Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The unanimity rule and religious fractionalisation in the Polish-Lithuanian Republic

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyses the role of the unanimity rule—known as liberum veto—in medieval Poland. We argue that the primary effect of the liberum veto was that it secured religious freedom and established domestic peace in an otherwise deeply divided and fractionalised country. What is more, this institution succeeded in doing so during an era which was characterised by violent religious conflicts and rise of absolutist monarchies throughout the European continent. Even after 1652, when the liberum veto seemed to have practically paralysed the decision-making of Polish-Lithuanian parliament, there were still reasons—related to religious issues—why its use could have been preferable to less inclusive voting rules. It can be argued, however, that the use of unanimity was not warranted in questions related to defence, especially in situations of national emergency, although it is questionable to which extent the sole presence of the liberum veto was susceptible to bring about the demise of the Polish-Lithuanian Republic.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Republic of Two Nations, Polish and Lithuanian was established in December 1568, completing thus the personal union of Krewo of 1386. In its original institutional form, it had lasted until the Constitution of 3 May 1791 and the following Partitions which deleted Poland from the map of Europe.

  2. Although the Polish-Lithuanian Republic experienced a long-term stagnation in terms of GDP per capita—due to shocks to agricultural production per capita—data show that Poland lived also through periods of rather steady growth. These were interrupted by massive negative shocks during wars and invasions. See Zanden (2004) for a comparison of Poland’s economic performance with those of other European countries. Allen (2003) shows that development indicators in the Rzeczpospolyta were similar to other countries of Central and Eastern Europe of the era. According to Broadberry and Gupta (2006, pp. 5–8), silver wages of skilled and unskilled labourers in major Polish cities—Gdansk, Warsaw and Krakow—were similar or even exceeded those in Vienna, Leipzig or Augsburg. In terms of rye, wages in Krakow were higher than those in Amsterdam. And in terms of real consumption, Polish urban labourers fared better than those in other major cities of Central and Eastern Europe—and even better than the ones in Milan or in Florence.

  3. Polish word poseł cannot be translated accurately as “representative” or “MP” because it means also “ambassador” and “messenger”.

  4. Obviously, these numbers changed over the history of the Republic.

  5. Zamoyski (1987, p. 101).

  6. See Tiebout’s (1956) famous discussion.

  7. Zamoyski (1987, p. 80).

  8. See Davies (1984, p. 162).

  9. Davies (1984, pp. 339–340) describes Confederation as an armed league of men sworn to pursue their grievance until justice was obtained. Unlike an ordinary rebellion or a civil war, the Confederation was perceived as a legal and constitutional instrument of resistance. Major confederations were formed among towns and nobles. In 1573 the whole Sejm joined the confederation of Warsaw which aimed at establishing religious tolerance.

  10. See Miller (1990).

  11. Jędruch (1993, p. 71).

  12. See also Jędruch (1993, p. 62).

  13. Zamoyski (1987, p. 75).

  14. See Collier and Hoeffler (2004), Fearon and Laitin (2003), Elbadawi and Sambanis (2002) or Hegre and Sambanis (2006).

  15. St. Bartholomew’s Day Massacre was a wave of violence against the Huguenots in France, started on 24th August 1572 (the feast of Barthomolew the Apostle). The total number of victims is unknown but estimates are of the order of tens of thousands.

  16. See for instance Lukowski and Zawadzki (2006).

  17. Jędruch (1993, p. 155).

  18. Ibid: 155.

  19. See Vagts and Vagts (1979).

References

  • Allen, R. C. (2003). Progress and poverty in early modern Europe. Economic History Review, 16, 403–443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barry, B. (1965). Political argument. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1997). Parliament as a wealth-maximizing institution: The right to the residual and the right to vote. International Review of Law and Economics, 17, 455–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y., & Kiser, E. (1997). The development and decline of medieval voting institutions: A comparison of England and France. Economic Inquiry, 35, 244–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry, S., & Gupta, B. (2006). The early modern great divergence: Wages, prices and economic development in Europe and Asia, 1500–1800. Economic History Review, 19, 2–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brzezinski, M. (1998). The struggle for constitutionalism in Poland. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1951). Knut Wicksell on marginal cost pricing. Southern Economic Journal, 18, 173–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calhoun, J. C. (1992). A disquisition on Government. In Ross M. Lence (Ed.), Union and liberty: The political philosophy of John C. Calhoun. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 56, 563–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, N. (1984). God’s playground. A history of Poland (Vol. I). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elbadawi, I., & Sambanis, N. (2002). How much war will we see?: Explaining the prevalence of civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 307–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97, 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frost, R. I. (1990). ‘Liberty without licence?’ The failure of polish democratic thought in the seventeenth century. In J. S. Pula & M. B. Biskupski (Eds.), Polish democratic thought from the renaissance to the great emigration: Essays and documents. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hegre, H., & Sambanis, N. (2006). Sensitivity analysis of empirical results on civil war onset. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 508–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., & Spitzer, M. L. (1986). Experimental tests of the coase theorem with large bargaining groups. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 149–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jędruch, J. (1993). Constitutions, elections and legislatures of Poland, 1493–1993. New York: Hippocrene Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klick, J., & Parisi, F. (2003). The disunity of unanimity. Constitutional Political Economy, 14, 83–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konopczynski, L. (1930). Le liberum veto: Etude sur le développement du principe majoritaire. Paris: Champion.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2005). Endogenizing fractionalization. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1, 75–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lukowski, J., & Zawadzki, H. (2006). A concise history of Poland (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, J. (1990). The sixteenth-century roots of the polish democratic tradition. In J. S. Pula & M. B. Biskupski (Eds.), Polish democratic thought from the renaissance to the great emigration: Essays and documents. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2005). Ethnic polarization, potential conflict, and civil wars. American Economic Review, 95, 796–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1991). Constitutional Rights. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 7, 313–333.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1996). Constitutional democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pula, J. S., & Biskupski, M. B. (Eds.). (1990). Polish democratic thought from the renaissance to the great emigration: Essays and documents. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D. W. (1975). The limits of consensual decision. American Political Science Review, 69, 1270–1294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rousseau, J.-J. (1772). Considerations on the government of Poland and on its proposed reformation, available at: http://www.constitution.org/jjr/poland.htm.

  • Smith, V. L. (1977). The principle of unanimity and voluntary consent in social choice. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 1125–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vagts, A., & Vagts, D. F. (1979). The balance of power in international law: A history of an idea. American Journal of International Law, 73, 555–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Zanden, J. L. (2004). Estimating early modern economic growth, Mimeo, available at: http://www.iisg.nl/research/jvz-estimating.pdf

  • Wicksell, K. (1896). Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen. Jena: Gustav Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zamoyski, A. (1987). The Polish way, a thousand-year history of the Poles and their culture. New York: Hippocrene Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is thankful for valuable comments and suggestions to Tyler Cowen, Pavol Hardos, Peter T. Leeson, Dennis C. Mueller and Charles K. Rowley. Gordon Tullock deserves credit for bringing the issue to our attention. The usual caveat applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dalibor Roháč.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Roháč, D. The unanimity rule and religious fractionalisation in the Polish-Lithuanian Republic. Constit Polit Econ 19, 111–128 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9037-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9037-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation