As defended prey increased in relative frequency from zero (and frequency of edible prey therefore decreased) so the birds attacked a smaller proportion of all individual prey present (Fig. 1a, Z = 7.155, df = 799, p < 0.001). This is a demonstration of the “public good” of protection, since all remaining individuals benefit from attacks on defended individuals. The birds attacked more in the aggregated than the dispersed arrangement (Z = 2.299, df = 799, p = 0.022) and in the full model there was no evidence of an interaction between dispersion and prey frequency (Z = −0.127, df = 799, p = 0.900). Similarly the proportion of all prey killed decreased as defended prey frequency increased (Fig. 1b, Z = 8.740, df = 799, p < 0.001), and a higher proportion were killed in the aggregated than the dispersed distributions (Z = 2.402, df = 799, p = 0.0163); again no interaction in the full model (Z = –0.406, df = 799, p = 0.684). Since each bird had a single exposure to their experimental condition, they could assess defended prey frequency and adjust attack probability rapidly.
We looked next at likelihood of survival in relation to edibility status (edible or defended) given that an attack had begun. Here we included bird ID as a random factor and examined the trials with mixed prey populations (taking edible prey frequencies 25, 50, 75 %). There was a significantly higher likelihood by this measure that an edible prey would be killed (as defined above) than a defended prey (Z = −4.897, df = 140, p < 0.001). The mean likelihood of death given attack for edible prey was 0.89 (SD = 0.31), whereas the mean likelihood for defended prey was only 0.38 (SD = 0.48). There was no effect of edible prey frequency on these behaviours (Z = 1.465, df = 799, p = 1.143). Dispersion also had no effect on probability of death given attack (Z = 1.518, df = 799, p = 0.129).
To examine whether the birds could to any extent discriminate mimics from models we used the method employed by Jones et al. (2013), in which we determine the difference between the observed proportion of prey attacked that are defended with that expected by their frequency in the set of prey presented. We then used a one-tailed t test, to determine if the mean difference across birds was different from zero. Birds could not discriminate mimics and models when the frequencies were toward the extremes (model frequency = 75 %, t = −1.586, df = 9, p = 0.147; model frequency = 25 %, t = 0.3458, df = 9, p = 0.7374), however there was a near-significant discrimination when the model frequency was 50 % (t = −2.2361, df = 9, p value = 0.052), in which the models were attacked less frequently than the mimics (supplementary material presents the mean values, and shows that even with some discrimination, models suffer from mimicry as mimic frequency increases).
A simple parameterised model of defence evolution
We now construct a simple model of toxin evolution to which we apply parameters from the experiment. Since there was no interaction between aggregation and automimic frequency on attack behaviours we have pooled the data, and ignore frequency dependent discrimination for simplicity here. We aim specifically to generate a clear, simple model here; more complex approaches are of course possible.
We can describe the general likelihood that a prey survives a time interval, Ti, simply as
$${\text{S}}_{\text{T = i}} = 1 - {\text{p}}_{ 1} {\text{p}}_{ 2} {\text{p}}_{ 3}^{\text{f}}$$
(1)
where p1 is the probability that a predator notices a prey in this interval; p2 is the probability that it attacks it given detection, and p
f3
the probability that it kills it given attack (i.e. ST=i = 1 − probability that it will be killed in a time interval, where the superscript f refers to the defence presence or absence of defence). This assumes, for simplicity, stationary levels of prey and predator numbers within a generation, and stable levels of learning. Our data show very rapid learning about frequencies by predators, which is consistent with this latter assumption.
The probability that a prey survives t time intervals, for example a season before reproduction, is now
$${\text{S}}_{{{\text{T = i}} \ldots {\text{t}}}} = (1 - {\text{p}}_{ 1} {\text{p}}_{ 2} {\text{p}}_{ 3}^{\text{f}} )^{\text{t}}$$
(2)
We can estimate p2 using the logistic regression equation from the analyses (Fig. 1)
$${\text{p}}_{2} = 1 - {1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 {\left( {1 + \exp ( - (1.807 - 1.951*{\text{F}}_{\text{mi}} ))} \right)}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\left( {1 + \exp ( - (1.807 - 1.951*{\text{F}}_{\text{mi}} ))} \right)}}$$
(3)
where Fmi = frequency of edible prey in the population. Hence attack probability decreases according to a decelerated function based on the data and shown in Fig. 2.
We now add a hypothetical fecundity penalty (F) incurred by investment in toxicity (see examples of toxin costs in Hetz and Slobodchikoff 1988; Ruxton et al. 2004; Higginson et al. 2011; Lindstedt et al. 2011). For the defended prey, this is Fo where Fo < 1 it indicates that fecundity is reduced from its initial value of 1 because resources are allocated away from reproduction and toward chemical defence. A value of Fo = 0.5 for example means that the prey depletes its fecundity by half to invest in chemical defence. The equivalent for the edible prey, Fi is always set to 1, because there is no investment in toxicity. Fitness is defined in as the product of fecundity and survival, \({\text{F}} . {\text{S}}_{{{\text{T}} = 1 \ldots {\text{t}}}}.\)
Note that the value of p
f3
differs for edible prey and defended prey, we term this p3′ for chemically defended prey (=0.38 in our experiment) and p3′′ for edible prey (=0.89). We can now specify the survival of defended prey (using p3′ and p3′′) as SoT=1…t and hence their fitness as \({\text{F}}_{\text{o}} . {\text{So}}_{{{\text{T}} = 1 \ldots {\text{t}}}}\) and the corresponding value for edible prey as \({\text{F}}_{\text{i}} . {\text{Si}}_{{{\text{T}} = 1 \ldots {\text{t}}}}.\)
Results
General outcomes of the model
We use this model to ask how toxicity would evolve in scenarios of different costs (variable values of Fo) and different season lengths (t). We keep p1 at 10−3, a 1 in a thousand chance of a prey being spotted per time interval. We assume that the prey population is small enough that it does not affect demand from predators, i.e. it does not satiate them when prey are edible.
We can illustrate three outcomes for the case of t = 1000, in which costs of toxicity vary, and we initially consider how a mutant “defended prey” would fare if it entered a population of otherwise undefended “edible prey” (assuming asexual clonal reproduction for simplicity). We use these conditions to explain how and when stable dimorphisms can be predicted.
In the first case (Fig. 3a), toxicity has no costs and the defended prey always has higher fitness than the edible prey, because it survives attacks more often. Note though that as defended prey frequency rises (and edible prey frequencies therefore decline), so the fitness of both forms increase. This illustrates a growing “public” benefit from rising frequencies of defended prey which emerges because predators reduce attacks on all prey as defended individuals become more common. Note the fitness of edible prey increases faster than that of defended prey as chemical defence expands in the prey population. Edible prey lack protection once an attack has taken place, so they have more to gain, in survival terms, if the attack probability declines. Since defended prey’s fitness is always higher than the edible prey’s fitness we would expect a new “defended mutant” to rise to fixation in the prey population. In the second case (Fig. 3b) costs of toxicity are excessive (Fo = 0.5) and a new defended mutant should never increase from rarity.
In the third case, Fo = 0.85 and the defended mutant prey is more fit than the edible prey when new and rare, but as it increases the fitness difference between prey types begins to close because of a higher rate of gain again for the edible prey from decreased attack probability (Fig. 3c). A point is reached where defended and undefended prey have equal fitness (red and green curves intersect). This is a stable equilibrium point. If for example defended prey frequency exceeded this equilibrium frequency, they would be less fit than edible prey and their frequency would shrink back to the equilibrium point. If in contrast they undershot the equilibrium frequency, they would be more fit and increase toward the equilibrium value. In the Supplementary Material we show that we can convert these fitness measures into a simple evolutionary simulation in which defended prey evolve to the specified equilibrium and return to it if frequencies are disturbed. Note also stability of defence dimorphisms has been examined in depth (Broom et al. 2005; Svennungsen and Holen 2007b) and we refer readers to mathematical treatments there.
A biological explanation for stable dimorphisms is that the individual benefit from costly toxins (of surviving an attack) declines as this phenotype becomes more common in the population, because prey are increasingly protected by the “public good” of reduced attack probabilities. Hence toxicity becomes less cost effective for individuals as its frequency rises. At the equilibrium point the net benefits of toxicity (increased survival from attack at a price of reduced fecundity) exactly match those of no toxicity (heightened survival from the public benefit of reduced attack probability, but with increased cost of death given attack).
Predicting equilibrium frequencies
We can now use our parameterised defended prey to predict the equilibrium frequencies of defended prey if costs of toxicity and season length varied as shown in Fig. 4. Looking first at the blue symbols (t = 1000 intervals) defended prey do not invade the population while the residual fecundity after paying for toxins is low (0.5–0.73), and as costs decrease (left to right) toxicity evolves to intermediate frequencies of increasing value until a point is reached at which toxicity is sufficiently cheap that it always rises to fixation. Considering increased season lengths we now see toxicity evolving more often and to higher equilibrium levels at high cost conditions. As the number of potential attacks increases with season duration so the value of the individual benefit of toxin caused survival increases. Note that these estimates are for infinite populations, and lack the influence of drift. So in cases where the benefits of toxicity are only slightly higher than nontoxicity at any frequency, we may expect much larger variations in toxin frequencies in natural populations. In our estimates in Fig. 4, this applies to conditions with long season lengths and high marginal costs of toxins (especially black symbols on the left side of the graph).