Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal Harvesting Policies Threaten Biodiversity in Mixed Fisheries

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

As marine ecosystems are under pressure worldwide, many scientists and stakeholders advocate the use of ecosystem-based approaches for fishery management. In particular, management policies are expected to account for the multispecies nature of fisheries. However, numerous fisheries management plans remain based on single-species concepts, such as maximum sustainable yield (MSY) and maximum economic yield (MEY), that respectively aim at maximizing catches or profits of single species or stocks. In this study, we assess the bioeconomic sustainability of multispecies MSY and MEY in a mixed fishery, characterized by technical interactions and therefore joint production. First, we analytically show how multispecies MSY and MEY can induce overharvesting and extinction of species with low productivity and low value. Second, we identify and discuss incentives on effort costs and landing prices, as well as technical regulations, that could promote biodiversity conservation and more globally sustainability. Finally, a numerical example based on the coastal fishery in French Guiana illustrates the analytical findings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We assume that r0/q0 = 0.

  2. We assume that r0/q0 = 0.

References

  1. Acheson, J. (1988). Patterns of gear changes in the Maine fishing industry: some implications for management. Marine Anthropological Studies, 1(1), 49–65.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Anderson, L. (1975). Analysis of open-access commercial exploitation and maximum economic yield in biologically and technologically interdependent fisheries. Journal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada, 32(10), 1825–1842. https://doi.org/10.1139/f75-217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Arreguin-Sanchez, F. (1996). Catchability: a key parameter for fish stock assessment. Reviews in Fish Biology and Fisheries, 6, 221–242. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00182344. http://link.springer.com/10.1007/BF00182344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Border, K. (2013). Alternative linear inequalities. Tech. rep., Caltech.

  5. Boyd, S., & Vandenberghe, L. (2004). Convex optimization. Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1109/TAC.2006.884922.

  6. Brown, G., Berger, B., Ikiara, M. (2005). A predator-prey model with an application to Lake Victoria fisheries. Marine Resource Economics, 20(3), 221–248. https://doi.org/10.1086/mre.20.3.42629473. http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/10.1086/mre.20.3.42629473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Burgess, M., Diekert, F., Jacobsen, N., Andersen, K., Gaines, S. (2015). Remaining questions in the case for balanced harvesting. Fish and Fisheries. https://doi.org/10.1111/faf.12123.

  8. Chaudhuri, K. (1986). A bioeconomic model of harvesting a multispecies fishery. Ecological Modelling, 32(4), 267–279. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3800(86)90091-8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Cissė, A., Doyen, L., Blanchard, F., Bėnė, C., Pėreau, J.C. (2015). Ecoviability for small-scale fisheries in the context of food security constraints. Ecological Economics, 119, 39–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Cissė, A., Gourguet, S., Doyen, L., Blanchard, F., Pėreau, J.C. (2013). A bio-economic model for the ecosystem-based management of the coastal fishery in French Guiana. Environment and Development Economics, 18(3), 245–269. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1355770X13000065.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Clark, C. (1973). The economics of overexploitation. Science, 181(4100), 630–634. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.181.4100.630.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  12. Clark, C. (2006). The worldwide crisis in fisheries: economic models and human behaviour. Cambridge University Press.

  13. Clark, C. (2010). Mathematical bioeconomics: the mathematics of conservation, 3rd Edn. Wiley.

  14. Clark, C., & Munro, G. (1975). The economics of fishing and modern capital theory: a simplified approach. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 2, 92–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Clark, C., Munro, G., Sumaila, U. (2010). Limits to the privatization of fishery resources. Land Economics, 86(2), 209–218. https://doi.org/10.1353/lde.2010.0020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Costello, C., Ovando, D., Clavelle, T., Strauss, C., Hilborn, R., Melnychuk, M., Branch, T., Gaines, S., Szuwalski, C., Cabral, R., Rader, D., Leland, A. (2016). Global fishery prospects under contrasting management regimes. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113 (18), 5125–5129. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1520420113. http://www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.0709640104 http://www.pnas.org/lookup/doi/10.1073/pnas.1520420113.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  17. Dichmont, C., Pascoe, S., Kompas, T., Punt, A., Deng, R. (2010). On implementing maximum economic yield in commercial fisheries. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107(1), 16–21. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0912091107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Doyen, L., Cissė, A., Gourguet, S., Mouysset, L., Hardy, P.Y., Bėnė, C., Blanchard, F., Jiguet, F., Pereau, J.C., Thėbaud, O. (2013). Ecological-economic modelling for the sustainable management of biodiversity. Computational Management Science, 10(4), 353–364. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10287-013-0194-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. European Union: Regulation (EU) No 1380/2013 of the European Parliament and the Council (2013).

  20. FAO. (2016). The state of world fisheries and aquaculture. Tech. rep., Food and Agriculture Organization.

  21. Finnoff, D., & Tschirhart, J. (2003). Harvesting in an eight-species ecosystem. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45, 589–611. https://doi.org/citeulike-article-id:8077890.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Flaaten, O. (1991). Bioeconomics of sustainable harvest of competing species. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 20(2), 163–180. https://doi.org/10.1016/0095-0696(91)90048-N. http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/009506969190048N.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Froese, R., Walters, C., Pauly, D., Winker, H., Weyl, O., Demirel, N., Tsikliras, A., Holt, S. (2015). A critique of the balanced harvesting approach to fishing. ICES Journal of Marine Science, 11. https://doi.org/10.1093/icesjms/fsv122.

  24. Garcia, S., Kolding, J., Rice, J., Rochet, M.J., Zhou, S., Arimoto, T., Beyer, J.E., Borges, L., Bundy, A., Dunn, D., Fulton, E., Hall, M., Heino, M., Law, R., Makino, M., Rijnsdorp, A., Simard, F., Smith, A. (2012). Reconsidering the consequences of selective fisheries. Science, 335(6072), 1045–1047. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1214594.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  25. Gourguet, S., Macher, C., Doyen, L., Thébaud, O., Bertignac, M., Guyader, O. (2013). Managing mixed fisheries for bio-economic viability. Fisheries Research, 140, 46–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fishres.2012.12.005. http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0165783612003499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Grafton, R., Kompas, T., Chu, L., Che, N. (2010). Maximum economic yield. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 54(3), 273–280. http://doi.wiley.com/10.1111/j.1467-8489.2010.00492.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Grafton, R., Kompas, T., Hilborn, R. (2007). Economics of overexploitation revisited. Science, 318 (5856), 1601–1601. http://www.sciencemag.org/cgi/doi/10.1126/science.1146017.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  28. Guillen, J., Macher, C., Merzėrėaud, M., Bertignac, M., Fifas, S., Guyader, O. (2013). Estimating MSY and MEY in multi-species and multi-fleet fisheries, consequences and limits: an application to the Bay of Biscay mixed fishery. Marine Policy, 40, 64–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2012.12.029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Hannesson, R. (1983). Optimal harvesting of ecologically interdependent fish species. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 10(4), 329–345. https://doi.org/10.1016/0095-0696(83)90003-7. http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/0095069683900037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Harley, S., Myers, R., Dunn, A. (2001). Is catch-per-unit-effort proportional to abundance? Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, 58(9), 1760–1772. https://doi.org/10.1139/cjfas-58-9-1760. File Attachments http://www.nrc.ca/cgi-bin/cisti/journals/rp/rp2_abst_e?cjfas_f01-112_58_ns_nf_cjfas58-01.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Kramer, D. (2008). Adaptive harvesting in a multiple-species coral-reef food web. Ecology and Society, 13(1).

  32. Larkin, P. (1977). An epitaph for the concept of maximum sustained yield. Transactions of the American Fisheries Society, 106(1), 1–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Legoviċ, T., & Geček, S. (2010). Impact of maximum sustainable yield on independent populations. Ecological Modelling, 221, 2108–2111. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2010.05.015.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Legoviċ, T., Klanjšček, J., Geček, S. (2010). Maximum sustainable yield and species extinction in ecosystems. Ecological Modelling, 221(12), 1569–1574. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2010.03.024.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Mace, P. (2001). A new role for MSY in single-species and ecosystem approaches to fisheries stock assessment and management. Fish and Fisheries, 2, 2–32. https://doi.org/10.1046/j.1467-2979.2001.00033.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Matsuda, H., & Abrams, P. (2006). Maximal yields from multispecies fisheries systems: rules for systems with multiple trophic levels. Ecological Applications, 16(1), 225–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. McWhinnie, S. (2009). The tragedy of the commons in international fisheries: an empirical examination. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 57(3), 321–333. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2008.07.008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Moffitt, E., Punt, A., Holsman, K., Aydin, K., Ianelli, J., Ortiz, I. (2015). Moving towards ecosystem-based fisheries management: options for parameterizing multi-species biological reference points. Deep Sea Research Part II: Topical Studies in Oceanography. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.dsr2.2015.08.002.

  39. Mueter, F., & Megrey, B. (2006). Using multi-species surplus production models to estimate ecosystem-level maximum sustainable yields. Fisheries Research, 81(2-3), 189–201. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fishres.2006.07.010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. NOAA: Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act (2007).

  41. Pascoe, S., Hutton, T., Thėbaud, O., Deng, R., Klaer, N., Vieira, S. (2015). Setting economic target reference points for multiple species in mixed fisheries. Tech. rep., Fisheries Research and Development Corporation.

  42. Patrick, W., & Link, J. (2015). Hidden in plain sight: using optimum yield as a policy framework to operationalize ecosystem-based fisheries management. Marine Policy, 62, 74–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Pėreau, J. C., Doyen, L., Little, L., Thėbaud, O. (2012). The triple bottom line: meeting ecological, economic and social goals with individual transferable quotas. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 63(3), 419–434. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2012.01.001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Pikitch, E., Santora, C., Babcock, E., Bakun, A., Bonfil, R., Conover, D., Dayton, P., Doukakis, P., Fluharty, D., Heneman, B., Houde, E., Link, J., Livingston, P., Mangel, M., McAllister, M., Pope, J., Sainsbury, K. (2004). Ecosystem-based fishery management. Science, 305(5682), 346–347. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1098222.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  45. Plagȧnyi, E. (2007). Models for an ecosystem approach to fisheries. Tech. rep., FAO Rome.

  46. Ricker, W. (1958). Maximum sustained yields from fluctuating environments and mixed stocks. Journal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada, 15(5), 991–1006. https://doi.org/10.1139/f58-054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Sanchirico, J., Smith, M., Lipton, D. (2008). An empirical approach to ecosystem-based fishery management. Ecological Economics, 64(3), 586–596. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.04.006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Sumaila, U., Khan, A., Dyck, A., Watson, R., Munro, G., Tydemers, P., Pauly, D. (2010). A bottom-up re-estimation of global fisheries subsidies. Journal of Bioeconomics, 12(3), 201–225. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-010-9091-8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Swanson, T. (1994). The economics of extinction revisited and revised: a generalised framework for the analysis of the problems of endangered species and biodiversity losses. Oxford Economic Papers, 46, 800–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Tromeur, E., & Loeuille, N. (2017). Balancing yield with resilience and conservation objectives in harvested predator-prey communities. Oikos, 126(12), 1780–1789. http://doi.wiley.com/10.1111/oik.03985.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Ulrich, C., Gascuel, D., Dunn, M., Le Gallic, B., Dintheer, C. (2001). Estimations of technical interactions due to the competition for resource in a mixed-species fishery, and the typology of fleets and métiers in the English Channel. Aquatic Living Resources, 14(5), 267–281. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0990-7440(01)01132-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Voss, R., Quaas, M., Schmidt, J., Hoffmann, J. (2014). Regional trade-offs from multi-species maximum sustainable yield (MMSY) management options. Marine Ecology Progress Series, 498, 1–12. https://doi.org/10.3354/meps10639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Walters, C. (2003). Folly and fantasy in the analysis of spatial catch rate data. Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, 60(12), 1433–1436. http://www.nrcresearchpress.com/doi/abs/10.1139/f03-152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Walters, C.J., Christensen, V., Martell, S.J., Kitchell, J. (2005). Possible ecosystem impacts of applying MSY policies from single-species assessment. ICES Journal of Marine Science, 62(3), 558–568. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.icesjms.2004.12.005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  55. Weitzman, M. (2002). Landing fees vs harvest quotas with uncertain fish stocks. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(2), 325–338. https://doi.org/10.1006/jeem.2000.1181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  56. World Bank. (2017). The Sunken Billions Revisited. Tech. rep., World Bank.

