1 Introduction

Stable value funds are an essential investment choice within 401(k) plans, functioning as financial vehicles that ensure capital preservation and augment the range of investment options for investors. The funds’ notoriety is highlighted by the third quarter of 2020, where stable value funds managed over USD $888 billion of assets (2020). A study by 2022 observes that over 82% of defined contribution plans provide stable value funds to their participants. The practical utility of stable value funds is also highlighted by Babbel and Herce (2018), who found that can improve the return of a retirement portfolio through better diversification.Footnote 1

Despite their significant role in the U.S. market, academic studies on stable value funds’ asset–liability management from an insurer’s perspective are scarce, with limited literature such as Kwun et al. (2009) and Kwun et al. (2010). This analytical gap becomes increasingly relevant due to recent trends in stable value funds, where there is a noticeable shift towards lower credit quality and longer-duration assets. This evolution in investment strategy accentuates the need for robust quantitative methods to effectively assess the associated insurance risks.

The 2023 technical defaults of several banks, as highlighted by Dinh (2023), featured distinct participant demographics, especially deposit holders in the venture capital industry, who, as Vo and Le (2023) notes, are likely to know each other, increasing the risk of a bank run. This underscores the importance of understanding the behavioral aspects of participants in asset–liability management. drawing from Alimoradian et al. (2023)’s empirical analysis of 44, 000 monthly cash flows across 297 stable value plans, we model a multicomponent liability model. This model incorporates behavioral factors observed within the participant cash flows such as rate deficit (Dar and Dodds 1989; Sierra Jimenez 2012), reputational mass lapse (Shin 2009), flight-to-safety behavior (Baur and Lucey 2010; Dorn and Huberman 2005), and regime-switching trends.

In this paper, we also introduce a robust asset model that encapsulates the primary risk factors in fixed-income funds. The traditional method for projecting a bond fund in the literature is combining interest rate models with defining fixed coupon payment structure as per Ringer and Tehranchi (2006), Andersson and Lagerås (2013), Alfonsi et al. (2019). However, these models often become overly complex, focusing predominantly on secondary risks such as term-structure basis spread risk. This complexity can overshadow the detection of primary risk factors, namely yield and duration. Our paper aims to address this gap by proposing a more streamlined approach that models the yield, a critical risk factor for diversified fixed-income funds. Utilizing the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) process, we simulate the dynamics of spreads and rates affecting the fund’s yield, with the calibration of the CIR parameters conducted against historical data using the log-likelihood method.

To complement our approach, we define a script that encapsulates the Synthetic GIC’s contractual cash flow terms, enabling us to estimate the insurer’s payoffs. Having scripted the three building blocks in a computer language - the asset model scenario generator, the participants’ cash flow model scenario generator, and the code for the Synthetic contract’s financials, we simulate scenarios using a Monte Carlo framework to assess the Synthetic GIC’s tail risk. We also provide sensitivity analysis to various input data.

Based on the simulation scenarios, we conduct scenario detection analysis to identify common patterns in the most significant tail scenarios produced by the Monte Carlo simulations. This scrutiny of significant tail scenarios helps pinpoint the primary risk scenarios for the insurer.Footnote 2 This risky scenario detection methodology will further assist us in Sect. 7, to further justify our liability cash flow mode; our liability model’s stochastic trend component is key in generating these adverse loss scenarios, in contrast to models like Kwun et al. (2009), which lack an independent stochastic component and struggle to generate high withdrawal rates at critical times. Additionally, the U.S. regulatory approach (2015) for reserve calculation doesn’t fully capture the complex, path-dependent nature of insurance risk in this product, often overlooking the riskiest scenarios in cash flow projections

Ermanno Pitacco’s seminal work on variable annuities (Bacinello et al. 2011) has profoundly influenced our research. His pioneering approach to modeling insurance-linked products has been a guiding beacon for us, particularly his insightful detection of risk scenarios (Bacinello et al. 2010). Pitacco’s blend of theoretical rigor and practical application has not only shaped our research but also continues to influence practices in the insurance industry. The existence of our current research is a testament to the continuity of his innovative thinking.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Sect. 2 introduces the stable value ecosystem, elucidates its structural mechanism, and explains the efficiency of such an investment structure. Section 3 and Sect. 4 present the asset model and the participants’ lapse liability model, respectively. Section 5 overlays the numerical simulation results while Sect. 6 discusses the risk scenarios for the insurer. Section 7 in particular discusses the path-dependent nature of the risk of this product and the suitability of our cash flow model. The paper concludes with a discussion of the economic capital requirements and best practices in stable value fund guarantee risk management. It provides recommendations for practitioners, rating agencies, and regulators on estimating stable value fund wrap risk in Sect. 8.

2 Stable value guaranteed insurance contract

Stable value funds are investment options offered by many defined contribution retirement plans, generally characterized as very low-risk investment options with liquidity and principal preservation similar to money market funds but with slightly higher returns.Footnote 3\(^{,}\)Footnote 4\(^{,}\)Footnote 5

Figure 1 is a pictorial representation of the stable value ecosystem. Participants, in search of low-risk and principal-preserving investments, make their contributions or distributions to a retirement account managed by a bankruptcy-remote trust. These contributions or distributions are made through an employer or a pool of employers, and an investment entity then invests those assets appropriately.Footnote 6 Under the terms of the insurance contract, the assets are guaranteed at book value responsive payment. The details of this book value mechanism will be discussed in the following subsection.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Stable value ecosystem

2.1 Book value wrap accounting

This subsection presents the mathematical formulation for the book value wrap accounting concept in the context of stable value funds. This specific accounting practice allows the fund participants to treat their investments at their original cost plus any credited interest, as opposed to their current market value. This key feature, which allows transactions at book value, provides the principal protection characteristic inherent to stable value funds.

