Skip to main content
Log in

Harmonizing IPRs on Software Piracy: Empirics of Trajectories in Africa

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the current efforts of harmonizing the standards and enforcement of IPRs protection worldwide, this paper explores software piracy trajectories and dynamics in Africa. Using a battery of estimation techniques that ignore as well as integrate short-run disturbances in time-dynamic fashion, we answer the big questions policy makers are most likely to ask before harmonizing IPRs regimes in the battle against software piracy. Three main findings are established. (1) African countries with low software piracy rates are catching-up their counterparts with higher rates; implying despite existing divergent IPRs systems, convergence in piracy rate could be a genuine standard-setting platform. (2) Legal origins do not play a very significant role in the convergence process. (3) A genuine timeframe for standardizing IPRs laws in the fight against piracy is most likely between a horizon of 4–8 years. In other words, full (100 %) convergence within the specified horizon will mean the enforcements of IPRs regimes without distinction of nationality and locality. Policy implications and caveats are discussed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This stance has gained prominence in the debate over if ‘permission’ should be granted to enable ‘copying’ of life-saving pharmaceuticals, especially those used in the management of HIV/AIDS in developing countries most affected and least likely to afford such treatments.

  2. Additional support for the possibility that the changing strength of IPRs regimes is based on a nation’s level of development or current technological ability could be traced in the rapid growth witnessed by South-East Asia. Some evidence suggest that the ‘East Asian Miracle’ could have originated from weaker IPRs regimes at the early stages of these nations’ development in addition to their accumulation of capital. These nations’ capacity to absorb, replicate and duplicate foreign innovations might have contributed to their relatively high growth rates. Further evidence has suggested that, as these countries became significant producers of new technologies and innovations, their IPRs regimes tightened. While Nelson and Pack (1999) have postulated that the productive assimilation of existing (foreign) productive techniques and technologies ‘was a critical component of the success of these countries’, Maskus (2000) cautions that weaker protection of IPRs will not necessarily be beneficial for developing countries as it may cause them to remain dependent on older and less efficient outdated technologies.

  3. The BSA data primarily measures the piracy of commercial software. We are unaware of any publicly available cross-national data on end-user software piracy. See Png (2008) for a discussion on the reliability of piracy data. Also, see Traphagan and Griffith (1998).

  4. Among the many researchers who have used this data are Marron and Steel (2000), Banerjee et al. (2005), Andrés (2006), and Goel and Nelson (2009).

  5. Piracy is strongly associated with poverty: faction of the population with low income. A stance that is valid from economic and cultural considerations (Moores and Esichaikul 2011, p. 1).

  6. The rule of law and regulation quality have a correlation of 87 %. GDP growth and GDP per capita growth: 95 %. Money supply and liquid liabilities: 96 %. PC users and internet penetration: 84 %.

  7. As emphasized by Bezmen and Depken (2004), studies assessing the piracy development nexus are subject to potential endogeneity problems because it is likely that a nation’s level of development is a crucial factor in its choice of or adherence to a particular IPRs regime. This confirms an earlier position by Ginarte and Park (1997) who found strong evidence that the level of economic development explains the strength of patent protection provided by individual countries.

  8. ‘We also demonstrate that more plausible results can be achieved using a system GMM estimator suggested by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). The system estimator exploits an assumption about the initial conditions to obtain moment conditions that remain informative even for persistent series, and it has been shown to perform well in simulations. The necessary restrictions on the initial conditions are potentially consistent with standard growth frameworks, and appear to be both valid and highly informative in our empirical application. Hence we recommend this system GMM estimator for consideration in subsequent empirical growth research’. Bond et al. (2001, pp. 3–4).

  9. While Narayan et al. (2011) have used Eq. (1) in the absence of fixed effects, this paper applies Eqs. (2) and (3) instead, in line with Fung (2009). The Fung (2009) approach has been used in recent African convergence literature (Asongu 2012a, b).

  10. In the one-step, the residuals are assumed to be homoscedastic.

  11. We have 6 two-year non-overlapping intervals: 2000; 2001–2002; 2003–2004; 2005–2006; 2007–2008; 2009–2010. There are also four three-year non-overlapping intervals: 2000–2001; 2002–2004; 2005–2007; 2008–2010. For both types of non-overlapping intervals, owing to the data and periodical constraints, the first interval is short of 1 year.

  12. Note that the second vector of determinants entails the second set of control variables as presented in Table 4 (regulation quality, per capita GDP growth, liquid liabilities, internet penetration, trade and FDI).

  13. This poses no issue because overall interpretations will not be based on the three-year NOI results. Their use enriches the analysis in providing trajectories and dynamics hitherto unexplored in convergence empirics.

  14. World Trade Organization (WTO)/Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS).

  15. WIPO: World Intellectual Property Organization.

References

  • Andrés, A. R. (2006). The relationship between copyright software protection and piracy: Evidence from Europe. European Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R., & Goel, R. K. (2011). Corruption and software piracy: A comparative perspective. Policy and Internet, 3(3), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R., & Goel, R. K. (2012). Does software piracy affect economic growth? Evidence across countries. Journal of Policy Modeling, 34, 284–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apergis, N., Christou, C., & Miller, S. M. (2010). Country and industry convergence in equity markets: International evidence from club convergence and clustering. Department of Banking and Financial Management, University of Piraeus, Greece.

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2012a). African stock market performance dynamics: a multidimensional convergence assessment. Journal of African Business. http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/pramprapa/36055.htm. Accessed 24 Oct 2012.

  • Asongu, S. A. (2012b). African financial development dynamics: big time convergence. African Journal of Economics and Management Studies. http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/pramprapa/36053.htm. Accessed 24 Oct 2012.

