1 Introduction

Economic shocks of DSGE models cannot always be recovered from VARs. This situation has been discussed e.g. in Chari et al. (2005), Christiano et al. (2006), Kapetanios et al. (2007), Ravenna (2007), and it is related to the non-fundamentalness of economic models, see Hansen and Sargent (1980), Lippi and Reichlin (1993, 1994) for early treatments of the problem.

Solutions of linear (or linearized) DSGE models can be expressed in linear state space form using several solution methods, such as Binder and Pesaran (1997), Uhlig (1999), Klein (2000), Sims (2001). In the following, we refer to the linear state space form as the ABCD form. When the number of shocks is equal to the number of observables and the matrix that loads the former into the latter is non-singular, the ABCD form is called square. We observe that the ABCD form of the solution dynamics need not be minimal, i.e. it may involve a non-minimal number of state variables. This is illustrated for example in Komunjer and Ng (2011), who show that the state space solutions in Christiano et al. (2005), An and Schorfheide (2007), Smets and Wouters (2007), García-Cicco et al. (2010) are all non-minimal.

In this paper we investigate population conditions for fundamentalness of the ABCD form and for the existence of a finite VAR representation of the observables.Footnote 1 Fundamentalness is currently checked using the ‘poor man’s invertibility condition’ in Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2007); applications of this approach can be found in Leeper et al. (2013), Schmitt-Grohé (2010), Kurmann and Otrok (2011), Sims (2012) inter alia. The poor man’s invertibility condition consists in the stability of the associate state matrix, \(F\) say, i.e. the state matrix in the system in which the role of inputs and outputs is interchanged, see Bart et al. (2008). Conditions for the VAR to be of finite order are given in Ravenna (2007), where a ‘unimodularity condition’ is proposed as a check. This condition consists in the unimodularity of the matrix polynomial \(I-Fz\), \(z\in \mathbb {C}\),Footnote 2 or equivalently in the nilpotency of \(F\), see Franchi and Vidotto (2013).

When the square ABCD form is minimal, we show that the poor man’s invertibility condition and the unimodularity condition are proper checks, i.e. they are necessary and sufficient conditions for fundamentalness. When the ABCD form is non-minimal, we find that the poor man’s invertibility condition and the unimodularity condition are not necessary. In other words \(F\) can be unstable while the square ABCD form is fundamental and \(I-Fz\) can be non-unimodular while the square ABCD form has a finite order VAR representation.

Because in current economic practice systems are not always in minimal state space form, in this paper we present alternative orthogonality conditions that are necessary and sufficient and which hold in possibly non-minimal square systems. This provides a check that does not require to transform the system to minimal ABCD form. These orthogonality conditions involve the eigenvectors associated with eigenvalues of the associate state matrix \(F\), and correspond to the case where there exist states that are cancelled in the VAR representation of the observables. For fundamentalness, the orthogonality conditions must apply to all the unstable eigenvalues, while for the existence of a finite VAR representation, the orthogonality conditions must hold for every nonzero eigenvalue.

When the orthogonality conditions hold, we find that the eigenvalues of the associate state matrix \(F\) are also eigenvalues of the state matrix, \(A\) say. This implies that when the eigenvalues of \(A\) and \(F\) are different, the orthogonality conditions do not hold. This provides a simplified strategy based solely on eigenvalues of \(A\) and \(F\). Finally we find that if the ABCD form is minimal, the orthogonality conditions coincide with the poor man’s invertibility condition and the unimodularity condition. This shows that the present orthogonality conditions are an extension of the conditions in the literature that apply to general (i.e. not necessarily minimal) linear state space forms.

Therefore, invertibility of linearized DSGE models should be checked either using the present orthogonality conditions or by first transforming the state space form to a minimal representation and then by applying the poor man’s invertibility condition to the minimal state space form. Similarly, existence of a finite VAR representation should be checked either using the present orthogonality conditions or by first transforming the state space form to a minimal representation and then by applying the unimodularity condition to the minimal state space form, see Franchi (2013) for an illustration on the Smets and Wouters (2007) model.

The results of the paper employ well-known concepts from systems theory, see e.g. Kailath (1980), Antsaklis and Michel (2007). The possibility to have cancellations of the type discussed in this paper in non-minimal state space systems was noticed by Rosenbrock (1970) inter alia, see his remark after Theorem 1.2, page 38 and Corollary 3, page 115. Here we give explicit algebraic condition on the system matrices that characterizes this situation. These tools are meant to be used by macro-economists, who deal with non-minimal state space representations of linearized DGSE models in practice and who are interested in determining if the observables in their model admit a VAR representation.

The results in this paper are also related to cointegration.Footnote 3 The possibility to have unstable states within a non-minimal state space gives in fact one more way to incorporate cointegration in DGSE models, by allowing unit-root stochastic trends in the states that can be canceled in the stable VAR representation of observables.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the square case. Section 3 shows that fundamentalness and the existence of a finite order VAR can be characterized in terms of an appropriate transfer function. Section 4 presents the orthogonality conditions. Section 5 specializes results to minimal square ABCD forms, showing that for minimal state spaces the orthogonality conditions coincide with the poor man’s invertibility condition and the unimodularity condition. Section 6 concludes. All proofs are collected in the Appendix.

2 Square ABCD Forms

Consider an equilibrium dynamics of a linearized DSGE model with representation

$$\begin{aligned} x_{t}&= A x_{t-1} + B w_{t}\nonumber \\ y_{t}&= C x_{t-1} + D w_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(x_{t}\) has dimension \(n_x\times 1\), \(y_{t}\) has dimension \(n_y\times 1\) and \(w_{t}\) is a white noise of dimension \(n_w\times 1\) with identity covariance matrix. \(A\) is called the state matrix and we refer to (1) as the ABCD form.

The following assumption is maintained throughout the paper.

Assumption 2.1

(Square ABCD form). The matrix \(D\) is square and invertible.

In square ABCD forms the number of economic shocks is equal to the number of observables and the matrix that loads the shocks into the observables is non-singular. In this case one can substitute \(w_{t}=D^{-1}(y_{t} - C x_{t-1})\) in the first equation in (1) and rewrite the square ABCD form in the ‘associate state space form’, see e.g. Ch.2.2 in Bart et al. (2008),

$$\begin{aligned} x_{t}&= Fx_{t-1}+BD^{-1}y_{t},\qquad \qquad F=A-BD^{-1}C,\nonumber \\ w_{t}&= - D^{-1}C x_{t-1} + D^{-1} y_{t} , \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where the role of input and output of system (1) are interchanged; \(F\) is called the ‘associate state matrix’.

The ABCD form is called minimal, see e.g. Ch.6 in Kailath (1980) or Ch.2 in Hannan and Deistler (1988), if the dimension of \(x_t\) is as small as possibile. Minimality holds if and only if the ABCD form is both controllable and observable, i.e. if \(\mathrm{rank }\mathcal {C}=\mathrm{rank }\mathcal {O}=n_x\), where

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {C}=\left( \begin{array}{cccc} B&AB&\cdots&A^{n_x-1}B \end{array} \right) ,\qquad \mathcal {O}= \left( \begin{array}{c} C \\ CA \\ \vdots \\ CA^{n_x-1} \end{array}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

are respectively called controllability and observability matrix.

Some remarks are in order.

Remark 2.2

The state matrix \(A\) may be stable or unstable.Footnote 4 Cases with unstable \(A\) are interesting from an economic point of view because they arise from models with unit roots in the endogenous state variables as well as those with non-stationary exogenous shocks, as in Chang et al. (2007).

Remark 2.3

The ABCD form may be minimal or non-minimal. Non-minimal ABCD forms are natural outcomes of standard solution methods: for example, Komunjer and Ng (2011) show that, using gensys and dynare, the ABCD forms in Christiano et al. (2005), An and Schorfheide (2007), Smets and Wouters (2007), García-Cicco et al. (2010) are all non-minimal.

3 Transfer Function

In square ABCD forms, it is of interest, see e.g. Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2007), to characterize situations in which the economic shocks can be recovered from the infinite history of the observable variables, i.e. cases in which \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation

$$\begin{aligned} A(L)y_{t} =u_{t},\qquad A(z)=I_{n_y}-\sum _{j=1}^\infty A_j z^j,\qquad u_{t}= M w_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where the sequence \(\{A_j\}_{j=1}^\infty \) is absolutely summable and \(M\) is a non-singular matrix that links economic shocks and reduced form errors. When (4) holds, (1) is said to be invertible (and \(w_{t}\) fundamental), see Hansen and Sargent (1980), Brockwell and Davis (1987), Lippi and Reichlin (1993, 1994). Furthermore it is of interest, see e.g. Ravenna (2007), to have conditions that describe when the VAR representation of \(y_t\) has finite order, i.e. when \(A(z)\) is a matrix polynomial.

In this section we link the existence of a (possibly finite) VAR representation of \(y_{t}\) to properties of the transfer function from \(y_{t}\) to \(D w_{t}\), \(T(L)y_{t}=D w_{t}\), implied by the associate state space form (2), where

$$\begin{aligned} T(z)=I_{n_y}-C(I_{n_x}-Fz)^{-1}BD^{-1}z,\qquad z\in \mathbb {C}. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

The relationship between the VAR representation of \(y_t\) and the transfer function \(T(z)\) is presented next; in the following we say that a function is regular if it is finite on the unit disc, i.e. for all \(z\in \mathbb {C}\) such that \(|z|< 1+\delta \), for some \(\delta >0\), see Johansen (2009) for a similar notion of regularity. Remark that the coefficients of the expansion of a regular function \(f(z)=\sum _{j=0}^\infty f_jz^j\) are geometrically decreasing and hence absolutely summable.

Proposition 3.1

(Transfer function conditions). The vector of observables \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation if and only if \(T(z)\) is regular. Moreover, the VAR representation is of finite order if and only if \(T(z)\) is a matrix polynomial. In either case, the coefficients of the VAR representation of \(y_{t}\) and the mapping between economic shocks and reduced form errors in (4) are given by \(A(z)=T(z)\) and \(M=D\).

The properties of the matrix function \(T(z)\) depend on those of \((I-Fz)^{-1}=\mathrm{adj }(I-Fz) / |I-Fz|\). The roots of \(|I-Fz|=0\) are poles of \((I-Fz)^{-1}\); because \(|I-Fz|=0\) if and only if \(z=\lambda _u^{-1}\), where \(\{\lambda _u\}\) are the nonzero eigenvalues of \(F\), if \(F\) is stable then \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) is regular because \(\min _{u} |\lambda _u^{-1}|>1\). Hence \(T(z)\) is regular and, by Proposition 3.1, this implies that \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation. Moreover, if \(F\) is nilpotent then \(I-Fz\) is unimodular and \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) is a matrix polynomial; hence \(T(z)\) is a matrix polynomial and, by Proposition 3.1, this implies that \(y_{t}\) admits a finite order VAR representation.

Observe that \(T(z)\) can be regular even if \(F\) is unstable and it can be a matrix polynomial even if \(F\) is not nilpotent. In fact, when \(F\) is unstable, \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) has poles in the (closed) unit disc and thus it is non-regular, but those singularities may be absent from \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) due to the presence of \(B\) and \(C\). In this case \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) is regular and thus the same holds for \(T(z)\). This possibility is illustrated in the following example, which serves as a running example in the rest of the paper.

Example 3.2

(Running example). This is a special case of the model in Chang et al. (2007). Let \(n_x=4\), \(n_w=n_y=2\) and

$$\begin{aligned} A=\left( \begin{array}{cc} \Phi _1 &{} \quad 0 \\ 0 &{} \quad I_2 \end{array} \right) ,\qquad B=\left( \begin{array}{c} \frac{1}{2}I_2 \\ I_2 \end{array} \right) ,\qquad C=\left( \begin{array}{cc} \Phi _1&\Phi _2 \end{array} \right) ,\qquad D= \Phi _2+\frac{1}{2}I_2, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \Phi _1=\left( \begin{array}{cc} 1 &{} 1 \\ -\frac{1}{2} &{} -\frac{1}{2} \end{array} \right) ,\qquad \Phi _2=\left( \begin{array}{cc} 1 &{} 1 \\ 1 &{} 1 \end{array} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Observe that \(D\) is non-singular so that the ABCD form is square. Moreover \(F=A-BD^{-1}C\) has eigenvalues \(\left\{ 1,3/5,0,0\right\} \), and \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) has a pole at \(z=1\) and thus it is non-regular. At the same time \(T(z)\) is regular, because

$$\begin{aligned} C(I_{n_x}-Fz)^{-1}B=\frac{5}{4(3z-5)}\left( \begin{array}{cc} 4z-6 &{} 4z-6 \\ z-3 &{} z-3 \end{array} \right) \end{aligned}$$

has no pole at \(z=1\) (it only has a pole at \(z=\frac{5}{3}\)) and hence the expansion \(T(z)=\sum _{j=0}^\infty T_jz^j\) has absolutely summable coefficients. This illustrates that one can have fundamentalness together with unstable \(F\).

Similarly, one can construct examples in which \(B\) and \(C\) cancel every pole of \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) so that \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) is a matrix polynomial, which in turn implies that the same holds for \(T(z)\). This shows that the poor man’s invertibility condition in Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2007) and the unimodularity condition in Ravenna (2007) are not necessary conditions for a VAR representation of a square ABCD form. The next proposition proves that they are sufficient conditions.

Proposition 3.3

(Sufficient conditions). If \(F\) is stable, then \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation; the converse does not hold. If \(F\) is nilpotent, then \(y_{t}\) admits a finite order VAR representation; the converse does not hold.

4 Conditions for the Existence of a VAR Representation

In this section we state necessary and sufficient conditions for fundamentalness and for the existence of a finite order VAR, in the form of orthogonality conditions or rank conditions. These conditions apply both to minimal and non-minimal square ABCD forms, and they are based on the idea of pole cancellations in \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) in the matrix function \(T(z)\).

We introduce the following notation: let \(\lambda _u\), \(u=1,\dots ,q\), be all the distinct nonzero eigenvalues of \(F\) and apply the partial fraction expansionFootnote 5

$$\begin{aligned}&(I-Fz)^{-1}=P(z)+H(z),\qquad P(z)=\sum _{u=1}^{q}P_u(z),\qquad P_u(z)=\sum _{j=1}^{m_u}\frac{P_{\lambda _u,m_u-j}}{(1-\lambda _u z)^j},\nonumber \\&\quad P_{\lambda _u,0}\ne 0. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Here \(H(z)\) is a matrix polynomial, \(P(z)\) is the sum of the principal parts \(P_u(z)\) of \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) at \(z=\lambda _u^{-1}\) and \(m_u\) is the order of the pole of \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) at \(z=\lambda _u^{-1}\). Note that zero eigenvalues of \(F\) are absent from \(|I-Fz|\) and hence they do not appear in the principal part \(P(z)\). A characterization of the pole cancellations in \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) due to the presence of \(B\) and \(C\) is given in the following Lemma, which define our orthogonality conditions.

Lemma 4.1

(Orthogonality conditions). \(T(z)\) has no pole at \(z=\lambda _u^{-1}\) if and only if the orthogonality conditions

$$\begin{aligned} CP_{\lambda _u,m_u-j}B=0,\qquad j=1,\ldots ,m_u, \end{aligned}$$
(7)

hold. If the orthogonality conditions hold, then \(\lambda _u\) is also an eigenvalue of \(A\).

Because \(P_u(z)\) fully characterizes the singularity of \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) at \(z=\lambda _u^{-1}\), in order for \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) to have no pole at \(z=\lambda _u^{-1}\), \(B\) and \(C\) must be such that \(CP_u(z)B=0\). This requires each coefficient of the principal part to be 0 when pre and post-multiplied by \(C\) and \(B\). Lemma 4.1 also states that if a pole cancellation occurs for a given eigenvalue of \(F\), then this must also be an eigenvalue of \(A\); this observation leads to the following necessary conditions.

Proposition 4.2

(Necessary conditions). The vector of observables \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation only if each unstable eigenvalue of \(F\) is also an eigenvalue of \(A\). Moreover, the VAR representation is of finite order only if each nonzero eigenvalue of \(F\) is also an eigenvalue of \(A\).

The main characterization result is stated next.

Proposition 4.3

(Necessary and sufficient orthogonality conditions). The vector of observables \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation if and only if the orthogonality conditions hold at each unstable eigenvalue of \(F\). Moreover, the VAR representation is of finite order if and only if the orthogonality conditions hold at each nonzero eigenvalue of \(F\).

An infinite order VAR representation requires the cancellation of all the poles associated with the unstable eigenvalues of \(F\); the VAR has finite order when the cancellation also involves the stable nonzero eigenvalues. Note that if all eigenvalues are stable, the first orthogonality condition for invertibility is automatically satisfied because there are no unstable eigenvalues. Similarly, if \(F\) is nilpotent, all eigenvalues are equal to 0, so that \(q=0\) in (6) and this implies \(P(z)=0\); hence also the second orthogonality condition for the existence of a finite order VAR is automatically satisfied. This illustrates that the poor man’s invertibility condition (and the unimodularity condition) implies the orthogonality conditions in Proposition 4.3 but not viceversa. That is, in square ABCD forms the former is stronger than the latter, and that the conditions differ.

An equivalent and more directly implementable rank condition is provided next.Footnote 6

Proposition 4.4

(Rank conditions). Let \(\lambda _u\) be a nonzero eigenvalue of \(F\), rank decompose \(F-\lambda _u I=\alpha \beta '\), where \(\alpha ,\beta \) are \(n_x \times r\) full column rank matrices, and define \(\alpha _\bot ,\beta _\bot \) as basesFootnote 7 of the orthogonal complements of the column spaces spanned by \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \) respectively. Then the orthogonality condition holds at \(\lambda _u\) if and only if \(\mathrm{rank }(\alpha _\bot 'B)<n_x-r\) or \(\mathrm{rank }(C\beta _\bot )<n_x-r\) (or both).

In the light of this equivalence one can thus restate the main characterization result in Proposition 4.3 replacing orthogonality conditions with rank conditions.

Proposition 4.5

(Necessary and sufficient rank conditions). The vector of observables \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation if and only if the rank condition holds at each unstable eigenvalue of \(F\). Moreover, the VAR representation is of finite order if and only if the rank condition holds at each nonzero eigenvalue of \(F\).

A MATLAB script that implements this check is available in the Additional Material to the present paper.

Example 4.6

(Continuation of Example 3.2). We illustrate our results using the running example, where the eigenvalues of \(F\) and \(A\) are \(\sigma _F=\left\{ 1,3/5,0,0\right\} \) and \(\sigma _A=\left\{ 1,1,1/2,0\right\} \) respectively. Because \(3/5\) is not an eigenvalue of \(A\), the necessary condition in Proposition 4.2 is not satisfied and one immediately sees that \(y_t\) does not have a finite order VAR representation. Because \(1\) is also an eigenvalue of \(A\), the necessary condition in Proposition 4.2 is satisfied and we proceed to check the rank condition for the eigenvalue equal to \(1\).

Rank-decomposing \(F-I=\alpha \beta '\), where \(\alpha ,\beta \) have dimension \(4 \times 3\), and defining \(\alpha _\bot ,\beta _\bot \) of dimension \(4 \times 1\) as bases of the orthogonal complements of \(\mathrm{col }\alpha \) and \(\mathrm{col }\beta \), one finds \(\alpha _\bot =(-3:-3:2:1)'\) and \(\beta _\bot =(0:0:1:-1)'\). Because

$$\begin{aligned} C=\left( \begin{array}{cccc} 1 &{} \quad 1 &{} \quad 1 &{} \quad 1\\ -\frac{1}{2} &{} \quad -\frac{1}{2} &{} \quad 1 &{} \quad 1 \end{array} \right) , \end{aligned}$$

one has \(C\beta _\bot =0\) and hence the rank condition in Proposition 4.4 is satisfied at the unstable eigenvalue equal to \(1\). This correctly indicates, see Proposition 4.5, that the vector of observables \(y_t\) has an infinite order VAR representation.

5 Minimal Square ABCD Forms

In this section we treat the special case of square minimal ABCD forms. Minimality could be directly obtained as a property of the DSGE’s solution or it could be derived from a non-minimal solution by eliminating irrelevant states, as described e.g. in Rosenbrock (1970). Here we show that if the square ABCD form is minimal, then the orthogonality conditions coincide with the poor man’s invertibility condition and with the unimodularity condition. We conclude this section by illustrating the result via the running example.

Proposition 5.1

(Equivalence in minimal state space forms). If the square ABCD form is minimal, then the vector of observables \(y_{t}\) admits an infinite order VAR representation if and only if \(F\) is stable. Moreover, the VAR representation is of finite order if and only if \(F\) is nilpotent.

When the ABCD form is minimal, \(CP_u(z)B \ne 0\) for any eigenvalue and hence no cancellation is possibile. Then each pole of \((I-Fz)^{-1}\) is a pole of \(C(I-Fz)^{-1}B\) and the orthogonality condition for an infinite order VAR holds (trivially) if and only if \(F\) has no unstable eigenvalues. Similarly, it holds (trivially) for a finite order VAR holds if and only if all eigenvalues are equal to zero. This shows that when the square ABCD form is minimal, the poor man’s invertibility condition and the unimodularity condition are equivalent to the orthogonality conditions and thus they become necessary and sufficient.

Example 5.2

(Continuation of Examples 3.2 and 4.6). We illustrate the last result on the running example, in which the controllability and observability matrix in (3) are such that \(\mathrm{rank }\mathcal {C}=4\) and \(\mathrm{rank }\mathcal {O}=2\). The ABCD form is thus controllable but not observable, and hence non-minimal.

A minimal representation can be derived as follows; here we use the subscript \(m\) to index quantities in the minimal state space representation. Write \(C\) as \(C=C_m v^{\prime }\), where

$$\begin{aligned} C_m= \left( \begin{array}{cc} 1 &{} \quad 1 \\ -\frac{1}{2} &{} \quad 1 \end{array} \right) , \qquad v^{\prime }= \left( \begin{array}{cccc} 1 &{} \quad 1 &{} \quad 0 &{} \quad 0 \\ 0 &{} \quad 0 &{} \quad 1 &{} \quad 1 \\ \end{array} \right) , \end{aligned}$$

and observe that \(v^{\prime }A=A_mv^{\prime }\), where \(A_m= \left( \begin{array}{cc} \frac{1}{2} &{} \quad 0 \\ 0 &{} \quad 1 \end{array} \right) .\) Define \(x_{m,t}=v^{\prime }x_{t}\) and \(B_m=v^{\prime }B\), pre-multiply the state equation by \(v^{\prime }\) and write the system as

$$\begin{aligned} x_{m,t}&= A_m x_{m,t-1} + B_m w_{t}\\ y_{t}&= C_m x_{m,t-1} + D w_{t}. \end{aligned}$$

This system is minimal; in fact the controllability and observability matrices of this system satisfy \(\mathrm{rank }\mathcal {C}_m=\mathrm{rank }\mathcal {O}_m=2\). Obviously, \(CA^jB=C_m v'A^jB=C_m A_m^jv'B=C_m A_m^jB_m\) and hence the so-called Markov coefficients of the two systems are equal.

We next apply Proposition 5.1 to this square minimal ABCD form. The eigenvalues of \(F_m\) are \(\left\{ 3/5,0\right\} \); hence they are all stable, and the poor man’s invertibility condition correctly signals that \(y_t\) has an infinite order VAR representation. The unimodularity condition does not apply, because \(F_m\) has one nonzero eigenvalue. This correctly signals that the system does not have a finite order VAR representation.

6 Conclusions

Standard solution methods of DSGE models do not necessarily deliver minimal state space forms. When the ABCD form is non-minimal the poor man’s invertibility condition in Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2007) and the unimodularity condition in Ravenna (2007) are not necessary for the existence of a VAR representation of the observables.

In this paper we have presented a check that is valid in the general square case, and hence can be applied to minimal and non-minimal ABCD forms. This illustrates that it is possible to have unstable eigenvalues in the state matrix and in the associate state matrix together with a VAR representation; this is possible because there may exist irrelevant unstable states that are cancelled in the VAR representation of the observables. Finally we show that if the state space form is minimal, the orthogonality condition coincides with the poor man’s invertibility condition and the unimodularity condition, because irrelevant states cannot exist.

The present results show that invertibility of linearized DSGE models should be checked either using the present orthogonality conditions or by first transforming the state space form to a minimal representation and then by applying the poor man’s invertibility condition to the minimal state space form. Similarly, existence of a finite VAR representation should be checked either using the present orthogonality conditions or by first transforming the state space form to a minimal representation and then by applying the unimodularity condition to the minimal state space form.