Advertisement

Environmental and Resource Economics

, Volume 48, Issue 3, pp 391–411 | Cite as

Potential Contributions of Political Science to Environmental Economics

  • Jon HoviEmail author
  • Arild Underdal
  • Hugh Ward
Open Access
Article

Abstract

While political science has much to offer, at least some of its contributions might be difficult to incorporate into economic models. Nevertheless, we argue that environmental economics might benefit from supplementing, combining, or sometimes even replacing the rational choice approach with other approaches commonly used in political science. We develop our argument by examining three core components of political science analysis: ideas, power, and institutions. For each component we review political science approaches and propositions with a view to determining “what’s in it” for environmental economics.

Keywords

Environmental economics Ideas Institutions Political science Power 

Notes

Acknowledgments

We thank the guest editors and two anonymous reviewers for many helpful comments. Frank Azevedo provided excellent editorial assistance.

Open Access

This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial License which permits any noncommercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and source are credited.

References

  1. Aakre S, Hovi J (2010) Emission trading: participation enforcement determines the need for compliance enforcement. European Union Politics 11(3): 427–445CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Abbott KW, Snidal D (1998) Why states act through formal international organizations. J Conflict Resolut 42: 3–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Aidt TS (1998) Political internalization of economic externalities and environmental policy. J Public Econ 69(1): 1–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Austen-Smith D (1995) Campaign contributions and access. Am Polit Sci Rev 89: 566–581CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Austen-Smith D (1997) Interest groups: money, information and influence. In: Mueller DC (eds) Perspectives in public choice. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  6. Axelrod R (2008) Political science and beyond: presidential address to the American political science association. Perspect Polit 6: 3–9Google Scholar
  7. Axelrod R, Keohane RO (1985) Achieving cooperation under anarchy: strategies and institutions. In: Oye KA (eds) Cooperation under anarchy. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  8. Bacharach SB, Lawler EJ (1984) Bargaining: power, tactics, and outcomes. Jossey-Bass, San FranciscoGoogle Scholar
  9. Backhouse RE, Medema SG (2009) On the definition of economics. J Econ Perspect 23: 221–233CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Barker, A, Peters, BG (eds) (1992) Politics of expert advice: creating, using and manipulating scientific knowledge for public policy. Edinburgh University Press, EdinburghGoogle Scholar
  11. Barnett M, Duvall R (2005) Power in global governance. In: Barnett M, Duvall R (eds) Power in global governance. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  12. Barrett S (2003) Environment and statecraft. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Barrett S (2007) Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global public goods. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  14. Barrett S, Stavins R (2003) Increasing compliance and participation in international climate change agreements. Int Environ Agr Polit Law Econ 3: 349–376Google Scholar
  15. Barry B (1980) Is it better to be powerful or lucky: part 1. Polit Stud 28: 183–194CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Becker GS (1976) The economic approach to human behavior. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  17. Bernard S, Asokan S, Warrell H, Lemer J (2009) Which country has the greenest bail-out? Financial Times 2 March 2009Google Scholar
  18. Biermann F, Siebenhüner B (eds) (forthcoming) Managers of global change: the influence of international environmental bureaucracies. MIT Press, Cambridge (2009)Google Scholar
  19. Brack, D (2003). Monitoring the montreal protocol. In: Trevor F (ed) Verification handbook 2003. Available at: http://www.vertic.org/assets/YB03/VY03_Brack.pdf, pp 209–226
  20. Breitmeier H, Young OR, Zürn M (2006) Analyzing international environmental regimes: from case study to data base. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  21. Brown Weiss, E, Jacobson, HK (eds) (1998) Engaging countries: strengthening compliance with international environmental accords. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  22. Busch PO, Jörgens H (2005) The international sources of policy convergence: explaining the spread of environmental policy innovations. J Eur Public Policy 12(5): 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Camerer CF, Loewenstein G (2004) Behavioral economics: past, present, future. In: Camerer CF, Loewenstein G, Rabin M (eds) Advances in behavioral economics. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  24. Chamley CP (2004) Rational Herds: economic models of social learning. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  25. Chayes A, Chayes AH (1993) On compliance. Int Organ 47: 175–205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Chayes A, Chayes AH (1995) The new sovereignty. Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  27. Cohen MD, March JG, Olsen JP (1972) A garbage can model of organizational choice source. Admin Sci Q 17: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Coleman JS (1973) The mathematics of collective action. Heinemann, LondonGoogle Scholar
  29. Dahl RA (1965) Modern political analysis. Prentice-Hall, Englewood CliffsGoogle Scholar
  30. Downs GW, Jones MA (2002) Reputation, compliance, and international law. J Legal Stud XXXI(January): S95–S114CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Downs GW, Rocke DM, Barsoom PN (1996) Is the good news about compliance good news about cooperation?. Int Organ 50: 379–406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Edelman MJ (1974) The symbolic uses of politics. University of Illinois Press, UrbanaGoogle Scholar
  33. Easton D (1953) The political system. Alfred A. Knoph, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  34. Elster J (1989) Nuts and bolts of the social sciences. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  35. Felder S, Schleiniger R (2002) Environmental tax reform: efficiency and political feasibility. Ecol Econ 42(1–2): 107–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Folmer H, Mouche P, Ragland S (1993) Interconnected games and international environmental problems. Environ Resour Econ 3: 313–335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Fredriksson PG (1997) The political economy of pollution taxes in a small open economy. J Environ Econ Manage 33(1): 44–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Friedman, J (eds) (1996) The rational choice controversy. Economic models of politics reconsidered. Yale University Press, New HavenGoogle Scholar
  39. Gates S, Humes B (1997) Games, information and politics. University of Michigan Press, Ann ArborGoogle Scholar
  40. Green D, Shapiro I (1994) The pathologies of rational choice. A critique of applications in political science. Yale University Press, New HavenGoogle Scholar
  41. Grossman GM, Helpman E (1994) Protection for sale. Am Econ Rev 84: 833–850Google Scholar
  42. Habeeb MW (1988) Power and tactics in international negotiation. The Johns Hopkins University Press, BaltimoreGoogle Scholar
  43. Haftel YZ, Thompson A (2006) The independence of international organizations: concept and applications. J Conflict Resolut 50: 253–275CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Hahn RW (1990) The political economy of environmental regulation: towards a unifying framework. Public Choice 65(1): 21–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Hajer MA (1995) The politics of environmental discourses: ecological modernization and the policy process. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  46. Hall PA, Taylor RCR (1996) Political science and the three new institutionalisms. Polit Stud 44: 936–957CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Harrison K (2007) The road not taken: climate change policy in Canada and the United States. Global Environ Polit 7: 92–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Hasenclever A, Mayer P, Rittberger V (1997) Theories of international regimes. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Hodgson GM (2006) What are institutions?. J Econ Issues 40: 1–25Google Scholar
  50. Holzinger K, Knill C (2004) Competition and cooperation in environmental policy: individual and interaction effects. J Public Policy 24(1): 25–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Hovi J, Aakre SY (2009) Theory of participation, compliance, and enforcement in international environmental agreements. Paper presented at the International Studies Associations’ 50th Annual Convention, New York City, 15–18 February 2009Google Scholar
  52. Howarth D (2000) Discourse. Open University Press, Milton KeynesGoogle Scholar
  53. Jacobsen K (2005), Perestroika in American political science. Post-autistic Econ Rev 32(6), http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue32/Jacobsen32.htm
  54. Janis IL (1982) Groupthink: psychological studies of policy decisions and Fiascoes. Houghton Mifflin, BostonGoogle Scholar
  55. Jenkins-Smith HC, Sabatier PA (1999) The dynamics of policy orientated learning. In: Jenkins-Smith HC, Sabatier PA (eds) Policy change and learning: an advocacy coalition approach. Westview, BoulderGoogle Scholar
  56. Jones BD, Baumgartner FR (2005) The politics of attention: how governments prioritize problems. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  57. Jordan A, Wurzel R, Brückner L (2003) European governance and the transfer of ’New’ environmental policy instruments. Public Admin 81(3): 555–574CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Jönsson C, Tallberg J (2008) Institutional theory in international relations. In: Pierre J, Peters GB, Stoker G (eds) Debating institutionalism. Manchester University Press, ManchesterGoogle Scholar
  59. Kahneman A, Tversky D (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decisions under risk. Econometrica 47: 263–291CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Keohane RO, Nye JS (1977) Power and interdependence. Little, Brown and Company, BostonGoogle Scholar
  61. Keohane RO, Martin LL (2003) Institutional theory, endogeneity, and delegation. In: Elman C, Elman M (eds) Progress in international relations theory. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  62. Kern K, Jörgens H, Jänicke M (2001) The diffusion of environmental policy innovations: a contribution to the globalisation of environmental policy. Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung Discussion Paper FS II 01–302Google Scholar
  63. Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest, and money. Harcourt Brace, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  64. Kingdon JW (1984) Agendas, alternatives and public policy. Little Brown, BostonGoogle Scholar
