Skip to main content
Log in

Energy Price Jumps, Fat Tails and Climate Policy

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many authors who have analyzed key energy prices, such as crude oil and natural gas, have found that these prices exhibit “fat tails”—the feature that large percentage changes occur far more often than would be predicted by a conventional model. These fat tails can arise either because of time-varying volatility or because of rapid, unexpected changes—also known as jumps. Addressing global climate change is likely to require broad-based deployment of new infrastructure. This new infrastructure is likely to be both costly to build and difficult to reverse—suggesting the deployment of new infrastructure is an example of “investment under uncertainty” [1]. In this context, a key concept is the “option value of waiting,” i.e., the potential gain in value that arises from waiting to learn more about the evolution of some key underlying stochastic ingredient, such as a commodity price or the cost of a carbon permit. We argue that this option value of waiting is likely to be increased by the presence of jumps. Assuming there is some urgency in undertaking these investments, the increase in option value of waiting is worrisome and motivates the deployment of a policy intervention that reduces this option value.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Many applications in this genre refer to the investment under uncertainty problem with the moniker “real options”. We will occasionally use this phrase in the pursuant discussion.

  2. A similar point can be made in regards to uncertainty about climate policy, for example whether or not the USA will adopt some form of carbon pricing [56].

  3. An alternative approach to allowing for large discrete changes in prices is to use a regime switching model. Papers that have adopted such a framework typically use a Markov switching model, wherein there are a small finite number of states (often 2), and where the probability of moving from one state to another becomes a focus of the investigation. [39] use a regime switching model in their investigation of optimal storage, and [51] employ such an approach to analyze Henry Hub NYMEX futures prices between February 2003 and July 2007. Their results indicate 22 switches during this period, and exhibit long periods of non-switching. While these authors provide a thorough analysis of the switching model, they also note that “[a]n obvious improvement would be to include price jumps within each regime” (p. 174).

  4. These energy markets can be correlated [52]; [49] and [55] demonstrate a link between UK natural gas prices and European crude prices. On the other hand, [, p. 48] argue that there has been a fundamental change in the relationship between oil and gas prices after 2000. And while the data from 2000 - 2006 is reflective of emerging technological trends, it predates the major burst in gas production that followed the widespread application of fracking.50

  5. This implicitly assumes the quantity delivered is fixed, i.e. supply is perfectly inelastic. More generally, an upward-sloping supply curve would induce quantity as a function of price. Adapting the model to allow for such a structure is feasible, but at the cost of considerable extra complexity. See [, pp. 195-199] for discussion.1

  6. In the pursuant discussion, we will often suppress the time subscript so as to reduce notational clutter.

  7. One aspect of the GBM process is that changes tend to exert an effect for a considerable length of time. An alternative approach would be to use a model in which the effect of changes in X tend to dissipate relatively more rapidly—for example, a mean-reverting process. Analysis such a process is more complicated, though the broad principles we describe in this section still apply [1].

  8. Details can be found in [1], pp. 71–72.

  9. Some authors model price jumps using a Lévy process, an approach that requires an ex ante definition of a jump. For example, [30] define a jump as an observation that falls outside of 2 standard deviations from the mean. Other authors assume jumps follow a Poisson process; one advantage of this approach is that there is no need to arbitrarily define a jump ex ante.

  10. The process described in eq. (11) is characterized by four parameters, \(\mu , \kappa , \alpha _1\) and \(\beta _1\). There is a general consensus in the literature is that a GARCH model with a limited number of terms performs reasonably well, and so we restrict our focus to this more parsimonious representation.

  11. This data is publicly available at https://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/pet_stoc_wstk_dcu_nus_w.html

  12. See [40] for a discussion of the mechanics of constructing these estimated jump probabilities.

  13. This data is publicly available at https://bakerhughesrigcount.gcs-web.com/na-rig-count.

  14. Our goal with this line of investigation is to assess the role of volatility, as opposed to producing a detailed investigation of drilling per se. For a detailed investigation of factors influencing drilling for oil, see [53]. Investigations of factors impacting drilling for natural gas are contained in [8, 54]. We note that rig counts are not reported for natural gas in two weeks, corresponding to the first week of 2004 and the Easter week of 2009; accordingly, there are 2 more observations for crude oil (836 vs. 834).

  15. One way to think about this step is that a Taylor’s series expansion has been executed, with higher order terms dropped.

References

  1. Dixit, A. K., & Pindyck, R. S. (1994). Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  2. Core Writing Team, R. K. Pachauri, & L. A. Meyer. (2014). Climate change 2014: Synthesis report. contribution of working groups I, II and III to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.

  3. Kellogg, R. (2014). The effect of uncertainty on investment: Evidence from texas oil drilling. American Economic Review, 104, 1698–1734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Weitzman, M. (2009). On modeling and interpreting the economics of catastrophic climate change. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Chevallier, J., & Ielpo, F. (2014). Twenty years of jumps in commodity markets. International Review of Applied Economics, 28(1), 64–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Chevallier, J., & Sévi, B. (2014). On the stochastic properties of carbon futures prices. Environmental and Resource Economics, 58, 127–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Gronwald, M. (2012). A characterization of oil price behavior - evidence from jump models. Energy Economics, 34, 1310–1317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Mason, C. F., & Wilmot, N. A. (2014). Jump processes in natural gas markets. Energy Economics, 46, S69–S79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Almansour, A., & Insley, M. (2017). The impact of stochastic extraction cost on the value of an exhaustible resource: An application to the Alberta oil sands. The Energy Journal, 37, 61–88.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Conrad, J. M., & Kotani, K. (2005). When to drill? Trigger prices for the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge. Resource and Energy Economics, 27, 273–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Davis, G. A., & Lund, D. (2018). Taxation and investment decisions in petroleum. The Energy Journal, 39, 189–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Davis, R. J., & Sims, C. (2019). Frack to the future: What enticed small firms to enter the natural gas market during the hydraulic fracturing boom? Energy Economics, 81, 960–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Cortazar, Gonzalo, & Casassus, Jaime. (1998). Optimal timing of a mine expansion: Implementing a real options model. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 38, 755–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Insley, M. (2017). Resource extraction with a carbon tax and regime switching prices: Exercising your options. Energy Economics, 67, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Mason, C. F. (2001). Nonrenewable resources with switching costs. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 42, 65–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Muehlenbachs, L. (2015). A dynamic model of cleanup: Estimating sunk costs in oil and gas production. International Economic Review, 56, 155–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Paddock, J. L., Siegel, D. R., & Smith, J. L. (1988). Option Valuation of Claims on Real Assets: The Case of Offshore Petroleum Leases. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(3), 479–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Slade, M. E. (2001). Valuing managerial flexibility: An application of real-option theory to mining investments. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 41, 193–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Conrad, J. M. (1997). Global warming: When to bite the bullet. Land Economics, 73, 164–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Pindyck, R. S. (2002). Optimal timing problems in environmental economics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26, 1677–1697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Pindyck, R. S. (2007). Uncertainty in environmental economics. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1, 45–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Narita, D., & Klepper, G. (2016). Economic incentives for carbon dioxide storage under uncertainty: A real options analysis. International Journal of Greenhouse Gas Control, 53, 18–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Szolgayova, J., Fuss, S., & Obersteiner, M. (2008). Assessing the effects of co2 price caps on electricity investments - a real options analysis. Energy Policy, 36, 3974–3981.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Bistline, J. E. (2014). Natural gas, uncertainty, and climate policy in the US electric power sector. Energy Policy, 74, 433–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Pindyck, R. S. (2004). Volatility in oil and gas markets. The Journal of Energy and Development, 30, 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Shafiee, S., & Topal, E. (2010). A long-term view of worldwide fossil fuel prices. Applied Energy, 87, 988–1000.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Askari, H., & Krichene, N. (2008). Oil price dynamics (2002–2006). Energy Economics, 30, 2134–2153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Postali, F. A., & Picchetti, P. (2006). Geometric Brownian Motion and structural breaks in oil prices: A quantitative analysis. Energy Economics, 28, 506–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Wilmot, N. A., & Mason, C. F. (2013). Jump processes in the market for crude oil. The Energy Journal, 34, 33–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Benth, F. E., Saltyte-Benth, J., & Koekbakker, S. (2008). Stochastic Modelling of Electricity and Related Markets. River Edge, NJ: World Scientific.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  31. Alberola, E., Chevallier, J., & Chèze, B. (2008). Price drivers and structural breaks in European carbon prices 2005–2007. Energy Policy, 36(2), 787–797.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Daskalakis, G., Psychoyios, D., & Markellos, R. N. (2009). Modeling CO2 emission allowance prices and derivatives: Evidence from the European trading scheme. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33, 1230–1241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Ansari, E., and Kaufmann, R. K. (2019). The effect of oil and gas price and price volatility on rig activity in tight formations and OPEC strategy. Nature Energy, 4, 321–328.

  34. Hammoudeh, S., Nguyen, D. K., & Sousa, R. M. (2014). What explain the short-term dynamics of the prices of CO2 emissions? Energy Economics, 46, 122–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Wilmot, N. A. (2016). Discontinuities in the coal market. Applied Economics Letters, 23, 790–794.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Xiaoming, L., Wan, K., & Ruiyu, L. (2012). Analysis on characteristics of coal price’s volatility: Based on GARCH model. Technology Economics, 4, 12.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Huisman, R., & Mahieu, R. (2003). Regime jumps in electricity prices. Energy Economics, 25, 425–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Thompson, M., Davison, M., & Rasmussen, H. (2009). Natural gas storage valuation and optimization: A real options application. Naval Research Logisitcs (NRL), 56, 226–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Chen, Z., & Forsyth, P. A. (2010). Implications of a regime-switching model on natural gas storage valuation and optimal operation. Quantitative Finance, 10, 159–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Mason, C. F., & Wilmot, N. A. (2020). Jumps in the convenience yield of crude oil. Resource and Energy Economics, 60, 101163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Wilmot, N. A. (2010). Investment under Uncertainty Utilizing Alternative Stochastic Processes. University of Wyoming.

  42. Mason, C. F. (2011). On stockpiling natural resources. Resource and Energy Economics, 33, 398–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Williams, J. C., & Wright, B. D. (1991). Storage and Commodity Markets. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  44. Fitzgerald, T., & Mason, C. F. (2021). Whose frac is it, anyway? Using sources of productivity gains to explain industrial organization in oilfield services. University of Wyoming.

  45. Gold, R. (2014). The Boom: How Fracking Ignited the American Energy Revolution and Changed the World. New York: Simon and Schuster Paperbacks.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Sinn, H.-W. (2017). Buffering volatility: A study on the limits of Germany’s energy revolution. European Economic Review, 99, 130–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Gollier, C., & Treich, N. (2003). Decision-making under scientific uncertainty: The economics of the precautionary principle. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27, 77–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Lange, A., & Moslener, U. (2004). A bird in the hand is worth two in the bush? When do we prefer something certainly dirty to something perhaps clean? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty29(1), 35-51.

  49. Asche, F., Osmundsen, P., & Sandsmark, M. (2006). The UK market for natural gas, oil and electricity: Are the prices decoupled? The Energy Journal, 27, 27–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Brown, S. P. A., & Yücel, M. K. (2008). What drives natural gas prices? The Energy Journal, 29, 45–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Chen, Z., & Forsyth, P. A. (2007). A semi-Lagrangean approach for natural gas storage valuation and optimal operation. SIAM Journal of Scientific Computing, 30, 339–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Gonzalez-Pedraz, C., Moreno, M., & Peña, J. I. (2014). Tail risk in energy portfolios. Energy Economics, 46, 422–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Newell, R. G., & Prest, B. C. (2019). The unconventional oil supply boom: Aggregate price response from microdata. The Energy Journal, 40, 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Newell, R. G., Prest, B. C., & Vissing, A. (2019). Trophy hunting vs. manufacturing energy: The price-responsiveness of shale gas. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 6, 391–431.

  55. Panagiotidis, T., & Rutledge, E. J. (2007). Oil and gas markets in the U.K.: Evidence from a co-integrating approach. Energy Economics, 29, 329–347.

  56. Prest, B., Burtraw, D., & Palmer, K. (2021). Waiting for clarity: How a price on carbon can inspire investment. Resources for the Future.

  57. Sadorsky, P. (1999). Oil price shocks and stock market activity. Energy Economics, 21, 449–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank two referees and the Advisory Editor for constructive feedback, which has improved the presentation of our manuscript. All remaining errors are the authors sole responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Mason summarized existing literature, described GBM model, conducted regressions and wrote 2/3 of the paper; Wilmot summarized literature, ran simulations, and wrote 1/3 of the draft.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Charles F. Mason.

Ethics declarations

Ethical approval

Not applicable

Conflict of interest

None.

Appendix

Appendix

In this Appendix, we provide the mathematical details underlying our numerical simulations. We start by fleshing out the problem under geometric Brownian motion (GBM) process. As noted in eq. (4), the optimal value function satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} \rho F(X)= \frac{1}{dt}E[\text {d}(F)]. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

We proceed by expanding the expression on the right-hand side, which gives rise toFootnote 15

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{dt}E[\text {d}(F)] = \alpha X F^{\, \prime }(X) + \frac{1}{2} \sigma ^2 X^2 F^{\, \prime \prime }(X). \end{aligned}$$

As a result, the fundamental equation of optimality reduces to the second-order differential equation

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{2} \sigma ^2 X^2 F^{\, \prime \prime }(X) + \alpha X F^{\, \prime }(X) - \rho F(X) = 0; \end{aligned}$$
(13)

the generic solution of this differential equation is the power function

$$\begin{aligned} F(X) = a X^\beta . \end{aligned}$$

Inserting this form into the fundamental equation of optimality, taking derivatives as appropriate, and combining terms leads to the characteristic equation

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\sigma ^2}{2} \beta (\beta -1)+ \alpha \beta - \rho = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(14)

which the parameter \(\beta\) must satisfy. There are two roots, which we denote as \(\beta _1\) and \(\beta _2\); it is easy to see that these roots satisfy \(\beta _1 < 0\) and \(\beta _2 > 1\). The complete solution to the fundamental equation of optimality is then

$$\begin{aligned} F(X)= a_1 X^{\beta _1} + a_2 X^{\beta _2}. \end{aligned}$$

The solution must also satisfy a boundary condition, namely that the optimal value becomes negligible as the spot price becomes very small (since it will almost surely not be optimal to invest under those conditions, the option to wait is essentially worthless). Since \(\beta _1 < 0\), the first term describing F would be unbounded if slope parameter \(a_1\) were non-zero. Hence, the requirement that F tends to zero as X tend to zero implies \(a_1 = 0\). Accordingly, the value function can be simplified to

$$\begin{aligned} F(X)= a X^{\beta }, \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where we have substituted a for \(a_2\) and \(\beta\) for \(\beta _2\) to reduce notational clutter.

In addition, the solution must satisfy two other conditions, the “value-matching condition” and the “smooth-pasting condition” [1]. At \(X^*\), the point at which it is optimal to build, the value-matching condition requires that the value of building equals the value of waiting:

$$\begin{aligned} F(X^*) = X^* - K. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Because the value function F(X) can be interpreted as the value of an option to invest in the future [1], this value must equal the difference between the value upon investing when the value of investing immediately, \(X^*\), and the sunk cost of investing, K. The smooth-pasting condition requires that the slope of the optimal value function equals 1, the slope of the function reflecting the value of waiting [1]. Accordingly,

$$\begin{aligned} a(X^*)^\beta = X^* - K; \end{aligned}$$
(17)
$$\begin{aligned} a \beta (X^*)^{(\beta -1)} = 1. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Multiplying both sides of eq. (18) by \(X^*/\beta\), substituting into eq. (17) and rearranging then yields eq. (7) in the text.

Now suppose the value X evolves according to the mixed jump-diffusion process

$$\begin{aligned} dX = \tilde{\alpha } X dt + \sigma X dz + (Y-1)dq, \end{aligned}$$

where as above dz is an increment of a standard Weiner process; here, we interpret Y as the magnitude of a jump if it occurs, and dq as an increment of a Poisson process (which captures the probability that a jump occurs). Because the term capturing jumps will add something to the expected value, the mean term (\(\alpha\) in the GBM representation) must be adjusted. Denoting the arrival rate under the Poisson process by \(\lambda\), and the mean value of a jump (should one occur) by \(\theta\), the drift term is [41]

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{dt}E[\text {d}(F)]{X} = \alpha^{+} = \alpha + \lambda \theta . \end{aligned}$$

In this setting, the equation governing optimal value function is more complicated than that of eq. (13). Here, the equation governing the optimal value function is determined by the interaction between jump size, Y, and continuation value, V:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{2} \sigma ^2 X^2 F^{\, \prime \prime }(X) + \tilde{\alpha } X F^{\, \prime }(X) + \lambda \int _0^{\infty } F(XY) G(Y) dY = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

where G(J) is the probability density function governing jump size. As with the GBM problem, the solution here is governed by the value-matching condition (5), as well as a smooth-pasting condition. This equation cannot be solved analytically, and so we use numerical methods as discussed in Sect. 4.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mason, C.F., Wilmot, N.A. Energy Price Jumps, Fat Tails and Climate Policy. Environ Model Assess 27, 993–1005 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-021-09795-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-021-09795-1

Keywords

Navigation