  57. Worm, B., Barbier, E., Beaumont, N., Duffy, J., Folke, C., Halpern, B., Jackson, J., Lotze, H., Micheli, F., Palumbi, S., Sala, E., Selkoe, K., Stachowicz, J., Watson, R. (2006). Impacts of biodiversity loss on ocean ecosystem services. Science, 314, 787–790. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1132294.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  58. Zhang, C., Chen, Y., Ren, Y. (2016). An evaluation of implementing long-term MSY in ecosystem-based fisheries management: incorporating trophic interaction, bycatch and uncertainty. Fisheries Research, 174, 179–189. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fishres.2015.10.007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Zhou, S., Smith, A., Punt, A., Richardson, A., Gibbs, M., Fulton, E., Pascoe, S., Bulman, C., Bayliss, P., Sainsbury, K. (2010). Ecosystem-based fisheries management requires a change to the selective fishing philosophy. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107(21), 9485–9489. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0912771107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Fabian Blanchard and Abdoul Cissé who provided useful insights into the case study of the fishery in French Guiana. We are also grateful to two anonymous reviewers for comments that greatly improved this manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by the following projects: SEAVIEW (funded by the Belmont Forum, ANR-14-JPF1-0003), ANR ACROSS (ANR-14-CE03-0001), ANR RESUS (ANR-14-CE03-0009), NAVIRE (Cluster of Excellence COTE, ANR-10-LABX-45), PIG CNRS VOGUE, and PIG CNRS ECOPE.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric Tromeur.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

In this Appendix, we aim at solving the following optimization problem:

$$ \max_{e } \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e. $$
(31)

We consider that species are ranked according to their biotechnical productivities, as expressed in Eq. 6. Then, for a given effort e,Footnote 1

$$ \text{if} \exists j \in \{ 1 {\ldots} N \}, \text{so that} \frac{r_{j-1}}{q_{j-1}} \leq e < \frac{r_{j}}{q_{j}}, $$
(32)

as for every i < j, we have \(x_{i}^{+}(e)= 0\), we deduce that

$$ \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e = \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e $$
(33)

As a result, for a given effort e, total catches can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e &=& \sum\limits_{i=j(e)}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e, \text{with} \\ j(e)&=& \min \left( i \in \{ 1 {\ldots} N \}, e < \frac{r_{i}}{q_{i}} \right). \end{array} $$
(34)

Therefore, optimization problem (31) can be written as follows:

$$ \max_{e } \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e = \max_{e} \sum\limits_{i=j(e)}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e, $$
(35)

where j(e) is defined in Eq. 34. Denote by e an optimal solution of this problem, and by j = j(e) the corresponding first non-extinct species. By definition, optimal solutions verify the following condition:

$$ \frac{r_{j^{*}-1}}{q_{j^{*}-1}} \leq e^{*} < \frac{r_{j^{*}}}{q_{j^{*}}}. $$
(36)

As j is the surviving species with the lowest biotechnical productivity, species j to N are not extinct at MMSY, and their biomasses are thus larger than zero. The optimization problem (31) is then equivalent to:

$$ \max_{e} \left( \sum\limits_{i=j^{*}}^{N} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e \right), $$
(37)

The optimal effort can be computed by using first-order optimality conditions:

$$ \frac{\partial \left( {\sum}_{i=j^{*}}^{N} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e \right)}{\partial e} = 0. $$
(38)

