Skip to main content
Log in

Approximate hedging for nonlinear transaction costs on the volume of traded assets

  • Published:
Finance and Stochastics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper is dedicated to the replication of a convex contingent claim h(S 1) in a financial market with frictions, due to deterministic order books or regulatory constraints. The corresponding transaction costs can be rewritten as a nonlinear function G of the volume of traded assets, with G′(0)>0. For a stock with Black–Scholes midprice dynamics, we exhibit an asymptotically convergent replicating portfolio, defined on a regular time grid with n trading dates. Up to a well-chosen regularization h n of the payoff function, we first introduce the frictionless replicating portfolio of \(h^{n}(S^{n}_{1})\), where S n is a fictitious stock with enlarged local volatility dynamics. In the market with frictions, a suitable modification of this portfolio strategy provides a terminal wealth that converges in \(\mathbb{L}^{2}\) to the claim h(S 1) as n goes to infinity. In terms of order book shapes, the exhibited replicating strategy only depends on the size 2G′(0) of the bid–ask spread. The main innovation of the paper is the introduction of a “Leland-type” strategy for nonvanishing (nonlinear) transaction costs on the volume of traded shares, instead of the commonly considered traded amount of money. This induces lots of technicalities, which we overcome by using an innovative approach based on the Malliavin calculus representation of the Greeks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Alfonsi, A., Schied, A., Schulz, A.: Optimal execution strategies in limit order books with general shape functions. Quant. Finance 10, 143–157 (2010)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Avellaneda, M., Stoikov, S.: High-frequency trading in a limit order book. Quant. Finance 8, 217–224 (2008)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Bouchaud, J.-P., Mézard, M., Potters, M.: Statistical properties of stock order books: empirical results and models. Quant. Finance 2, 251–256 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Cont, R., Stoikov, S., Talreja, R.: A stochastic model for order book dynamics. Oper. Res. 58, 549–563 (2010)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  5. Cherny, A.S., Engelbert, H.J.: Singular Stochastic Differential Equations. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, vol. 1858. Springer, Berlin (2005)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Darses, S., Lépinette, E.: Limit theorem for a modified Leland hedging strategy under constant transaction costs rate. In: Kabanov, Y., Rutkowski, M., Zariphopoulou, T. (eds.) Inspired by Finance. The Musiela Festschrift, pp. 159–199. Springer, Berlin (2014)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  7. Denis, E., Kabanov, Yu.: Mean square error for the Leland–Lott hedging strategy: convex pay-off. Finance Stoch. 14, 625–667 (2010)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Farmer, J.D., Gillemot, L., Lillo, F., Sen, A.: What really causes large price changes? Quant. Finance 4, 383–397 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Friedman, A.: Stochastic Differential Equations and Applications, vol. 1. Academic Press, San Diego (1975)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Fournié, E., Lasry, J.M., Lebuchoux, J., Lions, P.L., Touzi, N.: Applications of Malliavin calculus to Monte Carlo methods in finance. Finance Stoch. 3, 391–412 (1999)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Fukasawa, M.: Conservative delta hedging under transaction costs. In: Takahashi, A., Muromachi, Y., Nakaoka, H. (eds.) Recent Advances in Financial Engineering 2011, pp. 55–72. World Scientific, Singapore (2012)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  12. Kabanov, Y., Safarian, M.: On Leland’s strategy of option pricing with transaction costs. Finance Stoch. 1, 239–250 (1997)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Karatzas, I., Shreve, S.E.: Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin (1998)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  14. Leland, H.: Option pricing and replication with transactions costs. J. Finance XL, 1283–1301 (1985)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Lépinette, E.: Modified Leland’s strategy for constant transaction costs rate. Math. Finance 22, 741–752 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Lott, K.: Ein Verfahren zur Replikation von Optionen unter Transaktionkosten in stetiger Zeit. Dissertation. Universität der Bundeswehr München, Institut für Mathematik und Datenverarbeitung (1993). Unpublished

  17. Nguyen, H.T., Pergamenshchikov, S.M.: Approximate hedging problem via Leland’s strategy for stochastic volatility markets (2012). Available online http://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00747689

  18. Pergamenchtikov, S.: Limit theorem for Leland’s strategy. Ann. Appl. Probab. 13, 1099–1118 (2003)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  19. Protter, P.E.: Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations, 2nd. edn. Stochastic Modelling and Applied Probability. Springer, Berlin (2004). Version 2.1

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  20. Sekine, J., Yano, J.: Hedging errors of Leland’s strategies with time-inhomogeneous rebalancing (2008). Available online https://lmb.univ-fcomte.fr/archives/ps/bachelier3/slides2008/sekine.pdf

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Romuald Elie.

Additional information

This paper has received financial support from the Dauphine Chair in Asset Management, an initiative of Amundi and the University Paris-Dauphine, under the aegis of the Dauphine Foundation.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Convergence to the buy-and-hold price

Suppose that h(x)=(xK)+ is the convex payoff function associated to the call option. We want to prove that the prices \((\widehat {C}^{n}(0,S_{0}))\) converge to S 0 as n goes to ∞. To this end, observe that \(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}\), x=S 0, admits the Doléans-Dade form \(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{t}:=\exp (Z^{n}_{t}-(1/2)\langle Z^{n}\rangle_{t})\). We introduce for any M>0 the stopping time τ n,M:=inf{t: 〈Z n t M}. We easily show that \(\mathbb{Q}[\langle Z^{n}\rangle_{T}< M]\to0\) as n→∞, so that \(\langle Z^{n}\rangle_{T\wedge\tau^{n,M}}\to M\) as n→∞. Indeed, we may assume without loss of generality that Z n is bounded.

Observe that h may be uniformly approximated by a sequence of smooth convex functions g m with bounded first derivatives. Therefore, we may assume without loss of generality that h is smooth. When the payoff function is h(x)=x, we easily get that \(x=\widehat{C}^{n}(t,x)=\mathbb{E}\widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}_{T}\), so that the supermartingale \(\widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}\) is a martingale. Using the Itô decomposition, we deduce from the convexity of g m that for all stopping times τ, \(\mathbb{E}g^{m}(\widehat {S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T})\ge\mathbb{E}g^{m}(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge \tau ^{n,M}})\) and \(\mathbb{E}h(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T})\ge\mathbb {E}h(\widehat {S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge\tau^{n,M}})\) as m goes to ∞. Therefore, by Fatou’s lemma,

$$\liminf_n \mathbb{E}h(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T})\ge\mathbb {E}\liminf_n h\big(\widehat {S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge\tau^{n,M}}\big). $$

Using the time change \(Z^{n}_{t}=B_{\langle Z^{n} \rangle_{t}}\), where B is a Brownian motion in a new filtration (see Theorem II.42 in [19]), we deduce that

$$\mathbb{E}\liminf_n h\big(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge\tau ^{n,M}}\big)\ge \int_\mathbb{R}h\big(xe^{\sqrt{M}z-\frac{1}{2}M}\big)\varphi(z)\,dz, $$

where φ is the density of the standard Gaussian distribution. As M goes to ∞, using the explicit expression on the right-hand side in this inequality as the Black–Scholes price of the call of maturity 1 and strike \(\sqrt{M}\), we get \(\mathbb {E}\liminf_{n} h(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge\tau^{n,M}})\ge x\). On the other hand, \(\mathbb{E}h(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge \tau ^{n,M}})\le\mathbb{E}(\widehat{S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T\wedge\tau^{n,M}})=x\) since h(x)≤x. Therefore, we obtain \(\mathbb{E}h(\widehat {S}^{n,(0,x)}_{T})\to x\) as n→∞.  □

1.2 A.2 Proof of Proposition 3.6

Note that we cannot immediately conclude about the existence of a solution of (3.7) because the operator is not uniformly parabolic on (0,∞)×(0,1). This is why we bring the problem back to another one whose domain satisfies the required uniform parabolicity.