  65. Lasswell HD (1936) Politics: who gets what, when, how. McGraw-Hill, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  66. Lukes S (1974) Power: a radical view. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  67. Lyons B, Mehta J (1997) Contracts, opportunism and trust: self-interest and social orientation. Cambridge J Econ 21: 239–257Google Scholar
  68. March JG, Olsen JP (1989) Rediscovering institutions: the organizational basis of politics. The Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  69. Mearsheimer JJ (1995) The false promise of international institutions. Int Security 19: 5–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Miles EL et al (2002) Environmental regime effectiveness: confronting theory with evidence. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  71. Mitchell RB (1994) Regime design matters: intentional oil pollution and treaty compliance. Int Organ 48: 425–458CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Mitchell RB, Deane G (2009) Leaders, laggards, and institutional change (Unpublished)Google Scholar
  73. Moran M, Rein M, Goodin RE (eds) The Oxford handbook of public policy. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  74. North CD (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance (Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions). Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  75. Oates WE, Portney PR (2003) The political economy of environmental policy. In: Mäler KG, Vincent JR (eds) Handbook of environmental economics. Elsevier, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  76. OECD (2008) Environmentally related taxes and tradable permit systems in practice. OECD, ParisGoogle Scholar
  77. Olson M (1968) The logic of collective action. Schocken Books, New York (first published by Harvard University Press in 1965)Google Scholar
  78. Peters BG, Pierre J (1998) Governance without government, rethinking public administration. J Public Admin Res Theory 8: 223–243Google Scholar
  79. Pierson P, Skocpol T (2002) Historical institutionalism in political science. In: Katznelson I, Milner HV (eds) Political science: the state of the discipline. W W Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  80. Potters J, van Winden F (1992) Lobbying and asymmetric information. Public Choice 74: 269–292CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Riker WH (1986) The art of political manipulation. Yale University Press, New HavenGoogle Scholar
  82. Rokkan S (1966) Numerical democracy and corporate pluralism. In: Dahl RA (eds) Political opposition in western democracy. Yale University Press, New HavenGoogle Scholar
  83. Rutherford M (1994) Institutions in economics: the old and the new institutionalism. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Sabatier PA (1993) Policy change over a decade or more. In: Sabatier PA, Jenkins-Smith HC (eds) Policy change and learning: an advocacy coalition approach. Westview Press, BoulderGoogle Scholar
  85. Sabatier PA, Jenkins-Smith HC (1999) The advocacy coalition framework: an assessment. In: Sabatier PA (eds) Theories of the policy process. Westview Press, BoulderGoogle Scholar
  86. Shepsle K (1986) Institutional equilibrium and equilibrium institutions. In: Weisberg HF (eds) Political science: the science of politics. Agathon Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  87. Simon H A (1983) Reason in human affairs. Blackwell, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  88. Skaperdas S (1996) Contest success functions. Econ Theory 7: 283–290Google Scholar
  89. Stein AA (1982) Coordination and collaboration: regimes in an anarchic world. Int Organ 36: 299–324CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Tallberg J (2002) Paths to compliance: enforcement, management and the European Union. Int Organ 56(3): 609–643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Tews K, Busch PO, Jörgens H (2003) The diffusion of new environmental policy instruments. Eur J Polit Res 42(4): 569–600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Thelen K (1999) Historical institutionalism in comparative politics. Ann Rev Polit Sci 2: 369–404CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Underdal A (1998) Explaining compliance and defection: three models. Eur J Int Relat 4: 5–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Underdal A (2009) Can international conferences be modeled?. In: Aggestam K, Jerneck M (eds) Diplomacy in theory and practice. Liber, MalmöGoogle Scholar
  95. Victor DG (1998) The operation and effectiveness of the Montreal protocol’s non-compliance procedure. In: Victor DG, Raustiala K, Skolnikoff EB (eds) The implementation and effectiveness of international environmental commitments: theory and evidence. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  96. Wilson JQ (1973) Political organizations. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  97. Zartman IW, Rubin JZ (2000) Symmetry and asymmetry of negotiation. In: Zartman IW, Rubin JZ (eds) Power and negotiation. The University of Michigan Press, Ann ArborGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2011

Open AccessThis is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/2.0), which permits any noncommercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and source are credited.

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Political ScienceUniversity of OsloOsloNorway
  2. 2.CICERO Center for International Climate and Environmental ResearchOsloNorway
  3. 3.Department of GovernmentUniversity of EssexColchesterUK

Personalised recommendations