Advertisement

Environmental and Resource Economics

, Volume 73, Issue 2, pp 557–590 | Cite as

Optimal Transition from Coal to Gas and Renewable Power Under Capacity Constraints and Adjustment Costs

  • Renaud Coulomb
  • Oskar LecuyerEmail author
  • Adrien Vogt-Schilb
Article

Abstract

Given a cap on carbon emissions, what is the optimal transition from coal to gas and renewable energy? To answer this question, we model the dependence of the energy sector on both (1) polluting exhaustible resources and (2) long-lived capital such as power plants. To minimise adjustment costs, optimal investments in expensive renewable energy start before phasing out fossil-fuel consumption, and may even start before investing in gas-fired plants. Investment in gas-fired plants can reduce the need for expensive renewable investment in the short term, but they eventually need to be decommissioned to make room to carbon-free power in the long term. Simulations of the European Commission’s Energy Roadmap illustrate and quantify these results.

Keywords

Climate change mitigation Low-carbon investment Renewables Fossil fuels Resource extraction Early-scrapping 

JEL Classification

Q54 Q58 

References

  1. Abadie J, Carpentier J (1969) Generalization of the wolfe reduced gradient method to the case of nonlinear constraints. In: Fletcher R (ed) Optimization. Academic Press, New York, p 3747Google Scholar
  2. Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Bursztyn L, Hemous D (2012) The environment and directed technical change. Am Econ Rev 102(1):131–166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Allen MR, Frame DJ, Huntingford C, Jones CD, Lowe JA, Meinshausen M, Meinshausen N (2009) Warming caused by cumulative carbon emissions towards the trillionth tonne. Nature 458(7242):1163–1166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Alley RB, Marotzke J, Nordhaus WD, Overpeck JT, Peteet DM, Pielke RA, Pierrehumbert RT, Rhines PB, Stocker TF, Talley LD, Wallace JM (2003) Abrupt climate change. Science 299(5615):2005–2010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Alvarez RA, Pacala SW, Winebrake JJ, Chameides WL, Hamburg SP (2012) Greater focus needed on methane leakage from natural gas infrastructure. Proc Natl Acad Sci 109(17):6435–6440CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Ambec S, Crampes C (2012) Electricity provision with intermittent sources of energy. Resour Energy Econ 34(3):319–336CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Amigues J-P, Favard P, Gaudet G, Moreaux M (1998) On the optimal order of natural resource use when the capacity of the inexhaustible substitute is limited. J Econ Theory 80(1):153–170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Amigues J-P, Kama AAL, Moreaux M (2015) Equilibrium transitions from non-renewable energy to renewable energy under capacity constraints. J Econ Dyn Control 55:89–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. André FJ, Smulders S (2014) Fueling growth when oil peaks: directed technological change and the limits to efficiency. Eur Econ Rev 69:18–39 (Sustainability and Climate Change: From Theory to Pragmatic Policy) CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Arrow KJ, Kurz M (1970) Optimal growth with irreversible investment in a ramsey model. Econometrica 38(2):331–344CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Atkeson A, Kehoe PJ (1999) Models of energy use: putty–putty versus putty-clay. Am Econ Rev 89(4):1028–1043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Audoly R, Vogt-Schilb A, Guivarch C, Pfeiffer A (2018) Pathways toward zero-carbon electricity required for climate stabilization. Appl Energy 225:884–901.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2018.05.026 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Baker E, Fowlie M, Lemoine D, Reynolds SS (2013) The economics of solar electricity. Ann Rev Resour Econ 5(1):387–426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Blaquière A (1985) Impulsive optimal control with finite or infinite time horizon. J Optim Theory Appl 46:431–439CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. BP (2015) Statistical review of world energy 2015. British Petroleum, LondonGoogle Scholar
  16. Bramoullé Y, Olson LJ (2005) Allocation of pollution abatement under learning by doing. J Public Econ 89(9–10):1935–1960CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Böhringer C, Keller A, Bortolamedi M, Seyffarth AR (2016) Good things do not always come in threes: on the excess cost of overlapping regulation in EU climate policy. Energy Policy 94:502CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Cairns RD (1998) The microeconomics of mineral extraction under capacity constraints. Nonrenewable Resour 7(3):233–244CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Campbell HF (1980) The effect of capital intensity on the optimal rate of extraction of a mineral deposit. Can J Econ 13(2):349–356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Chakravorty U, Magné B, Moreaux M (2006) A hotelling model with a ceiling on the stock of pollution. J Econ Dyn Control 30(12):2875–2904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Chakravorty U, Moreaux M, Tidball M (2008) Ordering the extraction of polluting nonrenewable resources. Am Econ Rev 98(3):1128–1144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Coulomb R, Henriet F (2018) The grey paradox: how fossil-fuel owners can benefit from carbon taxation. J Environ Econ Manag 87:206–223CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Dasgupta P, Heal G (1974) The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources. Rev Econ Stud 41:3–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. del Rio Gonzalez P (2008) Policy implications of potential conflicts between short-term and long-term efficiency in CO\(_2\) emissions abatement. Ecol Econ 65(2):292–303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Drud A (1985) A GRG Code for large sparse dynamic nonlinear optimization problems. Math Programm 31:153191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Drud AS (1992) CONOPT a large-scale GRG code. ORSA J Comput 6:207216Google Scholar