Fix \(n\in\mathbb{N}\). Recall from Lemma 3.2 that \(\widehat {S}^{n}\) is the unique solution of the stochastic equation

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}_s =& x + \int_t^s \hat{\gamma }_n(\widehat {S}^{n,(t,x)}_u) \,dW_u , \quad t\le s \le1,\ (t,x)\in[0,1]\times (0,\infty), \end{aligned}$$

where we use the superscript (t,x) in order to emphasize the initial condition. Introducing \(\hat{\gamma}_{n}^{m}:x\mapsto\sqrt{\sigma^{2}x^{2}+\sigma \gamma_{n} |x|+m^{-1}}\), we denote by \(\widehat{S}^{n,m}\) the solution of

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{S}^{n,m,(t,x)}_s =& x + \int_t^s \hat{\gamma }_n^m(\widehat{S}^{n,m,(t,x)}_u) \,dW_u , \quad t\le s \le1,\ (t,x)\in [0,1]\times(0,\infty), \end{aligned}$$

for any m>0. Since \(\| \hat{\gamma}_{n}^{m}-\hat{\gamma}_{n} \|_{\infty}\le m^{-1/2}\) for m>0, we obtain \(\widehat{S}^{n,m,(t,x)}_{1} \to \widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}_{1}\) in \(\mathbb{L}^{2}\) as m goes to ∞, uniformly in (t,x)∈[0,1]×(0,∞). We deduce that the functions \(\widehat{C}^{n,m}(t,x) := \mathbb{E}[ h^{n}(\widehat {S}^{n,m,(t,x)}_{1}) \mid \mathcal{F}_{t}]\) converge uniformly, as m→∞, to the function \(\widehat{C}^{n}(t,x) := \mathbb{E}[ h^{n}(\widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}_{1}) \mid \mathcal{F}_{t}]\).

Applying Lemma 5.3.3 from [9] with Condition (A′) together with the estimate |∇h n|≤L implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \big|\widehat{C}^{n,m}(t,x) - \widehat{C}^{n,m}(u,y)\big|\le L \sqrt {\mathbb{E}\big| \widehat{S}^{n,(x,t)}_1 - \widehat {S}^{n,(u,y)}_1\big|^2} \le K \sqrt{(x-y)^2+|t-u|} \end{aligned}$$

for m>0, 0≤t,u≤1, and x,y≤|R| for a given R∈(0,∞), where the constant K depends on n, m, and R. We deduce that \(\widehat{C}^{n,m}\) is continuous for any m>0, and hence so is \(\widehat{C}^{n}\).

Fix m>0. We use arguments of Sect. 6.3 in [9] and try to follow their notation. Let us consider the sets

$$\begin{array}{rl@{\qquad}rl} Q_m :=& (0,1)\times\bigg(\dfrac{1}{m},m\bigg), & B_m &:= \{ 1\} \times\bigg(\dfrac{1}{m},m\bigg) , \\ T_m :=& \{0\} \times\bigg(\dfrac{1}{m},m\bigg) , & S_m &:= [0,1) \times\bigg\{ \dfrac{1}{m},m\bigg\} . \end{array} $$

For each yS m , it is easy to observe that there exists a closed ball \(K_{y}^{m}\) such that \(K_{y}^{m}\cap Q_{m}=\emptyset\) and \(K_{y}^{m}\cap \overline{Q_{m}}=\{y\}\). It follows that the function W y proposed in [9, Eq. (2.4) in Chap. 6] defines a barrier for each yS m . Besides, \(\widehat{C}^{n}\) and h n are continuous, and \(\hat{\sigma}_{n}\) is Lipschitz on \(\overline{Q_{m}}\). By [9, Theorem 6.3.6] we deduce that the Dirichlet problem

$$\begin{array}{rl@{\quad}l} \displaystyle u_t(t,x)+\frac{1}{2}\hat{\sigma }_n^2(x)x^2u_{xx}(t,x)&=0, &(t,x)\in Q_m \cup T_m,\\ \displaystyle u(T,x) &= h^n(x),& x\in B_m,\\ \displaystyle u(t,x) &= \widehat{C}^n(t,x),&(t,x)\in S_m, \end{array} $$

admits a unique solution u n,m, which is continuous on \(\overline {Q_{m}}\) with continuous derivatives \(u^{n,m}_{t}\), \(u^{n,m}_{xx}\) on Q m T m . Moreover, [9, Theorem 6.5.2] implies that u n,m has the stochastic representation