\(B_t\) and \(M_t\) represent the aggregated book value and market value for the sum of all participant contracts, respectively.

Definition 1

We define the following time-dependent processes for each \(t \ge 0\):

  • \(\left\{ M_t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) represents the market value of the fund;

  • \(\left\{ B_t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) denotes the book value of the fund;

  • \(\left\{ \gamma _t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) corresponds to the rate, also known as the crediting rate, that represents the growth of the book value of the fund;

  • \(\left\{ C_t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) represents the cash flow activities in/from the fund.

The book value of the fund evolves according to the following dynamic

$$\begin{aligned} d B_t = B_t \gamma _t dt + d{C}_{t} \,, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

while we assume crediting \(\left\{ \gamma _t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) to be described by the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma _t = \left( \frac{1}{\theta _t} \ln {\frac{M_t}{B_t}} + y_t - p \right) _+, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(p \in \mathbb {R}^+\) is the insurance premium while \(\left\{ \theta _t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) (expressed in years) is the duration, and \(\left\{ y_t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) is the yield of the fund that will be mathematically developed further in this paper.

Remark 1

For general accounts and most separate stable value funds, \(\gamma _t\) can be defined at the discretion of the insurance company. However, for Synthetic GICs and some separate account products, \(\gamma _t\) can be defined by means of an exact formula. While there are several versions for the crediting formulas used within the market, one of the most used formulas corresponds to Eq. (2). Other contracts may use a different crediting rate expression. Still, when expressed in a continuous formulation, they always converge to Eq. (2) (or equivalent have a residual difference w.r.t. this formula).

Note that Eq. (2) is aiming at making the book value converge to the market value in \(\theta _t\) years. Hence, for a given yield \(y_t\) (resembling the growth speed of the market value \(M_t\)) and insurance costs p, the right side of Eq. 2 approximates the crediting rate to achieve the convergence of the book value to the market value in \(\theta _t\) years.

For example, if we assume no cash inflows/outflows, i.e., if \(d C_u=0\) during the period \( [t, t+\theta _t ] \), \(B_t\) depends only on the crediting rate \(\gamma _t\). Moreover, if we neglect market risk, i.e., the market value grows at a pace of \(y_t-p\), then even if there is an asset–liability mismatch at t, i.e., \(B_t \ne M_t\), we desire the two to be the same over \(\theta _t\) years.Footnote 7 However, in reality, both cash inflows and outflows occur, and the yield of the fund changes over time. Furthermore, if \(\gamma _t\le 0\), convergence is no longer guaranteed. This is the motivation behind the fact the fund needs to recourse to an insurance company to cover any losses due to an asset–liability mismatch, which will be further explained in the following Section.

In the context of stable value funds, the retirement plan trust manages assets using an investment entity while being liable for the book value of the assets to the retirement plan participants. To ensure asset–liability parity, the trust enters into a guarantee contract with an insurer.

2.2 Insurance guarantee

Table 1 illustrates a simplified T-account from the 401(k) trust’s perspective. On the left side, the trust manages assets using an investment entity. On the right side, the trust is liable for the book value of the assets to 401(k) plan participants. To ensure asset–liability parity, the trust enters into a guarantee contract with an insurance firm and pays insurance premiums. According to the asset–liability matching principle, the book value plus the sum of insurance premiums should always be at par with the assets.

Table 1 Simplified T-Account from the 401(k) trust’s perspective

A key characteristic of a stable value fund guarantee is that the insurance company acts as the last resort, meaning that as long as the last individual (or the last pool of individuals) has not withdrawn their assets from the fund, the current participants invested in the stable value fund - and not the insurer - will pay for any past fund shortage. In other words, the insurer will make a claim payment only when the assets of the stable value fund have been fully exhausted. The last resort concept is the core advantage of stable value funds over other guaranteed investment structures, making the insurance guarantee relatively more affordable since, because of the last resorting, the embedded put option becomes very remote and out of the money.

Definition 2

The market value deficit \(G_t\), also known as asset–liability mismatch, is defined as the difference between the book value and market value, i.e., \(G_t= B_t-M_t\).

Another key tool is given by the last resort time. Given a time horizon \(T_{max}\), the last resort time \(\hat{T}\) is defined as the time when the market value reaches below zero \(M_{\hat{T}} \le 0\), thus

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{T} = T_{max} \wedge \inf _{t \ge 0} \left\{ t: M_t \le 0 \right\} \,. \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, \(G_{\hat{T}}\) as the insurance loss paid at time \(\hat{T}\), the asset–liability mismatch at the last resort when the last participant withdraws, hence the following

$$\begin{aligned} G_{\hat{T} } = \left( B_{\hat{T} }- M_{\hat{T} } \right) _{+} = B_{\hat{T} } \,, \end{aligned}$$
(3)

holds.

We emphasize that the stochastic resort time \(\hat{T}\) corresponds to a random variable. Although the contract theoretically has no fixed maturity, it’s common to introduce a time horizon, \(T_{max}\), for practical purposes. This is because parties may have the option to terminate the contract early under legal clauses commonly known as extended termination or wind-down. Also, a defined time horizon is necessary for computational simulation. Here, we note that even though in this paper the stochastic last resort time \(\hat{T}\) is determined by computational methods, this variable can also be calculated by means of stochastic optimal control techniques; this analysis is left for further research.

3 Asset model

This section of the paper focuses on modeling the dynamics of the market value of stable value funds, an essential aspect of the asset–liability management framework. Diverging from the methodology of modeling fixed income funds based on the sum of coupons, the model presented in this paper adopts a more generic approach, emphasizing yield as the primary risk factor. This approach is inspired by the way practitioners assess the dynamics and returns of these types of funds.

The following equation describes how the market value of the fund can grow or shrink based on the fund’s cash flows (\(C_t\)), taking into account the insurance premium (p) as a cash outflow.

$$\begin{aligned} dM_t = M_t ( y_t + \delta ) dt - M_t \theta _t d y_t -p B_t dt +d C_t. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

In the model described by Eq. 4, the yield \(y_t\) is crucial as it represents the return on investment. The adjustment rate \(\delta \) accounts for the increase/decrease in the value of the securities within the fund due to factors such as the convexity of the fund, impaired securities, operational volatility, etc. Therefore, in our model, the net expected growth rate of the fund is captured by \(y_t + \delta \). In the real world, the parameter \(\delta \) can be dynamic and stochastic, possibly influenced by various factors including the yield. However, for simplicity in our model, we assume \(\delta \) to be constant. It’s also worth noting that a variation of the model, as seen in Eq. 4, is discussed in the works of Jarrow (1978) and Hopewell and Kaufman (2017).

By concentrating on the yield as the primary risk factor and incorporating the effective duration, this model provides a more suitable approach for understanding and managing the risks associated with fixed-income funds.

To complete our model, we have to define the dynamics of the yield \(\{y_t\}_{t \ge 0}\). A natural approach to modeling the yield of a fixed income fund involves decomposing it into the sum of a risk-free rate \(r_t\) and a spread \(s_t\) given by:

$$\begin{aligned} y_t= r_t +s_t \,. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

The spread \(s_t\) is commonly known as an option-adjusted spread, or OAS.Footnote 8 We also assume that the interest rates and OAS evolves according to the following Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (“CIR”) model.

$$\begin{aligned} d r_t= & {} \kappa _r ( r_t - r_\infty ) dt + \nu _r \sqrt{r_t} dW^r_t \nonumber \\ ds_t= & {} \kappa _s ( s_t - s_\infty ) dt + \nu _s \sqrt{s_t} dW^s_t \nonumber \\ \langle W^s_t, W^r_t \rangle= & {} \rho t. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

The parameters of the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model are detailed as follows: The mean reversion levels, \(r_\infty \) for rates and \(s_\infty \) for spreads, represent the long-term average levels. These parameters are the asymptotic values of the rate \(r_t\) and spread \(s_t\) as t becomes large. The speed of mean reversion is defined by \(\kappa _r\) for rates and \(\kappa _s\) for spreads, indicating how rapidly the reversion towards the mean occurs. The volatilities, \(\nu _r\) and \(\nu _s\), measure the extent of fluctuation in rates and spreads. The model also specifies the initial values for rates and spreads. The Brownian motions \(W^s_t\) and \(W^r_t\) introduce randomness into the model, with \(\rho \) representing the correlation between these two stochastic processes.

4 Liability cash flow model

In this section, we present a model for the liability cash flow dynamics of the stable value fund, focusing on the cash flows generated by the participants’ contributions and withdrawals. Recall that \(C_t\) is the stochastic process representing the accumulated cash flows by the participants of the stable value fund. A positive \(C_t\) indicates the growth of the stable value fund, while a negative \(C_t\) signifies withdrawals from the fund. We define the dynamics of \(\left\{ C_t\right\} _{t \ge 0}\) as per Eq. 7:

$$\begin{aligned} d {C}_{t} = B_t \left( \underbrace{ \beta _t }_{ \text {structural trend including herd behavior}} + \underbrace{g ( r_t - \gamma _t )}_{ \text {rate deficit} } + \underbrace{ f ( s_t ) }_{ \text {flight-to-safety} } \right) dt. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

As it can be deciphered from Eq. 7, the model is composed of key components whose relevance to liability cash flows will be elaborated upon in the rest of this section.

  • A structural, non-monotonic regime-changing trend in cash flows related to the nature of plan sponsors’ ecosystem, which indirectly influences participants’ behavior. In our model, this is captured by the term \(\beta _t\).

  • A rate deficit risk factor: This is represented in our model by the term \(g(r_t-\gamma _t)\). The rate deficit hypothesis, as illustrated in Alimoradian et al. (2023); Barsotti et al. (2016), suggests that withdrawals from financial products can be modeled using interest rate differentials between the product in question and other Conflict of interest rates.

  • A herd behavior component: This component is also included in our model’s \(\beta _t\) term.

  • The cash flow risk-mitigating effect of flight-to-safety behavior during a crisis: In our model, this is captured by the term \(f(s_t)\).

4.1 Regime changing trend component

The regime-changing trend component is important for capturing the dynamics of different market conditions and plan-sponsor ecosystem and their impact on the participant’s cash flows. Alimoradian et al. (2023) conducted empirical data analysis and identified non-monotonic trends within the historical participant cash flow data; they observed that these trends are stochastic, varying in both size and duration, with notable change points. Importantly, they find no strong correlation between trends before and after a change point. This lack of correlation is attributed to an economic intuition that these trends are indicative of the prevailing market environment and the overall health of the plan-sponsor ecosystem.Footnote 9 These observations align with the findings of Madrian and Shea (2001) and Mitchell et al. (2006), who analyzed individual 401(k) account data and concluded that the plan-sponsor’s role is critical in investment allocation decisions. They found that approximately 10% of liability cash flow activities by participants of the fund were found to be influenced by the plan sponsor. Notably, these changes in trends are often structural and unpredictable, contingent on factors like management decisions that extend beyond quantifiable economic variables. For instance, a company with a history of stable employment may continue this trend in the subsequent years. However, if there is a regime change, the trend could swing in any direction.

We define the set \(\left\{ S_i, \tau _i \right\} \) as the i-th state and its time of switching to this state. With this notation, Eq. 8 relates the trends \(\beta \) with the states. In addition, the duration of each state (\(\tau _{i+1}-\tau _i\)) is stochastic, and we assume that it follows an exponential distribution with the intensity parameter \(\frac{1}{d_i}\). Note that \(d_i\) does have a simple economic interpretation; it is the average duration in years of being in the regime \(S_i\). Therefore, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \forall \tau _i \le t \le \tau _{i+1} \,, \quad \beta _t= & {} b_i \nonumber \\ P ( \tau _{i+1} - \tau _i \ge x )= & {} e^{-\frac{x}{d_i} } \, \nonumber \\ P( S_{i} = s )= & {} p_s \,. \end{aligned}$$
(8)

As discussed earlier, in Eq. 9, we assume that the trend of the next regime, \(\beta _{i+1}\), is independent of the trend of the current regime, \(\beta _{i}\).

$$\begin{aligned} (\beta _{i+1}, \tau _{i+1}) \perp \!\!\! \perp (\beta _{i}, \tau _{i}) \,, \end{aligned}$$
(9)

In other words, we assume the parameters of the next regime do not depend on those of the current regime.

To round out our model, we discretize the state process into four states: growth, stability, and decline, and we include an additional herd state. This is depicted in Table 2. The growth state signifies a positive cash flow trend for the fund, whereas the decline state signifies a trend of withdrawals. Note that in Table 2, the probability of occurrence of the herd state is a function of the market-to-book value ratio, while the probabilities of occurrence of other states are considered constant.

Table 2 Participant trends probability of occurrence and their average duration

Table 2 presents a regime-switching model with three main states and an additional state to account for herd behavior. A three-state model offers the benefit of alternating between high, stable, and low withdrawal rates at random intervals. It is worth noting that the goal here is not to prescribe the exact number of states needed for cash flow projections. Instead, we aim to provide a generic model for liability cash flows that aligns with behavioral studies, as seen in Alimoradian et al. (2023). Therefore, an insurance industry practitioner could choose to apply to fewer or more states based on the specific experience of the plan.

4.2 Herd component

The herd state is an important component in our model because it accounts for the potential impact of mass withdrawals on the insurer’s liability. This behavioral component was observed in stable values by Alimoradian et al. (2023). Further, according to studies by Loisel and Milhaud (2011) and Barsotti et al. (2016), peer-to-peer influence and contagion effects can lead to mass correlation in withdrawals among policyholders’ cash flows, resulting in mass lapses. Alimoradian et al. (2023) also note that a low market-to-book value could potentially be perceived as a weakness and hypothetically lead to reputational issues, increasing the likelihood of herd behavior. Therefore, in Table 13, the herd behavior is shown in the last trend component \(p(\frac{M_t}{B_t})\) as a function of market-to-book value.

4.3 Rate deficit component

Equation 7 also has a rate deficit component shown by the function \(g(\cdot )\) as the difference between the yield of the fund and the crediting rate of the stable value fund. This concept, a well-recognized hypothesis in literature, has been empirically examined in studies such as Outreville (1990), Tsai et al. (2002), Floryszczak et al. (2016), Barucci et al. (2020). In Alimoradian et al. (2023), the authors analyze historical data for the years 2000 to 2021 to observe any relationship between the participant’s lapses and the interest rates. However, the authors did not observe any relationship between the rate deficits and the cash flow rates. Still, they pointed out that the historical period of 2000 to 2021 was limited as the market was not exposed to an inflationary period where interest rates rose significantly.

4.4 Flight-to-safety component

The flight-to-safety hypothesis, as discussed in Baur and Lucey (2010), Ji et al. (2020) and Dorn and Huberman (2005), posits that during times of market stress, investors tend to shift their investments from riskier assets to safer assets. The risk-mitigating effect of flight-to-safety was empirically observed in stable values by the study of Alimoradian et al. (2023). This factor should thus be considered when modeling stable value fund liability cash flows to account for potential shifts in participant behavior during market crises.

In this work, we model the ’flight-to-safety’ effect using the function \(f(s_t)\), where \(s_t\) represents the OAS spread of the fund. One might question why we have chosen \(s_t\) as an indicator of market distress and the flight to safety rather than other indicators, such as equity performance. We have two primary reasons for this choice.

First, stable value funds are diversified investment portfolios encompassing a large portion of U.S. fixed income markets. Therefore, these funds are highly correlated with and representative of the U.S. fixed income market. A common indicator of the U.S. financial market entering a crisis is a widening global credit spread, as discussed in Salhi and Thérond (2014). Given its diversified nature, a stable value fund would also experience this widening of spreads during a crisis.