  27. Drud AS (1992) CONOPT A Large-Scale GRG Code. ORSA Journal on Computing 6:207216Google Scholar
  28. ENERDATA (2015) Global Energy & CO\(_2\) Ddatabase. Consulted May 2012Google Scholar
  29. Espey JA, Espey M (2004) Turning on the lights: a meta-analysis of residential electricity demand elasticities. J Agric Appl Econ 36:65–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. EU (2011) Impact assessment accompanying the communication from the commission: energy roadmap 2050. European Commission Staff Working Document Sec (2011) 1569 finalGoogle Scholar
  31. Eurostat (2014) Statistiques de l’Union Européenne. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/. Accessed 1 Feb 2014
  32. EWEA (2014) Wind in Power: 2013 European Statistics. The European Wind AssociationGoogle Scholar
  33. Fay M, Hallegatte S, Vogt-Schilb A, Rozenberg J, Narloch U, Kerr T (2015) Decarbonizing development : three steps to a zero-carbon future. World Bank, WashingtonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Fischer C, Withagen C, Toman M (2004) Optimal investment in clean production capacity. Environ Resour Econ 28(3):325–345CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Flouri M, Karakosta C, Kladouchou C, Psarras J (2015) How does a natural gas supply interruption affect the EU gas security? A Monte Carlo simulation. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 44:785–796CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. G7 (2015) Leaders’ Declaration G7 Summit GermanyGoogle Scholar
  37. Gaudet G (1983) Optimal investment and adjustment costs in the economic theory of the mine. Can J Econ/Revue Can Econ 16(1):39–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Gaudet G, Lasserre P (2011) The efficient use of multiple sources of a nonrenewable resource under supply cost uncertainty. Int Econ Rev 52(1):245–258CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Gaudet G, Salant SW (2014) The hotelling model with multiple demands. In: Robert H, Layton D (eds) Handbook on the economics of natural resources. Edward Elgar Publishing, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
  40. Gerlagh R, Kverndokk S, Rosendahl KE (2014) The optimal time path of clean energy R&D policy when patents have finite lifetime. J Environ Econ Manag 67(1):2–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Gould JP (1968) Adjustment costs in the theory of investment of the firm. Rev Econ Stud 35(1):47–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Guivarch C, Monjon S, Rozenberg J, Vogt-Schilb A (2015) Would climate policy improve the European energy security? Climate Change Econ 6:1550008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Ha Duong M, Grubb M, Hourcade J-C (1997) Influence of socioeconomic inertia and uncertainty on optimal CO\(_{2}\)-emission abatement. Nature 390(6657):270–273CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Herfindahl OC (1967) Depletion and economic theory. In: Gaffney M (ed) Extractive resources and taxation. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison, pp 63–90Google Scholar
  45. Holland SP (2003) Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. J Environ Econ Manag 45(3):569–588CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Hotelling H (1931) The economics of exhaustible resources. J Political Econ 39(2):137–175CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. IEA (2014a) CO\(_2\) emissions from fuel combustion. Int Energy Agency.  https://doi.org/10.1787/co2_fuel-2014-en
  48. IEA (2014b) Harnessing electricity’s potential. Energy Technology Perspectives. Int Energy Agency.  https://doi.org/10.1787/energy_tech-2014-en
  49. IPCC (2014) Summary for Policymakers, Climate Change 2014, Synthesis Report. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate ChangeGoogle Scholar
  50. Jorgenson D (1967) The theory of investment behavior. In: Determinants of investment behavior. NBER, pp 129–188Google Scholar
  51. Kemp MC, Van Long N (1980) Ontwo folk theorems concerning the extraction of exhaustible resources. Econometrica 48(3):663–673CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Krautkraemer JA (1998) Nonrenewable resource scarcity. J Econ Lit 36(4):2065–2107Google Scholar
  53. Labandeira X, Labeaga JM, López-Otero X (2012) Estimation of elasticity price of electricity with incomplete information. Energy Econ 34(3):627–633CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Lasserre P (1985) Exhaustible-resource extraction with capital. In: Scott A (ed) Progress in natural resource economics. Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp 178–202Google Scholar
  55. Lemoine D, Traeger CP (2016) Economics of tipping the climate dominoes. Nat Clim Change 6(5):514–519CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Lucas J, Robert E (1967) Adjustment costs and the theory of supply. J Political Econ 75(4):321–334CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Marcantonini C, Ellerman AD (2014) The implicit carbon price of renewable energy incentives in Germany. EUI RSCAS Climate Policy Research Unit Report 2014/28Google Scholar
  58. Matthews HD, Gillett NP, Stott PA, Zickfeld K (2009) The proportionality of global warming to cumulative carbon emissions. Nature 459(7248):829–832CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. McGlade C, Ekins P (2015) The geographical distribution of fossil fuels unused when limiting global warming to 2C. Nature 517(7533):187–190CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Mussa M (1977) External and internal adjustment costs and the theory of aggregate and firm investment. Economica 44(174):163–178CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. OECD (2015) Projected Costs of Generating Electricity 2015. OECD Publishing, NEA/IEA/OECDGoogle Scholar
  62. Pfeiffer A, Hepburn C, Vogt-Schilb A, Caldecott B (2018) Committed emissions from existing and planned power plants and asset stranding required to meet the paris agreement. Environ Res Lett 13(5):054019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Pindyck RS (1991) Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment. J Econ Lit 29(3):1110–1148Google Scholar
  64. Rogner H-H, Aguilera RF, Archer C, Bertani R, Bhattacharya SC, Dusseault MB, Gagnon L, Haberl H, Hoogwijk M, Johnson A, Rogner ML, Wagner H, Yakushev V (2012) Chapter 7–energy resources and potentials. Global Energy Assessment-Toward a Sustainable Future, pp 423–512. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA and the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, AustriaGoogle Scholar
  65. Rosendahl KE (2004) Cost-effective environmental policy: implications of induced technological change. J Environ Econ Manag 48(3):1099–1121CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Rozenberg J, Vogt-Schilb A, Hallegatte S (2017) instrument choice and stranded assets in the transition to clean capital. Inter-American Development Bank Working Paper 782, Washington DC, USAGoogle Scholar
  67. Seierstad A, Sydsaeter K (1987) Optimal control theory with economic applications. North-Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  68. Shindell DT (2015) The social cost of atmospheric release. Clim Change 130(2):313–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Smulders S, van der Werf E (2008) Climate policy and the optimal extraction of high- and low-carbon fossil fuels. Can J Econ/Revue Can Econ 41(4):1421–1444CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Solow RM (1974) Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources. Rev Econ Stud 41:29–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Stiglitz J (1974) Growth with exhaustible natural resources: efficient and optimal growth paths. Rev Econ Stud 41:123–137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Tahvonen O, Salo S (2001) Economic growth and transitions between renewable and nonrenewable energy resources. Eur Econ Rev 45(8):1379–1398CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. UE (2011) A Roadmap for Moving to a Competitive Low Carbon Economy in 2050. European Commission Communication from the Commission COM (2011) 112 finalGoogle Scholar
  74. Ulph A, Ulph D (2013) Optimal climate change policies when governments cannot commit. Environ Resour Econ 56(2):161–176CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (1991) Pollution control and the Ramsey problem. Environ Resour Econ 1(2):215–236CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2012) Too much coal, too little oil. J Public Econ 96(12):62–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2014) Growth, renewables, and the optimal carbon tax. Int Econ Rev 55(1):283–311CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Vogt-Schilb A, Hallegatte S (2017) Climate policies and nationally determined contributions: reconciling the needed ambition with the political economy. WIREs Energy Environ.  https://doi.org/10.18235/0000714
  79. Vogt-Schilb A, Hallegatte S, de Gouvello C (2014) Marginal abatement cost curves and the quality of emission reductions: a case study on Brazil. Clim Policy.  https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2014.953908
  80. Vogt-Schilb A, Meunier G, Hallegatte S (2018) When starting with the most expensive option makes sense: optimal timing, cost and sectoral allocation of abatement investment. J Environ Econ Manag 88:210–233CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Wei C (2003) Energy, the stock market, and the putty-clay investment model. Am Econ Rev 93(1):311–323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Williams JH, DeBenedictis A, Ghanadan R, Mahone A, Moore J, Morrow WR, Price S, Torn MS (2012) The technology path to deep greenhouse gas emissions cuts by 2050: the pivotal role of electricity. Science 335(6064):53–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Williams R (2010) Setting the initial time-profile of climate policy: the economics of environmental policy phase-ins. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 16120Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature B.V. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Renaud Coulomb
    • 1
  • Oskar Lecuyer
    • 2
    Email author
  • Adrien Vogt-Schilb
    • 3
  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of MelbourneParkvilleAustralia
  2. 2.Division Innovation, Recherche et SavoirsAgence Française de DéveloppementParisFrance
  3. 3.Inter-American Development BankWashingtonUSA

Personalised recommendations