We obtain

$$ e^{*} = \frac{1}{2} \frac{{\sum}_{i=j^{*}}^{N} r_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1}}{{\sum}_{i=j^{*}}^{N} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}}. $$
(39)

Consequently, the optimal value j can be computed by solving the following problem:

$$ \max_{j} \left( \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} x_{i}^{+}(e^{*}) q_{i} e^{*} \right), $$
(40)

where e is computed relative to j, following Eq. 39. As optimal solutions verify condition (36), surviving species at MMSY display positive biomasses, and this problem is equivalent to:

$$ \max_{j} \left( \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e^{*}}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e^{*} \right). $$
(41)

The expression of total catches can be simplified as follows:

$$ \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e^{*}}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e^{*}=e^{*} \left( \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} r_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} - e^{*} \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1} \right) $$
(42)

By replacing the effort with its optimal expression as given in Eq. 39, we obtain:

$$ \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e^{*}}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e^{*}=\frac{1}{4} \frac{\left( {\sum}_{i=j}^{N} r_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} \right)^{2}}{{\sum}_{i=j}^{N} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}} $$
(43)

The optimal j is thus the solution of the following optimization problem:

$$ j^{*} = \underset{j = 1 {\ldots} N}{\arg\!\max} \left( \frac{1}{4} \frac{\left( {\sum}_{i=j}^{N} r_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} \right)^{2}}{{\sum}_{i=j}^{N} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}} \right). $$
(44)

1.2 A.2 Proof of Proposition 2

In this Appendix, we aim at solving the following optimization problem:

$$ \max_{e } \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e - c e. $$
(45)

We consider that species are ranked according to their biotechnical productivities, as expressed in Eq. 6. Then, for a given effort e,Footnote 2

$$ \text{if} \exists j \in \{ 1 {\ldots} N \}, \text{so that} \frac{r_{j-1}}{q_{j-1}} \leq e < \frac{r_{j}}{q_{j}}, $$
(46)

as for every i < j we have \(x_{i}^{+}(e)= 0\), we deduce that

$$ \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e - c e = \sum\limits_{i=j}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e - \text{c e} $$
(47)

As a result, for a given effort e, total profits can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e -\text{c e} \!&=&\! \sum\limits_{i=k(e)}^{N} \!\!p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e - \text{c e}, \text{with} \\ k(e)\!&=&\! \min \left( \!i \!\in \!\{ 1 {\ldots} N \}, e \!< \frac{r_{i}}{q_{i}} \right). \end{array} $$
(48)

Therefore, optimization problem (45) can be written as follows:

$$ \max_{e } \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e - \text{c e} = \max_{e} \sum\limits_{i=k(e)}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e) q_{i} e - \text{c e} , $$
(49)

where k(e) is defined in Eq. 48. Denote by e an optimal solution of this problem, and by k = k(e) the corresponding first non-extinct species. By definition, optimal solutions verify the following condition:

$$ \frac{r_{k^{*}-1}}{q_{k^{*}-1}} \leq e^{*} < \frac{r_{k^{*}}}{q_{k^{*}}}. $$
(50)

As k is the surviving species with the lowest biotechnical productivity, species k to N are not extinct at MMEY, and their biomasses are thus larger than zero. The optimization problem (45) is then equivalent to:

$$ \max_{e} \left( {\sum}_{i=k^{*}}^{N} p_{i} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e - \text{c e} \right), $$
(51)

The optimal effort can be computed by using first-order optimality conditions:

$$ \frac{\partial \left( {\sum}_{i=k^{*}}^{N} p_{i} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e - \text{ce} \right)}{\partial e} = 0. $$
(52)

We obtain:

$$ e^{*} = \frac{1}{2} \frac{{\sum}_{i=k^{*}}^{N} r_{i} p_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} - c}{{\sum}_{i=k^{*}}^{N} p_{i} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}}. $$
(53)

Consequently, the optimal value k can be computed by solving the following problem:

$$ \max_{k} \left( \sum\limits_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} x_{i}^{+}(e^{*}) q_{i} e^{*} - \text{c e}^{*} \right), $$
(54)

where e is computed relative to k, following Eq. 53. As optimal solutions verify condition (50), surviving species at MMEY display positive biomasses, and this problem is equivalent to:

$$ \max_{k} \left( \sum\limits_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e^{*}}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e^{*} - \text{c e}^{*} \right). $$
(55)

