Skip to main content
Log in

The voter initiative and the power of the governor: evidence from campaign expenditures

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although a great deal of research examines the impact of the voter initiative process on the state legislature, the consequences for the state executive branch have been largely ignored. The voter initiative process provides the governor with a method to circumvent the legislature, which may increase the power of the governor in theory. However, it also provides citizens with a means to bypass the traditional lawmaking process and avoid the governor’s veto. This may reduce the power of the governor and lead to policies farther from the preferences of the governor. This study examines the impact of the voter initiative process on the power of the state governor by estimating total election cycle spending. Campaign expenditures are expected to reflect any sustained gain or loss in power due to the availability of the voter initiative process. The results indicate that gubernatorial campaign expenditures are significantly lower in states in which the voter initiative process is available. This finding suggests that state governors sustain a loss in political power when the voter initiative is available. Additionally, the findings imply that individuals may employ the voter initiative process as a substitute for gubernatorial support.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In addition to political influence and political resources, the ambitions of the individual politician may also impact campaign expenditures (Schlesinger 1966). Therefore, a candidate and his donors may spend money on a campaign in order to continue climbing the political ladder. However, research has shown that political influence and resources have significant effects on campaign expenditures.

  2. While the legislature and the governor are elected by the voters, Matsusaka (2005) notes that the preferences of the median voter in the state may not coincide with the preferences of the legislature as a whole. State legislators are elected in district elections and typically represent the median voter of the district. Gilligan and Matsusaka (2001), Bradbury and Crain (2001), and Baqir (2002) discuss this issue.

  3. This simple model ignores gubernatorial veto power. While the governors of all states except for North Carolina have some type of veto power, the passage of a voter initiative avoids the governor’s veto powers.

  4. Gerber (1996, 1999) and Matsusaka and McCarty (2001) find that the threat of a voter initiative can cause the state legislature to enact legislation to avoid a less favorable outcome through the voter initiative process. Matsusaka (1995), Gerber and Hug (2001), Arceneaux (2002), and Randolph (2010) find that the indirect effect of the voter initiative has an impact on legislation and policy outcomes.

  5. The governor can still benefit in this situation with incomplete information (Gerber and Lupia 1995; Matsusaka and McCarty 2001). The voter can be harmed if incomplete information exists (Matsusaka 2005).

  6. While candidates and their donors may spend money to gain election to a political office in order to progress toward more desirable political positions, other variables concerning political influence and political resources have significant explanatory power concerning campaign spending. The impact of the voter initiative process on gubernatorial campaign expenditures is significant in this study even though some candidates may simply aspire to greater political positions.

  7. Beyle (1998) develops two scales in order to measure the governor’s appointment power and the governor’s budgetary power. Governor appointment power is measured by examining the governor’s ability to appoint positions in public utilities, transportation, education, health, corrections, and welfare. The scale ranges from 0 when the legislature is able to select the position to 5 where the governor appoints the position without any approval (rounded to the nearest 0.5). Governor budgetary power is measured on a scale where 1 indicates that budget responsibilities are shared among elected officials and the legislature has an unlimited ability to change the budget and 5 indicates that the governor has full control of the budget and the legislature cannot alter the budget. Higher scores indicate a higher degree of power. The updated index is available online through the website listed in the references.

  8. Incumbents enjoy recognition and status benefits over challengers, allowing them access to greater finances. Open seat candidates are also well financed as they have a greater chance to win than challengers. Gierzynski and Breaux (1991) and Moncrief (1998) show that incumbents and open seat candidates spend more in elections in comparison to challengers.

  9. Previous research has found that greater degrees of competition are associated with higher campaign spending as donors are more willing to contribute in more competitive races (Thompson et al. 1994). Candidates generally have an idea of the closeness of the election and spend accordingly. This follows Muth’s (1961) rational expectations and is used in Kirchgässner and Meyer Zu Himmern (1997).

  10. While there are numerous ways to examine campaign finance law, Primo et al. (2006) argue that the dummy variable approach best suits the analysis of campaign finance law as other issues (such as specific dollar limitations, enforcement of campaign finance law, and other differences between states) are difficult to measure and can be subjective in nature.

  11. While some recent research has argued that the voter initiative process is endogenous to historical factors in states (Marschall and Ruhil 2005), others have argued that political landscapes have changed as the voter initiative process in most states was enacted prior to 1915 (Matsusaka 1995). Matsusaka (2005) offers empirical evidence to the theoretical evidence against the endogeneity issue.

  12. Wyoming is not included as a voter initiative state because it has an extremely high signature requirement at 15%. Illinois is not included as a voter initiative state because it is the only state in which a proposal can only be used to alter the organization of the state legislature. This follows the logic of Matsusaka (2004). The inclusion of Wyoming and Illinois does not significantly alter the results.

  13. 24 states have a form of the voter initiative at the state level. The signature requirement varies from a low of 3% to a high of 15% (Initiative and Referendum Institute n.d.a). This difference in signature requirements results in substantial differences in the effects of the voter initiative process. It can be very difficult to collect the signatures required for states with high signature requirements.

  14. Bowler and Donovan (2004) use the number of formal provisions required to place a voter initiative on the ballot in order to develop the qualification difficulty index. The number of provisions that restrict the ability of the legislature to alter the effects of a successful voter initiative is used to develop the legislative insulation index. Their indices have been reversed in this paper in order to simplify the interpretation of the indices. Bowler and Donovan (2004) find that reversing the indices do not alter the results.

  15. State fixed effects are not included in the analysis because the availability of the voter initiative process does not change from 1980 to 2002, with the exception of Mississippi in 1992.

  16. Regional variables are constructed as follows: North (CT, MA, ME, NH, NJ, NY, PA, RI, VT), South (AL, AR, DE, FL, GA, KY, LA, MD, MS, NC, OK, SC, TN, TX, VA, WV), Midwest (IA, ID, IL, IN, KS, MI, MN, MO, ND, NE, OH, SD, WI), and West (AZ, CA, CO, MT, NM, NV, OR, UT, WA, WY).

  17. Louisiana uses an open election format instead of the traditional primary and general election format used by other states. All candidates compete in an initial election regardless of party affiliation. If one candidate receives more than 50% of the vote, they are awarded the position of governor. Otherwise, a runoff election is held with the top two candidates from the initial election.

  18. Regressions including the four outliers were also performed. While the inclusion of the outliers does not change the primary results, the outliers do have a large impact on the magnitude of coefficients. The mean for per capita gubernatorial spending is $2.68 across all elections. Per capita spending in New Hampshire, 2002 was $14.21. Millionaire businessman Craig Benson spent a large amount of his own money in a year where a record number of voters participated. Per capita spending in West Virginia, 1980 was $13.66. This could be a data error as election winner Jay Rockefeller is reported as spending in excess of $11 million dollars for re-election. Per capita spending for South Dakota, 2002 was $12.22. This election was an upset victory for Mike Rounds in which a great deal of money was spent by other candidates in the primary and again in the general election. Finally, per capita spending was $11.49 in Rhode Island, 1990. Bruce Sundland (in his third attempt at the governor seat) spent a great deal of money to defeat incumbent Edward DiPrete.

  19. The results of this analysis are robust to any changes in the model employed. An analysis excluding the primary election independent variables was performed as an additional check. The primary results of the analysis persist.

  20. A number of the independent variables in the gubernatorial are either difficult or impossible to include in the Senate analysis. However, the results regarding the voter initiative variables are consistent regardless of the empirical specification.

References

  • Abrams, B. A. (1981). Political power and the market for governors. Public Choice, 37, 521–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arceneaux, K. (2002). Direct democracy and the link between public opinion and state abortion policy. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 2, 372–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Artés, J., & Viñuela, E. G. (2007). Campaign spending and office-seeking motivations: An empirical analysis. Public Choice, 133, 41–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baqir, R. (2002). Districting and government overspending. Journal of Political Economy, 110(6), 1318–1354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardwell, K. (2003). Campaign finance laws and the competition for spending in gubernatorial elections. Social Science Quarterly, 84(4), 811–825.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beyle, T. (1998). Governors. In V. Gray, R. Hanson, & H. Jacob (Eds.), Politics in the American states (7th ed., pp. 191–231). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

  • Beyle, T. (2008). Gubernatorial power. http://www.unc.edu/~beyle/gubnewpwr.html. Accessed June 1, 2010.

  • Beyle, T., & Jensen, J. (2010). The gubernatorial campaign finance database. http://www.unc.edu/~beyle/guber.html. Accessed June 1, 2010.

  • Bowler, S., & Donovan, T. (2004). Measuring the effect of direct democracy on state policy: Not all initiatives are created equal. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 4(3), 345–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: Cross country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breaux, D., & Gierzynski, A. (1991). It’s money that matters: campaign expenditures and state legislative primaries. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 16, 429–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congressional Research Service. (various years). Campaign finance law. Washington: National Clearinghouse on Election Administration.

  • Crain, W. M., Deaton, T., & Tollison, D. (1977). Legislators as taxicabs: On the value of seats in the US house of representatives. Economic Inquiry, 15(2), 298–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M., & Tollison, D. (1977). Attenuated property rights and the market for governors. Journal of Law and Economics, 20(1), 205–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federal Election Commission. (various years). Campaign finance reports and data (Candidate Financial Summaries). http://www.fec.gov/finance/disclosure/ftpsum.shtml. Accessed June 1, 2010.