$$\begin{aligned} u^{n,m}(t,x) =& \mathbb{E}\Big( \widehat{C}^n \big(\tau^m,\widehat {S}^{n,(t,x)}_{\tau^m}\big){\mathbf{1}_{\{\tau^m< 1\}}} + h^n\big(\widehat {S}^{n(t,x)}_1\big){\mathbf{1}_{\{\tau^m=1\}}} \Big) , \quad(t,x)\in Q_m, \end{aligned}$$

where τ m is the first time when \(\widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}\) exits Q m . The definition of \(\widehat{C}^{n}\) implies

$$\begin{aligned} u^{n,m}(t,x) =& \mathbb{E}\widehat{C}^n \big(\tau^m,\widehat{S}^{n,(t,x)}_{\tau ^m}\big) = \mathbb{E}h^n\big(\widehat{S}^{n(t,x)}_1\big) = \widehat{C}^{n}(t,x) , \quad(t,x)\in Q_m. \end{aligned}$$

As m→∞, we deduce that \(\widehat{C}^{n}\) solves the PDE (3.7). Moreover, the function \(\bar{C}^{n}: (t,y) \mapsto\widehat{C}^{n}(t,e^{y})\) solves the uniformly parabolic PDE

$$\begin{array}{rl@{\quad}l} \displaystyle v_t(t,y)+\frac{1}{2}\hat{\sigma }^2_n(e^y)v_{yy}(t,y)-\frac{1}{2}\hat{\sigma }_n^2(e^y)v_{y}(t,y)&=0,& (t,y)\in[0,1)\times\mathbb{R},\\ \displaystyle v(1,y)&=h(e^y),& y\in\mathbb{R}. \end{array} $$

By [9, Theorem 6.3.6], \(\bar{C}^{n}\) is also the unique solution of the same PDE restricted to an arbitrary smooth bounded domain. Moreover, [9, Theorem 6.5.2] implies that \(\bar{C}^{n}\) has a unique probabilistic representation. We deduce that \(\widehat{C}^{n}\) is the unique solution of (3.7).  □

1.3 A.3 Classical properties of the Malliavin derivative

In this section, we simply recall classical properties of Malliavin calculus, which are widely used in the derivation of sensitivity estimates in this paper. For a more detailed presentation of the Malliavin calculus and its application in finance, see [10].

We first detail its relation with the first variation process. Let X be a one-dimensional Itô process with dynamics

$$\begin{aligned} d X_t =& b(X_t) \,dt+\sigma(X_t) \,dW_t, \end{aligned}$$

with differentiable drift and diffusion coefficients. Its first variation process ∇X solves the stochastic differential equation

$$\begin{aligned} d \nabla X_t =& b'(X_t)\,dt + \sigma'(X_t) \,dW_t, \quad\nabla X_0 = 1. \end{aligned}$$

Then the Malliavin derivative of X can be computed via the relation

$$\begin{aligned} D_s X_t =& \nabla X_t (\nabla X_s)^{-1}\sigma(X_s), \quad0\le s \le t \le T. \end{aligned}$$

Besides, if g is a \(C^{1}_{b}\) function, we have

$$\begin{aligned} D_s g(X_t) =& g'(X_t)\nabla X_t (\nabla X_s)^{-1}\sigma(X_s), \quad0\le s \le t \le T. \end{aligned}$$

We finally recall the integration-by-parts formula. For a given Malliavin-differentiable random variable ϕ and a stochastic process u, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}\int_0^\infty(D_t \phi) u_t \,dt =& \mathbb{E}\phi\int_0^\infty u_s \,dW_s, \end{aligned}$$

where the last stochastic integral is of Skorokhod type and coincides with the classical Itô integral whenever u is \(\mathbb{F}\)-adapted.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Elie, R., Lépinette, E. Approximate hedging for nonlinear transaction costs on the volume of traded assets. Finance Stoch 19, 541–581 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-015-0262-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-015-0262-2

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification (2010)

JEL Classification

Navigation