The expression of total profits can be simplified as follows:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\sum\limits_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e^{*}}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e^{*} - \text{c e}^{*}\\ &=& e^{*} \left( \sum\limits_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} r_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} - e^{*} \sum\limits_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1} - c \right) \end{array} $$
(56)

By replacing the effort with its optimal expression as given in Eq. 53, we obtain:

$$ \sum\limits_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} \left( \frac{r_{i} - q_{i} e^{*}}{s_{i}} \right) q_{i} e^{*} - \text{c e}^{*}=\frac{1}{4} \frac{\left( {\sum}_{i=k}^{N} r_{i} p_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} - c \right)^{2}}{{\sum}_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}} $$
(57)

The optimal k is thus the solution of the following optimization problem:

$$ k^{*} = \underset{k = 1 {\ldots} N}{\arg\!\max} \left( \frac{1}{4} \frac{\left( {\sum}_{i=k}^{N} r_{i} p_{i} q_{i} s_{i}^{-1} - c \right)^{2}}{{\sum}_{i=k}^{N} p_{i} {q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}} \right). $$
(58)

1.3 A.3 Proof of Proposition 4

Let us consider that species k has the lowest MSY effort \(e_{k}^{\textsc {msy}}\). Species k is overharvested at MMSY if the following difference is positive:

$$ \sum\limits_{i=j^{*}}^{N} \alpha_{i} e_{i}^{\textsc{msy}} - e_{k}^{\textsc{msy}}=\sum\limits_{i=j^{*}}^{N} \alpha_{i} (e_{i}^{\textsc{msy}} - e_{k}^{\textsc{msy}}), $$
(59)

as \({\sum }_{i=j^{*}}^{N} \alpha _{i} = 1\). From Eq. 14, this sum is greater or equal to zero. But if at least two species differ in the sense that \(e_{i}^{\textsc {msy}}<e_{j}^{\textsc {msy}}\), then this sum becomes strictly positive. Species k is then overharvested at MMSY. Using a similar proof relying on the ranking (14), it can be shown that the species with the largest MSY effort is always underharvested at MMSY.

1.4 A.4 Proof of Proposition 9

Let \(p_{k}^{\prime }=p_{k}+\tau _{k}\) be the subsidized price of species k, with τk positive. We suppose that the subsidy does not change the number of harvested species, so that k keeps the same value. Then,

$$ e^{\textsc{mmey}^{\prime}} = \frac{1}{2}\frac{{\sum}_{i=k^{*}}^{N} r_{i}p_{i}q_{i}s_{i}^{-1} - c + r_{k}q_{k}s_{k}^{-1}\tau_{k}}{{\sum}_{i=k^{*}}^{N} p_{i}{q_{i}^{2}}s_{i}^{-1} + {q_{k}^{2}}s_{k}^{-1}\tau_{k}}=\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma + \delta \tau_{k}}{\rho + \phi \tau_{k}}, $$
(60)

with \(\gamma ={\sum }_{i = 1}^{N} r_{i}p_{i}q_{i}s_{i}^{-1}-c\), \(\delta =r_{k}q_{k}s_{k}^{-1}\), \(\rho = {\sum }_{i = 1}^{N} p_{i}{q_{i}^{2}}s_{i}^{-1}\) and \(\phi ={q_{k}^{2}}s_{k}^{-1}\). The effect of subsidy τk is given by differentiating this expression with respect to τk:

$$ \frac{\partial e^{\textsc{mmey}^{\prime}}}{\partial \tau_{k}}=\frac{1}{2}\frac{\delta \rho -\gamma \phi}{(\rho+ \phi \tau_{k})^{2}} $$
(61)

This derivative is negative if

$$ \frac{\gamma}{\rho} > \frac{\delta}{\phi} \Leftrightarrow \frac{{\sum}_{i = 1}^{N} r_{i}p_{i}q_{i}s_{i}^{-1}-c}{{\sum}_{i = 1}^{N} p_{i}{q_{i}^{2}}s_{i}^{-1}} > \frac{r_{k}}{q_{k}} \Leftrightarrow e^{\textsc{mmey}} > e_{k}^{\textsc{msy}}. $$
(62)

It means that if species k is overharvested at MMEY (\(e^{\textsc {mmey}}>e_{k}^{\textsc {msy}}\)), subsidies on species k reduce the effort at MMEY and thus improve sustainability. If the new effort becomes lower than \(r_{k^{*}-1} / q_{k^{*}-1}\), then according to the demonstrations of Propositions 1 and 2, a new MMEY effort has to be recomputed that includes species k− 1. Likewise, by considering that \(p_{k}^{\prime }=p_{k}-\tau _{k}\) is the taxed price of species k, it can be found that taxing species that are underharvested at MMEY also reduces the effort at MMEY. Again, if the MMEY effort becomes small enough, this can increase the number of species in the system.

1.5 A.5 Proof of Proposition 10

It is equivalent to proving that a vector of prices can be found that avoids overharvesting at MMEY. From Proposition 8, we know that if \(\forall k \in \left [ 1,...,N \right ], c\geq {\sum }_{i = 1}^{N} \frac {p_{i} {q_{i}^{2}}}{s_{i}} (\frac {r_{i}}{q_{i}}-\frac {r_{k}}{q_{k}})\), that is ccsus as defined in Eq. 20, then all species are either underharvested or fully harvested at MMEY. In matrix form, it is equivalent to: \(\text {MP} \leq \mathcal {C}\), with \( P = \left (\begin {array}{c} p_{1} \\ {\vdots } \\ p_{N} \end {array}\right )\), \( \mathcal {C} = \left (\begin {array}{c} c \\ {\vdots } \\ c \end {array}\right )\) and \( M=\left (\begin {array}{cccccc} 0 & {\ldots } & \frac {{q_{N}^{2}}}{s_{N}}(\frac {r_{N}}{q_{N}}-\frac {r_{1}}{q_{1}}) \\ {\vdots } & {\ddots } & {\vdots } \\ \frac {{q_{1}^{2}}}{s_{1}}(\frac {r_{1}}{q_{1}}-\frac {r_{N}}{q_{N}}) &{\ldots } & 0 \end {array} \right ) \). Following a corollary to Farkas’ lemma described in [4, 5], only one of the following alternatives holds: either ∃ PRN so that \(\text {MP} \leq \mathcal {C}\) and P ≥ 0, or else ∃μRN so that μM ≥ 0, \(\mu ^{\prime } \mathcal {C} < 0\) and μ > 0 (μ being the transpose of vector μ). As \(\mathcal {C} >0\), only the first alternative holds. It is thus always possible to find a system of prices that avoids overharvesting at MMEY, by reducing the effort at MMEY. As reducing the MMEY efforts amounts to subsidizing overharvested species and taxing underharvested species (Proposition 9), it is always possible to find a system of taxes and subsidies that precludes overharvest and extinction at MMEY.

1.6 A.6 Case Study with Ecological Interactions

In this Appendix, we test the validity of the assumption of neglecting trophic interactions in the case study of the coastal fishery in French Guiana. To do this, we study the following system:

$$ x_{i}(t + 1)=x_{i}(t) \left( 1+r_{i} - \sum\limits_{j} s_{\text{ij}}x_{j}(t)-q_{i}e(t) \right), $$
(63)

where sij describes the interaction between species i and j. If i = j, sij describes intraspecific competition. If ij, sij is positive if i preys upon j and negative if j preys upon i. Calibrated parameters are drawn from [9]. As in the main text, we assume that the proportion of each fleet remains constant.

To compute the biomass deviation from MSY, we numerically identify efforts corresponding to all monospecific MSY, to MMSY, and to MMEY. For effort values ranging between 0 and the effort at which all species are extinct, we run the system to equilibrium, and we compute catches of all species. For all effort values, sharks and groupers disappeared in the long term. The preliminary assumption of not considering these two top predators is thus reasonable. We then identify efforts at which catches of each species are maximized, and efforts at which total catches (MMSY) and total profits (MMEY) are maximized. This allows us to compute the biomass deviation from monospecific MSY at MMSY and MMEY. Results are shown in Fig. 5. As in the main text, we only represent species that were not extinct at both MMSY and MMEY. Results are almost exactly similar to results from the main text. Very small differences exist, such as the fact that the biomass deviation at MMEY of the South American silver croaker is slightly closer to zero with trophic interactions. Thus, the assumption of neglecting trophic interactions in the case study of the coastal fishery in French Guiana does not affect our numerical results.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Sustainability of MMSY and MMEY policies in the coastal fishery in French Guiana, in the presence of ecological interactions. Deviation of the harvested species’ biomasses from their MSY levels are shown. A − 100% deviation indicates that the species is extinct. As the Green weakfish, the Common snooks, the Gillbacker sea catfish, the sharks and the groupers are extinct at MMSY and MMEY, their corresponding deviations are not shown on this figure. Abbreviations are explained in Table 1

1.7 A.7 Extension to Other Growth and Production Functions

In this Appendix, we test whether our main results hold with more complex growth and production functions. We focus on MMSY results, as in these cases analytical MMEY results are difficult, if not impossible, to obtain. We first consider the case of a logistically growing population harvested with a Cobb-Douglas production function h = qxaeb. For the sake of a tractable analysis, we consider that a = 1. It comes that the monospecific MSY effort is

$$ e_{i}^{\textsc{msy}} = \left( \frac{r_{i}}{2q_{i}} \right)^{\frac{1}{b}}, $$
(64)

and that the MMSY effort is

$$ e^{\textsc{mmsy}} \!= \left( \!\sum\limits_{i} \alpha_{i} \left( e_{i}^{\textsc{msy}} \right)^{b} \right)^{\frac{1}{b}}, \quad \text{with} \quad \alpha_{i}=\frac{{q_{i}^{2}} s_{i}^{-1}}{{\sum}_{j = 1}^{N} {q_{j}^{2}} s_{j}^{-1}}, $$
(65)

under the assumption that no species extinction occurs at MMSY. Here, the expression of the MMSY effort is a weighted power mean of monospecific MSY efforts. As a consequence, Propositions 4 and 5 are still valid. Note that if b = 1, we find the same result as in Proposition 3.

Let us now consider a model with a Gompertz growth function and a Schaefer harvest function. The model can be written as follows:

$$ x_{i}(t + 1)=x_{i}(t) \left( 1+r_{i} ln\left( \frac{K_{i}}{x_{i}(t)} \right) -q_{i} e \right) $$
(66)

Equilibrium stocks are given by:

$$ x_{i}(e) = K_{i} \exp \left( - \frac{q_{i} e}{r_{i}} \right), $$
(67)

and the monospecific MSY effort is

$$ e_{i}^{\textsc{msy}} = \frac{r_{i}}{q_{i}} $$
(68)

The MMSY effort is then

$$ e^{\textsc{mmsy}} = \frac{1}{{\sum}_{i} \frac{\alpha_{i}}{e_{i}^{\textsc{msy}}}} \qquad \text{with} \qquad \alpha_{i} = \frac{q_{i} x_{i}(e)}{{\sum}_{i} q_{i} x_{i}(e)}, $$
(69)

under the assumption that no species extinction occurs at MMSY. Here, the MMSY effort is a weighted harmonic mean of MSY efforts. Thus, as in the previous case, Propositions 4 and 5 are still valid. Arithmetic, power, and harmonic means all belong to the generalized mean family. Therefore, these results suggest that the MMSY effort can be expressed as a weighted generalized mean, which precise form depends on the type of function considered.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tromeur, E., Doyen, L. Optimal Harvesting Policies Threaten Biodiversity in Mixed Fisheries. Environ Model Assess 24, 387–403 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-018-9618-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-018-9618-2

Keywords

Navigation