Secondly, the OAS spread is an internal risk factor to the system, impacting both assets and liabilities. Using an internal risk factor is more coherent with the model structure and ensures that the flight-to-safety component is organically integrated into the system. If we chose an external factor, it would be equivalent to adding an independent stochastic component to the model. For instance, if equity performance was used as the argument to the function f(.), it would only be material to the risk measurement if there is a significant correlation between interest rates and equities. Assuming no strong correlation exists, incorporating equities would merely add an independent stochastic factor that would be more appropriately introduced directly into the stochastic trend component as an extra trend state representing process.

5 Wrap risk results

This section outlines the main results from the Monte Carlo simulation of the model we described earlier. Before diving into the specifics, we will introduce an added assumption to the model. In our model framework, the effective duration, represented by \(\theta _t\), indicates how sensitive an asset is to changes in its yield. For the discussions in this paper, we will assume that the effective duration remains constant. This is a reasonable assumption because stable-value funds often have fixed durations due to the investment constraints set by their respective insurance companies. So, for the rest of this paper, we assume that \( \forall t \ge 0 \quad \theta _t = \theta \).

Table 3 shows the loss frequency under different parameter assumptions for the probability of transitioning into a decline (\(p_{1}\)) and different definitions of a decline (\(b_1\)). Other parameter inputs are as described in Appendix A. Table 3 also shows the convexity of the wrap risk resulting when the loss frequency is low, an indication of the remoteness of the risk.Footnote 10

Table 3 Loss frequency for different probabilities of entering a declining state in a year, and different declining state annual withdrawal rate
Table 4 99% CTE of present value (PV) of loss, comparison for the different probabilities of entering a declining state in a year, and different declining state annual withdrawal rate

In our analysis presented in Tables 4 and 3, we set the correlation parameter (\(\rho \)) between interest rates and spread brownians as zero. Recognizing the sensitivity of our results to this parameter, we conducted an expanded analysis across different correlation levels, as shown in Table 5. Table 5 illustrates that a higher correlation between OAS and interest rates slightly heightens the tail risk for insurance guarantees. This is intuitively expected, as higher correlation between the two variables, implies higher volatility for the fund which means higher chances of the fund reaching to lower market-to-book value ratios. However, the Table 5 also shows that the results are not very sensitive to this parameter.

Table 5 Loss frequency and 99% CTE of PV of loss for different correlation between rate and spreads’ Brownians.

As detailed by Duffee (1998), the relationship between interest rates and OAS spreads is complex and regime-dependent, often exhibiting a negative correlation. In addition to Duffee (1998), which focused on corporate bonds, one may realize by looking at Table 6 that there is a very high concentration on mortgage-backed securities in stable value funds. These securities are known to experience duration convexity, and consequent OAS spread variations due to prepayment behaviors during rate fluctuations (Hanson 2014; Boudoukh et al. 1997). This adds another layer to the nuanced interplay between interest rates and OAS spreads for stable value funds. However, our analysis in Table 5 indicates that the first-order risk sensitivity to the correlation factor \(\rho \) is not substantial. Therefore, even though the relationship is more complex than just correlating two Brownians, our choice of the model is fit for the purpose simply because the sensitivity of the tail risk of the guarantee to this relationship seems to be limited.Footnote 11 Given the non-stationarity and predominantly negative correlation, along with the limited sensitivity to \(\rho \), we maintain a zero correlation assumption for the remainder of this paper.

Table 6 shows that stable value funds consist of various asset classes, including Asset-Backed Securities (ABS), Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities (RMBS), Commercial Mortgage-Backed Securities (CMBS), and Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBS). This table presents three portfolios with varying risk levels based on their allocations to these securities: Portfolio 1 has the lowest risk, Portfolio 3 the highest, and Portfolio 2 represents a medium risk profile. We, therefore, analyze the impact of credit quality and asset composition on wrap risk.Footnote 12 We then performed a risk analysis for these different portfolios in Table 7 shows the risk profile of the wrap for Portfolio 1, 2, and 3; it shows how the stable value wraps tail risk increases when guaranteeing riskier assets.

Table 6 Asset Allocation for three investment portfolios. Portfolio 1 is of lowest risk profile, followed by Portfolio 2 and 3 which are respectively of higher risk
Table 7 Guarantee risk of funds with different investment portfolios for a wrap contract specified in Sect. A.

Most stable value wraps do not cover, or only partially cover, the default risk of the assets. However, in practice, investment managers can sell the assets before any default occurs. Therefore, the fund will still likely experience a market value loss due to credit rating migration. This credit migration risk is embedded in the parameter \(\delta \) of Eq. 4 of our model.Footnote 13 We note that, in the real world, \(\delta \) can be time-dependent and stochastic in nature. However, for simplicity, we assume that \(\delta \) is constant. Nevertheless, given this simplification, we consider a conservative approach in setting this parameter, and also for completeness, we provided results for a range of values for the \(\delta \) parameter in Table 7.

To ensure our paper’s findings are not overly dependent on the time of publication, we did not set the initial OAS spread (\(s_0\)) to the most current market-calibrated level in any of the results shown in this paper. Instead, we used the long-term mean level (\(s_{\inf }\)) for \(s_0\). However, to study how changes in the current OAS spread level might affect our results, we conducted additional analyses. The outcomes of these analyses are presented in Table 8, demonstrating that the tail risk of wrap has little sensitivity to variations in \(s_0\).

Table 8 Loss frequency and 99% Conditional Tail Expectation (CTE) of the present value (PV) of loss for different initial OAS spread levels (\(s_0\)) of Portfolio 1.

One factor that has a strong impact on the tail risk of the guarantee is the duration. Table 9 shows that funds with higher duration have significantly greater tail risk. As an example, the loss frequency increases from 0.03% to 3.22% from a 3-year to a 6-year stable value fund duration.

Table 9 Guarantee risk for different asset durations. For this analysis, we assumed \(b_1= 1/5\), and \(p_1= 1/20\)

Lastly, we also reviewed the statutory reserve and capital requirements for the wrap contract and compared it with the tail risk of the model presented here.

The U.S. National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) model regulation for reserve estimation for Synthetic GICs are described in (2015). The execution of the model regulation, generally requires insurers to project liability cash flows, presupposing a minimum guaranteed rate, typically set at 0% for individually managed Synthetic GICs. Since liabilities almost invariably possess a 0% crediting rate floor, the present value of liabilities predominantly falls below the market value of assets. Therefore, for a typical individually managed Synthetic GICs contract similar to the one presented in Appendix A, the reported reserve is almost always 0, and the reserve margin is positive. The reserve margin is defined as the positive part of the difference between the market value of assets and the present value of projected guaranteed liabilities.

Also, NAIC’s Risk Based Capital (RBC) for Synthetic GICs are detailed in 2021.Footnote 15 The NAIC risk-based capital rules treat Synthetic GICs akin to guaranteed separate accounts, as deduced from 2021:

“Synthetic GICs are contracts with provisions similar to separate accounts with guarantees, except that the insurance company does not own the assets. For businesses of this type, the C1 and C-3 risk-based capital is determined to be the same as if the insurance company owned the assets and provided the same guarantees as in a guaranteed separate account.”

Further elaboration on guaranteed separate accounts interprets C-1 and C-3 components, with potential offsets by the reserve margin. 2021 statement:

“Non-Indexed Separate Accounts: ... For contracts valued using the fair value of assets and the fair value (at current interest rates) of liabilities, risk-based Capital is calculated as the excess of the regular C-1 and C-3 standards over the applicable reserve margins...”

It is worth noting that the Appendix for RBC capital in Fabozzi (1998) does not explicitly mention this offsetting effect. However, the interpretation posits that any computed C-1 and C-3 capital can be offset against any reserve margins. Given that a typical individually managed Synthetic GIC, such as the one presented in Appendix A, possesses a positive reserve margin, effectively neutralizing the C-1 and C-3 capital impact. Therefore, due to this potential offset of both C-1 and C-3 risks by the reserve margin, risk-based capital typically culminates in zero allocation.

Table 10 illustrates the NAIC reserve and capital charges for a U.S. insurer under the formulaic approach and the assumption of reserve estimates regulation 2015. For completeness, we also assessed the 99% conditional tail expectation (CTE), the loss frequency, and the average loss size.

Table 10 Monte Carlo based estimation of the stable value fund wrap risk. For this analysis, we assumed \(b_1= 1/5\), and \(p_1= 1/20\).

6 Risk scenarios to be considered by an insurer

The main objective of this paper is to introduce the readers to the risk scenarios from the insurer’s perspective. In order to do this, we projected assets and liabilities within a Monte Carlo framework and studied the scenarios in which losses are observed. This exercise helped us to identify two common patterns: the yield spike mean reverting scenario and the inflationary scenario. In this section, we discuss these scenarios and provide historical backtests to assess their validity.

6.1 Inflation

Figure 2 shows the average yield and withdrawal rates for the loss threshold of 0.1% centile. This is the highest threshold of losses, and, as can be seen, the most extreme scenarios occur when the yields are rising with strong withdrawal rates occurring simultaneously. We call these scenarios the inflationary scenarios.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Top 0.1% average loss path scenarios. Data source: Monte Carlo simulation

Inflationary yield rises have already happened historically, specifically during the inflationary period of the late 1970 s/early 1980 s and during the Great Depression Period of the 1930 s. Although stable value funds did not exist at the time, evaluating a hypothetical wrap risk during these periods may provide insight into the magnitude of the risk. Therefore, without any explicit assumptions, we back-test a wrap contract against these periods.

1970 s Inflationary Period: In the late 1970 s and into the early 1980 s, there was an inflationary period that experienced sustained double-digit interest rates for approximately three years (Fig. 3). From the perspective of stable value fund assets, this scenario would have exhibited a longer period of adverse market conditions than the 2008 financial crisis. However, higher yields also allow the crediting rate reset mechanism to potentially converge to differences between market values and book values. Figure 4 below shows a hypothetical loss scenario over this period. Although stable value funds did not exist at the time, we used historical data from the Federal Reserve to construct this hypothetical scenario. It shows an insurance loss scenario with cash withdrawal rates of 40% annually (\(\sim \) 4.16% monthly) for a sustained period of 7 years. In the figure, the fund yield is the historical yield level obtained by summing the 3y UST rates and the OAS spreads. Interest rates were based on 2020, and OAS spreads were estimated using US Moody’s equivalent Baa corporate bonds available from 2020.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Hypothetical Synthetic GIC contract with losses during the Inflationary Period if stable value funds had existed at the time. Data source: Simulated backtest against historical data by 2020

Great Depression Period: Interest rates also reached double digits during the Great Depression, starting in the late 1920 s. With the Great Depression lasting approximately ten years, the adverse conditions would have lasted much longer than the 2008 financial crisis. Figure 4 shows a hypothetical loss scenario over this period. The graph shows the losses incurred for a 60% annualized withdrawal rate for a sustained period of 3 years. Once again, high yields combined with worsening withdrawal rates produce an environment that can result in sustained losses.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Great Depression hypothetical scenario. The same data sources as the inflationary period were used for this analysis. Data source: Simulated backtest against historical data by 2020

COVID-19 Pandemic: Post-COVID-19 pandemic is not yet known, the U.S. economy has experienced high inflation and rising interest rates during much of the aftermath of the pandemic with stable value funds, consequently experiencing asset–liability mismatches that could result in a loss when coupled with a high withdrawal rates. Figure 5 shows the consequence of the aftermath of the pandemic period for a very high withdrawal scenario on a hypothetical fund. The long-term effect of the pandemic is not yet known, but for the example wrap contract, there is an 11% market value to book value deficit, so the wrap may incur losses if it experiences a high withdrawal rate in the future.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Post COVID-19 pandemic inflationary scenario assuming no liability cash flows (positive or negative). Data source: Valerian Capital Group LLC proprietary data for the SV Fund Yield

Fig. 6
figure 6

The yield spike mean reverting scenarios observed within the 1% of loss scenarios. Data source: simulated single scenario

6.2 Yield spike

Figure 6 shows another pattern observed within the 1% loss scenarios. The pattern shows a period in which yields rise and withdrawals co-occur, followed by sustained lower yields, which we refer to as yield spike mean reverting scenarios. The mean reverting scenario is when yields rise sharply and then subsequently revert back to more normalized levels. While the normalization of market conditions would likely suggest the mitigation of risk, this scenario is risky if it coincides with very large withdrawals during high yield periods. Suppose large withdrawals do not occur during high yield periods. In that case, mean reversion will have a lesser impact since there will be capital gains that offset any capital losses that occurred during the original increase in yields. As such, the path to a loss is a “run” on the stable value fund with a large proportion of the book value balances withdrawn over a relatively short period of time. The interrelationship in this scenario is path dependent; higher yields followed by mean reversion and withdrawals combine to create a low-yielding environment without a likelihood of market-to-book value convergence.

Financial Crisis: The reader may again realize that mean-reverting scenarios have also happened historically, specifically during the 2008 financial crisis. During the financial crisis, there were adverse conditions that reduced the market value of stable value fund assets. However, most of the funds did not experience net cash outflows, so there were no actual wrap contract losses experienced during the financial crisis.Footnote 16 Furthermore, as shown below in Fig. 7, the market value of stable value fund assets rose significantly by mid-2009 as shown by the negative market value deficit, i.e., by mid-2009, the market value had returned to a level equal to or greater than the book value.

Figure 7 shows a loss scenario under a potential cash flow withdrawal rate. The graph shows a loss scenario generated by a 60% (\(\sim \) 7.35% monthly) annualized withdrawal rate occurring for a sustained period of 18 months.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Withdrawal scenario that would have generated losses as a result of the financial crisis. Simulated backtest

The inflation and mean reverting yield spike are the two riskiest scenarios observed within our projected paths. In both of these scenarios, a common characteristic is that an increase in yields aligns with significant cash flow withdrawals. When yields rise, the market value of assets, as well as the gap between assets and liabilities, expands. If this coincides with substantial withdrawals, the gap becomes irrecoverable, leading to losses for the insurer. Another way to describe the economics behind the above scenarios is through the time of recovery of an asset–liability mismatch. In the discussion in Sect. 2.1, we showed that if there is no market risk, and no cash flow risk, and the crediting rate formula has not reached its plateau of 0%, then book and market value will converge over \(\theta \) years. This last condition in our previous statement is crucial. If the market-to-book ratio is very low, one can see that crediting rate formula 2 will result in a 0% crediting rate and therefore, the recovery time will be much longer. In addition, when we have strong withdrawals coinciding with a low market-to-book value, each withdrawal will worsen the market-to-book ratio hence in mathematical terms we have: \( \dfrac{M_t}{B_t}< 1 \Rightarrow \dfrac{M_t-\Delta }{B_t-\Delta } < \dfrac{M_t}{B_t} \). Therefore, the riskiest scenarios from the insurance perspective are withdrawals occurring during low market-to-book ratio, because they will make the convergence of market-to-book to par longer, if not impossible. Such a scenario of low market-to-book ratio as such can occur only if the yields rises. This is the basis of the inflation and mean reverting yield spike.

7 Path dependence of synthetic GIC Risk and the suitability of the liability model

This section investigates the path-dependent nature of Synthetic GIC risk and our model’s aptitude for generating scenarios that replicate the riskiest paths.

In section 6, we identified inflation and mean-reverting yield spikes as the primary risk scenarios. When these scenarios coincide with large withdrawals, they lead to insurer losses. However, the timing of withdrawals is crucial-they must follow the yield increase, but not too distantly.

Figure 8 presents three variations of the mean-reverting scenario. The left graph shows a scenario with early withdrawals, and the right graph depicts late withdrawals. Neither of these scenarios results in losses. Conversely, the central scenario represents a substantial loss payment, demonstrating the significant impact of withdrawal timing on insurance loss.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Three variations of the mean reverting scenario. Data source: simulated backtest.Data source: simulated single scenario

Indeed, not only is the timing of withdrawals crucial but so too are the periods without withdrawals. Figure 9 compares the same mean reverting scenario with a deterministic model with constant withdrawal rates and one where the same withdrawal rates only occur during a yield spike. A severe loss of about 11% of the original notional results is evident when the withdrawal rate occurs within 24 months (left graph). Conversely, if a deterministic trend model were used, the loss would be just below 2% (right graph).

Fig. 9
figure 9

A mean-reverting scenario example. If a deterministic model were used instead, the loss size would be less than 2% of the initial book value. Conversely, combining cash flow withdrawals with the stable value fund’s significant market value decrease results in an approximately 11% loss of the initial book value. Data source: simulated backtest

Figure 10 further emphasizes the impact of synchronizing the yield spike period with the withdrawal period by comparing the insurance loss size for various withdrawal starting dates. The same yield spike scenario forms the basis for this comparison, with annual withdrawal rates of 20%, 40%, and 60% over 48 months. The x-axis marks the withdrawal starting period relative to the yield spike initiation date. Negative values on the x-axis denote withdrawals starting before the yield increase, and positive values indicate withdrawals beginning after the yield increase. The most substantial insurance loss arises when the withdrawal kick-off aligns with the yield spike onset.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Insurance loss size (Market-to-Book value deficit) as a function of the withdrawal starting date relative to the yield spike initiation date. Data source: simulated backtest

The stochastic state trend component of our cash flow model provides flexibility in high withdrawal rate durations and starting periods, as well as non-withdrawal periods. Therefore, our model can generate the riskiest paths due to this stochastic trend component. However, if our model only incorporated a rate-deficit component, akin to the model in Kwun et al. (2010), the mean-reverting scenario depicted in Fig. 11 would generate no losses as withdrawals would not be correctly timed.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Mean reverting scenario with a linear rate-deficit withdrawal model g(.). Data source: simulated backtest. Data source: simulated backtest

We should note that while the examples given primarily focused on the mean-reverting yield spike scenario, we also tested the inflationary scenario. Our findings confirm that for both scenarios, the highest insurance loss occurs when periods of high withdrawals coincide with the yield spike or inflationary period.

In conclusion, our cash flow model, with its stochastic multi-state beta component, proves an adaptable tool for the valuation and risk management of insurance liabilities arising from stable value wrap contracts. The path-dependent nature of Synthetic GIC risk necessitates a model capable of generating a wide variety of loss scenarios with variable withdrawal timings and durations. Our model’s flexibility, combined with its grounding in empirical participant behavior, allows it to generate nuanced risk scenarios critical for effective risk management of stable value funds.

8 Conclusions

The paper describes a methodology for insurance companies to use within their ERM framework to better understand risk scenarios, assess tail risk, and determine capital requirements for stable value guarantees. Hence, our model can be used to estimate the capital requirements for the insurance company to maintain a certain low probability of insufficient capital for loss payments. In this research, we proposed and tested an asset and liability model for stable value fund wraps.

On the asset side, we suggested an innovative approach to modeling fixed income funds that offers a compelling alternative to traditional arbitrage-free interest rate models, which we argue are ill-suited to handle large portfolios of fixed-income funds. Our model’s core strength lies in its ability to capture the primary risk factor for fixed-income funds, the yield, despite its simplicity.

On the liability side, we introduced a multi-component model encapsulating a rate deficit, regime switching trends, herd behavior, and a flight-to-safety component. We argue this is the most suitable model for detecting risk scenarios from the insurer’s perspective. Furthermore, our model is consistent with empirical observations that detect long-to-medium-term trends within historical data.

Through our research, we identified two critical scenarios: the inflationary scenario and the mean reverting yield spike scenario. The importance of these scenarios lies in their ability to provide comparative notes on different risk sectors, aiding companies in assessing their aggregate risk exposures.

Economic capital requirements were a focus of our research. Our findings showed that the tail CTE, as a measure of economic capital, is starkly different from the NAIC’s approach, which almost always results in zero capital. We noted the significance of understanding the differing statutory capital requirements under various regulations. While we did not explicitly calculate the Solvency II capital for a typical fund, our analysis suggests that it would likely be near zero for a fund with 100% market-to-book ratio due to less frequent loss occurrences. In contrast, the Swiss solvency test’s 99% expected shortfall might demonstrate a non-zero capital charge.

The research highlights the vital influence of duration on tail risk. Our findings show an almost threefold increase in estimated loss frequency for a six-year fund guarantee compared to a four-year fund, with the loss size being more than twice as large. Additionally, we highlighted how the composition of the portfolio and the credit quality of assets influence tail risk. To illustrate this, we provided metrics for tail risk across various stable value fund portfolios, each with differing risk levels.

In conclusion, our research underscores the necessity for a model that can generate variable withdrawal scenarios in response to fluctuations in yield. We demonstrated that our multi-state beta component model outperforms deterministic trend models and rate-deficit function models in capturing the complex interplay between yield spikes, inflation, and participant withdrawal behavior. Our research contributes to a comprehensive understanding of Synthetic GIC risk management, with our model’s flexibility accommodating additional factors specific to the insurance contract. This model serves as a step towards better industry practices in managing Synthetic GIC risks and a robust foundation for further research.