  • Banerjee, D., Khalid, A. M., & Sturm, J.-E. (2005). Socio-economic development and software piracy. An empirical assessment. Applied Economics, 37, 2091–2097.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992). Convergence. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 223–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995). Economic growth. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1986). Productivity, growth, convergence and welfare: What the long run data show. American Economic Review, 76, 1072–1085.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bezmen, T. L., & Depken, C. A. (2004). The impact of software piracy on economic development, Working Paper. Florence, SC: Francis Marion University.

  • Bezmen, T. L., & Depken, C. A. (2006). Influences on software piracy: Evidence from the various United States. Economics Letters, 90, 356–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S., Hoeffler, A., & Tample, J. (2001). GMM estimation of empirical growth models. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, G., De Bonis, R., & Silvestrini, A. (2012). Do financial systems converge? New evidence from financial assets in OECD countries. Journal of Comparative Economics, 40, 141–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Business Software Alliance. (2007). 2006 Piracy study. New York: BSA.

  • Business Software Alliance. (2009). What is software piracy? Retrieved May 19 2012 from http://www.bsa.org/Piracy%20Portal.aspx.

  • Caporale, G. M., Erdogan, B., & Kuzin, V. (2009). Testing for convergence in stock markets: a non-linear factor approach. Discussion paper no. 932. Berlin: Deutsches Institut fur Wirtschaftsforschung.

  • Costantini, M., & Lupi, C. (2005). Stochastic convergence among european economies. Economics Bulletin, 3(38), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Depken, C. A., & Simmons, L. (2004). Social construct and the propensity for software piracy. Applied Economics Letters, 11, 97–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falvey, R., Foster, N., & Greenway, D. (2006). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Review of Development Economics, 10, 700–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, M. (2012). Piracy, globalization and the colonization of the Commons. Global Media Journal, 6(1), 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fung, M. K. (2009). Financial development and economic growth: Convergence or divergence? Journal of International Money and Finance, 28, 56–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginarte, J. C., & Park, W. G. (1997). Determinants of patent rights: A cross-national study. Research Policy, 26(3), 283–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goel, R. K., & Nelson, M. A. (2009). Determinants of software piracy: Economics, institutions, and technology. Journal of Technology Transfer, 34, 637–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, D. M., & Gruben, W. C. (1996). The Role of intellectual property rights in economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 48, 323–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Husted, B. W. (2000). The impact of national culture on software piracy. Journal of Business Ethics, 26, 197–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Islam, N. (1995). Growth empirics: A panel data approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(4), 1127–1170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, L. (2004). The multifaceted evolution of Korean technological capabilities and its implications for contemporary policy. Oxford Development Studies, 32(3), 341–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kranenburg, H. L., & Hogenbirk, A.E. (2003). Determinants of multimedia, entertainment, and business software copyright piracy: A cross-national study. Mimeo: Department of Organization and Strategy, University of Maastricht.

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., & Mansfield, E. (1996). Intellectual property protection and U.S. foreign direct investment. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(2), 181–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 407–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1994). Intellectual property protection, foreign direct investment, and technology transfer. Washington, D.C.: International Finance Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marron, D. B., & Steel, D. G. (2000). Which countries protect intellectual property? The case of software piracy. Economic Inquiry, 38(2), 147–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, E. K. (2000). Intellectual property rights and economic development. Boulder: University of Colorado.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, K. E., & Penubarti, M. (1995). How trade related are intellectual property rights? Journal of International Economics, 39, 227–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, S. M., & Upadhyay, M. P. (2002). Total factor productivity and the convergence hypothesis. Journal of Macroeconomics, 24, 267–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moores, T. T., & Esichaikul, V. (2011). Socialization and software piracy: A study. Journal of Computer Information Systems, 1–9. Retrieved 25 October, 2012 from http://iacis.org/jcis/articles/Moores_Esichaikul_51_3.pdf.

  • Narayan, P. K., Mishra, S., & Narayan, S. (2011). Do market capitalization and stocks traded converge? New global evidence. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35, 2771–2781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Pack, H. (1999). The Asian miracle and modern growth theory. Economic Journal, 109, 416–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. American Economic Review, 84, 359–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, W., & Ginarte, J. (1997). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 51–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peitz, M., & Waelbroeck, P. (2006). Piracy of digital products: A critical review of the theoretical literature. Information Economics and Policy, 18, 449–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Png, I. (2008). On the reliability of software piracy statistics. Mimeo: National University of Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous growth and technical change. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 71–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rushing, F. W., & Thompson, M. A. (1996). An empirical analysis of the impact of patent protection on economic growth. Journal of Economic Development, 21(2), 61–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rushing, F. W., & Thompson, M. A. (1999). An empirical analysis of the impact of patent protection on economic growth: An extension. Journal of Economic Development, 24(1), 67–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seyoum, B. (1996). The impact of intellectual property rights on foreign direct investment. Columbia Journal of World Business, 31(1), 50–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SIIA. (2000). SIIA report on global software piracy 2000. Washington, DC: Software and Information Industry Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swan, T. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record, 32, 334–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todaro, M. P., & Smith, S. C. (2003). Economic development (8th ed.). Boston, MA: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Traphagan, M., & Griffith, A. (1998). Software piracy and global competitiveness: Report on global software piracy. International Review of Law, Computers & Technology, 12, 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, G., & Maskus, K. E. (2001). Intellectual property rights, licensing, and innovation in an endogenous product-cycle model. Journal of International Economics, 53, 169–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author is highly indebted to the editor and referees for their very useful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simplice A. Asongu.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 5, 6 and 7.

Table 6 Variable definitions
Table 7 Correlation matrix

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Asongu, S.A. Harmonizing IPRs on Software Piracy: Empirics of Trajectories in Africa. J Bus Ethics 118, 45–60 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1552-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1552-7

Keywords

Navigation