  • Gerber, E. R. (1996). Legislative response to the threat of popular initiatives. American Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 99–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R. (1999). The populist paradox: Interest group influence and the promise of direct legislation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R., & Hug, S. (2001). Legislative response to direct legislation. In M. Mendelsohn & A. Parkin (Eds.), Referendum democracy. New York: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R., & Lupia, A. (1995). Campaign competition and policy responsiveness in direct legislation elections. Political Behavior, 17(2), 287–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gierzynski, A., & Breaux, D. (1991). Money and votes in state legislative elections. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 16, 203–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gifford, A., & Santoni, G. J. (1978). Politicians and property rights: An analysis of the relationship between campaign expenditures and wage and price controls. Public Choice, 33, 71–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2001). Fiscal policy, legislature size, and political parties: Evidence from the first half of the twentieth century. National Tax Journal, 54, 383–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogan, R. E. (2000). The costs of representation in state legislature: Explaining variations in campaign spending. Social Science Quarterly, 81(4), 941–956.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogan, R. E., & Hamm, K. E. (1998). The costs of representation in state legislatures: Variations in district-level campaign spending. In J. A. Thompson & G. F. Moncrief (Eds.), Campaign finance in state legislative elections (pp. 55–79). Washington DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Initiative and Referendum Institute at the University of Southern California. (n.d.a). Comparison of statewide initiative processes. http://www.iandrinstitute.org/New%20IRI%20Website%20Info/Drop%20Down%20Boxes/Requirements/A%20Comparison%20of%20Statewide%20I&R%20Processes.pdf. Accessed June 1, 2010.

  • Initiative and Referendum Institute at the University of Southern California. (n.d.b). Statewide initiatives since 1904. http://www.iandrinstitute.org/New%20IRI%20Website%20Info/Drop%20Down%20Boxes/Historical/Statewide%20Initiatives%201904-2000.pdf. Accessed June 1, 2010.

  • Kirchgässner, G., & Meyer Zu Himmern, A. (1997). Expected closeness and turnout: An empirical analysis for the German general elections, 1983–1994. Public Choice, 91, 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R., Jr. (2000). A simple explanation for why campaign expenditures are increasing: The government is getting bigger. Journal of Law and Economics, 43, 359–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marschall, M., & Ruhil, A. V. S. (2005). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative reconsidered: Addressing endogeneity. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 5(4), 327–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: Evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 619–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (2000). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative in the first half of the twentieth century. Journal of Law and Economics, 43, 619–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (2004). For the many or the few: The initiative, public policy, and American democracy. Chicago, IL.: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (2005). The endogeneity of the initiative: Comment on Marschall and Ruhill. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 5(4), 356–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (2008). Direct democracy and the executive branch. In S. Bowler & A. Glazer (Eds.), Direct democracy’s impact on American political institutions (pp. 115–136). New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G., & McCarty, N. M. (2001). Political resource allocation: benefits and costs of voter initiatives. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 17, 413–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moncrief, G. F. (1998). Candidate spending in state legislative races. In J. A. Thompson & G. F. Moncrief (Eds.), Campaign finance in state legislative elections. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29, 315–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palda, F. (1992). The determinants of campaign spending: The role of the government jackpot. Economic Inquiry, 30, 627–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Primo, D. M., Milyo, J., & Groseclose, T. (2006). State campaign finance reform, competitiveness, and party advantage in gubernatorial elections. In M. M. McDonald & J. Samples (Eds.), The marketplace of democracy: Electoral competition and American politics. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Randolph, G. M. (2010). Measuring the indirect effect: Voter initiatives and legislative production in the American states. Public Finance Review, 38(6), 762–786.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, J. R. (2005). The impact of divided government on legislative production. Public Choice, 123(1–2), 217–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlesinger, J. A. (1966). Ambition and politics: Political careers in the United States. Chicago, IL: Rand-McNally and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistical Abstract of the United States. (2010). http://www.census.gov/compendia/statab/past_years.html. Accessed June 1, 2010.

  • Stonecash, J. (1990). Campaign finance in New York senate elections. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 15, 247–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Council of State Governments. (various years). The book of the states (Vols. 23–35). Lexington, KY: The Council of State Governments.

  • Thompson, J. A., Cassie, W., & Jewell, M. E. (1994). A sacred cow or just a lot of bull? Party and PAC money in state legislative elections. Political Research Quarterly, 47, 223–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tolbert, C., Grummel, J., & Smith, D. (2001). The effects of ballot initiatives on voter turnout in the American states. American Politics Research, 29(6), 625–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to two anonymous referees, editor Alan Hamlin, and Russell S. Sobel for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gregory M. Randolph.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 6.

Table 6 Data sources and variable definitions for gubernatorial analysis

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Randolph, G.M. The voter initiative and the power of the governor: evidence from campaign expenditures. Const Polit Econ 22, 265–286 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-011-9106-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-011-9106-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation