Skip to main content
Log in

Platform competition with common ownership

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the allocative effects of platform competition with common ownership in two-sided markets. We find that when both sides singlehome, common ownership increases the consumer surplus for the side treated as a loss leader, but decreases the consumer surplus for the other side. When one side multihomes, common ownership does not affect the consumer surplus for the multihoming side, but decreases the consumer surplus for the singlehoming side. When we introduce demand expansion into the model, captive users may still benefit from common ownership if they are treated as a loss leader. We show that common ownership does not necessarily hurt all platform users by extending the canonical Armstrong model of platform competition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, Bai and Matsumura (2023) find that common ownership makes firms locate away with each other on the Hotelling line, but cross-group effects are not their focus.

  2. The literature on platform competition often compares the cases of two-sided singlehoming and competitive bottlenecks. For example, Geng et al. (2023) explore how the number of active platforms is determined when users can only singlehome or can multihome on one side. Geng et al. (2023) do not take common ownership into account, while this paper studies how two platforms compete under common ownership.

  3. Common ownership is different from cross ownership. According to López and Vives (2019), cross ownership means a firm acquires rival firms’ shares.

  4. For example, we can interpret groups 1 and 2 as sellers and buyers, respectively (Belleflamme and Peitz 2019). In this paper, subscription fees and prices are used interchangeably.

  5. There is a point that should be noted. Since common ownership occurs when external investors acquire platforms’ shares, the degree of common ownership is considered as exogenous. In other words, \(\lambda\) should not be endogenized under common ownership.

  6. When \(\lambda = 0\), the two platforms aim to maximize their profits separately. When \(\lambda = 1\), the two platforms collapse to a monopoly platform.

  7. Here, we would like to express our gratitude to an anonymous reviewer for providing the intuitive interpretation of the condition.

  8. Rochet and Tirole (2003) provide many examples of cross-subsidization such as credit cards and the Internet.

References

  • Armstrong M (2006) Competition in two-sided markets. RAND J Econ 37(3):668–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong M, Wright J (2009) Mobile call termination. Econ J 119(538):F270–F307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar J, Schmalz MC, Tecu I (2018) Anticompetitive effects of common ownership. J Finance 73(4):1513–1565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai N, Matsumura T (2023) Common ownership in a delivered pricing duopoly. J Econ 139(3):191–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belleflamme P, Peitz M (2019) Platform competition: Who benefits from multihoming? Int J Ind Organ 64:1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brito D, Ribeiro R, Vasconcelos H (2020) Overlapping ownership, endogenous quality, and welfare. Econ Lett 190:109074

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Caillaud B, Jullien B (2003) Chicken & egg: Competition among intermediation service providers. RAND J Econ 34:309–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carbonnel A (2021) The two sides of platform collusion. Eur Compet J 17(3):745–760

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geng Y, Zhang Y, Li J (2023) Two-sided competition, platform services and online shopping market structure. J Econ 138(2):95–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefouili Y, Pinho J (2020) Collusion between two-sided platforms. Int J Ind Organ 72:102656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Y, Zhang J (2021) Product positioning with overlapping ownership. Econ Lett 208:110058

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • López AL, Vives X (2019) Overlapping ownership, R&D spillovers, and antitrust policy. J Polit Econ 127(5):2394–2437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nocke V, Peitz M, Stahl K (2007) Platform ownership. J Eur Econ Assoc 5(6):1130–1160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peitz M, Samkharadze L (2022) Collusion between non-differentiated two-sided platforms. Econ Lett 215:110506

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Raizonville A (2020) Platform coopetition in two-sided markets. Rev Econ Ind 172:19–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet J-C, Tirole J (2003) Platform competition in two-sided markets. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(4):990–1029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato S, Matsumura T (2020) Free entry under common ownership. Econ Lett 195:109489

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research is supported by Guangdong Planning Office of Philosophy and Social Science (GD22YLJ01) and Guangdong University of Foreign Studies (2022RC076).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pengqing Zhang.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors report no conflicts of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

In the model with demand expansion of Sect. 4, the following assumption is necessary to ensure that both platforms are active, and the markets for both sides are fully covered.

Assumption 3.

