cost of financial capital (w3) that consists of interest expenses and similar charges and commission expenses over total liabilities (see Table 3 for more details on descriptive statistics on input, input prices and output). On the output side, PBs have a lower value of customer loans (y1), of level of services (y2), and of other loans (y3). With regard to geographic location, banks located in the Northern regions (i.e. North-West (N-W) and North-East (N-E)) have a high level of customer loans (y1), of services (y2), and of other loans (y3) than Central-Southern&Islands (i.e. Centre (CE) and South-Islands (SI)). The costs of labor (w1), physical (w2), and financial (w3) are higher for PBs and for banks operating in the Northern regions. PBs have a greater number of workers (x1) and branches (x2) and a higher level of liabilities (x3).

Table 3 Descriptive statistics for the inputs, inputs prices and outputs used in the production function. This Table describes the statistics of the outputs, inputs, and input prices used in the production function. In particular: customer loans (y1), services or non-traditional activities (y2), securities and other loans (y3). Number of workers (x1), number of branches (x2), fundraising (x3); labour cost (w1). Cost of physical capital (w2), cost of financial capital (w3). N-W + N-E: North-West and North-East. CE + SI: Centre and South-Islands. MB: mutual cooperative banks. PB: profit oriented banks (commercial and popular). The source is BilBank 2000 database from ABI. N: number of observations. All variables averaged between 1994 and 2015. Standard deviation in brackets. All monetary aggregates are in thousands of Euros (at 2005 prices)

Recent studies have strongly approved of the inclusion of some environmental and bank-specific variables in a one-stage stochastic frontier (Lozano-Vivas et al., 2002, Hasan et al., 2009), particularly when considering the Italian context (Destefanis et al., 2014; Barra et al., 2016). Therefore, we include in the z-vector associated with the technical inefficiency of production units for the following environmental and bank-specific factors: (i) bank size as measured by the natural logarithm of total assets (TA); (ii) bank capitalization as measured by the ratio of equity to total assets (ETA); (iii) typology of banks such as MBs and PBs in which popular banks are used as the benchmark group; (iv) macro areas such as North-West (N-W), North-East (N-E), and South&Islands (SI), while Central (CE) is used as a benchmark to control for any unobservable territorial effects; and (v) the typology of major, large, medium, small, and minor. We use major group as a benchmark for the different sizes of financial institutions. Further, we include a time trend and its square to control for any unobservable shocks that affect the inefficiency of financial stability. For a comparison check, the Italian Statistical Office (ISTAT 2005), being a public research body and the main provider of official statistics to support citizens and decision-makers, currently identifies 110 provinces (the NUTS3 category) and 686 LMAs (labor market areas). These classifications highlight remarkable differences in economic performance across the Italian territory. LMA-level data for branches, deposits, and loans come from the Bank of Italy data set (Bollettino Statistico). Thus, LMAs represent a deeper territorial disaggregation than NUTS 3 level subdivisions that are sub-regional areas where the bulk of the labor force lives and works (Destefanis et al. 2014; Barra and Zotti, 2019). The other variables useful for our analysis come from the BilBank 2000 database. All monetary aggregates are in thousands of deflated 2005 euros. Our sample begins in 1994, because bank data are not available before that year. The test and SFA regressions are performed using STATA 13.1.

The descriptive statistics confirm that the Northern regions have the financial institutions that are bigger in terms of dimension (related to TA), are more stable (related to FSROA), and have a higher level of capital (related to ETA) than Central-Southern&Islands regions. Furthermore, according to the typology of banks, the statistics confirm that stability is driven by the presence of MBs in the market. In fact, MBs show some different territorial and financial characteristics to PBs (Destefanis et al. 2014). As expected, PBs present a level of total assets (TA) higher than that of MBs. On the other hand, MBs show a level of capitalization (ETA) higher than PBs due to their amount of total assets. According to the market structure, Northern regions are less concentrated than Central-Southern&Islands regions. Moreover, MBs are more concentrated than PBs, both in the case of HHI and MS indicators. These differences are more marked when separate markets are considered Table 4.

Table 4 Descriptive statistics for the financial stability, market structure, bank size and level of capitalization. This Table describes the statistics of the variables used in our empirical analysis. The description of these variables is reported in Table 1. N-W + N-E: North-West and North-East; CE + SI: Centre and South-Islands. MB: mutual cooperative banks. PB: profit oriented banks (commercial and popular. Popular used as benchmark group). The source is BilBank 2000 database from ABI. N: number of observations. All variables averaged between 1994 and 2015. Standard deviation in brackets. All monetary aggregates are in thousands of Euros (at 2005 prices)

6 Empirical Results

The theoretical results highlight a negative relation between concentration and stability that depends on some conditions for MBs members’ structure. To confirm our theoretical predictions, we conduct an empirical exercise in which we estimate the relation between market structure and the inefficiency of financial stability using a parametric approach (SFA) (see Tabak et al. 2012 for a similar approach).Footnote 14 In order to get closer to the theoretical model, we assume that the MBs and PBs compete in the same market. Taking the inefficiency of financial stability (based on the ROA) as the dependent variable and the HHI as the main market structure indicator, we observe that the inefficiency decreases in a more concentrated market (similar to Keeley 1990; Allen and Gale 2000, 2004; Beck et al. 2006a; Matsuoka 2013; Barra and Zotti, 2019), but when the square of the HHI is considered, the inefficiency increases; we find a U-shaped relation between market structure’s concentration and the inefficiency of financial stability (Table 5, column A1). In other words, banks that operate under low concentration levels are less fragile in terms of the inefficiency of stability (similar to Tabak et al. 2012). As a robustness check, we assess the same model but use the MS that is calculated by using the loans as follows:

$$ {MS}_{i,t}=\sum \limits_{i=1}^N\left({\frac{Loans_{i,t}}{Total\ Loans}}_{k,t}\right) $$
(23)

where Loansi refers to the customer loans of bank i over time t, and the Total Loansk refers to total customer loans grouped at the k level of the labor market over time t. We observe that the inefficiency of financial stability decreases when the MS is high, but when its square is considered, the inefficiency increases; in this case, the finding also indicates the presence of a U-shaped relation between market concentration and the inefficiency of financial stability (Table 5, column A3).

Table 5 Inefficiency of stability and market structure. The indirect approach (SFA). The description of these variables is reported in Table 1. Standard errors in brackets

As regards the control variables, particular attention should be given to the total assets (TA) that is a good proxy for the banking dimension and to equity on total assets (ETA) that is a good proxy for bank capitalization. The signs of these two controls are negative and significant in all the estimations performed and thereby indicate that greater size and capitalization are important drivers in reducing the inefficiency of stability. We also find that the presence of MBs in the market reduces this inefficiency compared to the presence of PBs.

7 Conclusions and Policy Implications

In recent years, both theoretical and empirical studies on credit markets have devoted attention to analysing the relation between the structure of the credit market and the financial stability of banks (Allen and Gale, 2004; Boyd and De Nicoló, 2006; Fu and Heffernan, 2009; Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al., 2009; Fang et al., 2011). As previously discussed, both economic theory and empirical evidence provide contrasting results on this relation. Occasionally, there appears to be a negative trade-off between concentration and financial stability. Moreover, since the 2008–2009 financial crisis, studies have found that MBs play a stabilizing role in the banking system as a whole. This study makes two original contributions to the literature: first, by analysing the relation between market structure and financial stability from both a theoretical and an empirical point of view; second, by considering the peculiar polymorphism that characterizes the credit market in which at least two main types of bank operate: PBs and MBs. Despite the consistently strong findings about the differences between these two types, relatively few studies have directly examined the strategic interaction of different types of intermediaries (Berger et al., 2004).

The results of the theoretical model depend on the proportion of borrower members of the MBs. The main theoretical finding shows that, under the condition that MBs are not dominated by borrowers, a less concentrated market structure increases the stability of both types of banks (Hesse and Čihák, 2007; Fiordelisi and Mare, 2014).

The empirical analysis contributes by adding evidence on what can be considered a relevant open question. We observe a U-shaped relation in which a less concentrated market structure reduces inefficiency of stability for both types of banks but a more concentrated market structure increases it.Footnote 15

When the concentration is measured separating the two groups of banks (MBs and PBs), the result described above is confirmed that supports the theoretical predictions (Destefanis et al., 2014; Barra and Zotti, 2019). A specific value added by this study is that, by combining theory and empirical evidence, it provides interesting results that might be helpful to policymakers in developing and implementing regulatory policies aimed at promoting competition and preserving financial stability in the banking system (see Mester 2017 for a discussion about changes to bank supervision and regulation in order to promote financial stability). In particular, with regard to the effectiveness of the ongoing reforms of the MBs in some European countries, for example in Italy, the results might be helpful in enhancing the potential role of MBs as buffers against the financial instability in the banking system.

This analysis can be extended to future research on the European area, for example, by focusing on countries with the same financial market characteristics, such as the simultaneous presence of a network of MBs (Hesse and Čihák, 2007; Fiordelisi and Mare, 2014) together with PBs and verify if the results hold or not.