\(4t_{1} t_{2} \left( {2 - \frac{1}{{1 + \theta t_{1} }}} \right) > \left( {1 + \theta t_{1} } \right)\left( {\alpha_{1} + \alpha_{2} } \right)^{2} + 4\theta t_{1} \alpha_{1} \alpha_{2}\), \(r_{1} > f_{1} + \frac{{1 - \lambda + 4\theta t_{1} }}{{1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} }} \cdot \frac{{t_{1} - \alpha_{1} }}{2} + \frac{{t_{1} \left( {1 + \theta \alpha_{1} } \right) - \alpha_{2} \left( {1 + \theta t_{1} } \right)}}{{1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} }}\), and \(r_{2} > f_{2} + \frac{{t_{2} - \theta \alpha_{2}^{2} }}{2} + \frac{{t_{2} - \theta \alpha_{1} \alpha_{2} }}{1 - \lambda } - \frac{{\theta \alpha_{2} }}{{1 - \lambda + 4\theta t_{1} }}\left[ {\frac{{\left( {3 + \lambda } \right)\alpha_{1} }}{1 - \lambda } + \alpha_{2} } \right] - \left[ {1 + 2\theta \left( {r_{1} - f_{1} } \right) + \theta \left( {\alpha_{1} - \alpha_{2} } \right)} \right]\left[ {\frac{{\alpha_{1} + \theta t_{1} \left( {\alpha_{1} - \alpha_{2} } \right)}}{{1 - \lambda + 4\theta t_{1} }} + \frac{{\alpha_{2} }}{2}} \right]\).

We can find that if there is no demand expansion (i.e., \(\theta = 0\)), then Assumption 3 collapses to Assumption 1. The first condition is associated with active platforms, and it implies \(t_{1} t_{2} > \left( {1 + \theta t_{1} } \right)\alpha_{1} \alpha_{2}\). When the markets are fully covered, demand expansion is likely to downward adjust the minimum intrinsic benefit of joining a platform for group 2, since the cross-group external effect for group 2 will increase. However, the minimum intrinsic benefit for side 1 depends on platform differentiation \(t_{1}\). To see this, we define \(r_{1}^{*} \left( \theta \right) = f_{1} + \frac{{1 - \lambda + 4\theta t_{1} }}{{1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} }} \cdot \frac{{t_{1} - \alpha_{1} }}{2} + \frac{{t_{1} \left( {1 + \theta \alpha_{1} } \right) - \alpha_{2} \left( {1 + \theta t_{1} } \right)}}{{1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} }}\), which implies \(\frac{{\partial r_{1}^{*} \left( \theta \right)}}{\partial \theta } = \frac{{t_{1} \left( {1 + \lambda } \right)\left( {\alpha_{2} - t_{1} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} } \right)^{2} }}\). When platform differentiation is larger than the cross-group effect for group 2 (i.e., \(t_{1} > \alpha_{2}\)), demand expansion can reduce the minimum intrinsic benefit of joining a platform for side 1. Without hinterlands, according to Proposition 1, we know that \(t_{1} > \alpha_{2}\) implies platforms make profits from group 1. To attract potential users by demand expansion, platforms should decrease the price, and thus a lower requirement for group 1’s intrinsic benefit.

Appendix B

Lemma 1.

When the market is fully covered and demand expansion is possible, if the net surplus generated by group 1’s marginal user joining a platform is negative (i.e., \(r_{1} - f_{1} + \frac{{\alpha_{1} - t_{1} }}{2} < 0\)), platforms use the side of group 1 as a loss leader.

Proof.

Substituting \(r_{1} = f_{1} - \frac{{\alpha_{1} - t_{1} }}{2}\) into the second condition of Assumption 3, we have \(\frac{{\left( {1 + \theta t_{1} } \right)\left( {\alpha_{2} - t_{1} } \right)}}{{1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} }} > 0\). Let \(r_{1}^{*} = f_{1} - \frac{{\alpha_{1} - t_{1} }}{2}\), then the second condition of Assumption 3 can be written as \(r_{1} - r_{1}^{*} + \frac{{\left( {1 + \theta t_{1} } \right)\left( {\alpha_{2} - t_{1} } \right)}}{{1 - \lambda + 2\theta t_{1} }} > 0\). To ensure that the second condition of Assumption 3 is satisfied, if \(r_{1} < r_{1}^{*}\), then there must be \(\alpha_{2} > t_{1}\). In addition, when \(r_{1} < f_{1} - \frac{{\alpha_{1} - t_{1} }}{2}\), we have \(t_{1} > 2r_{1} - 2f_{1} + \alpha_{1}\), then \(\frac{{1 + \theta \left( {2r_{1} - 2f_{1} + \alpha_{1} } \right)}}{{1 + \theta t_{1} }} \cdot t_{1} < t_{1}\). Hence, if \(\alpha_{2} > t_{1}\), we have \(\alpha_{2} > t_{1} > \frac{{1 + \theta \left( {2r_{1} - 2f_{1} + \alpha_{1} } \right)}}{{1 + \theta t_{1} }} \cdot t_{1}\), which implies platforms take the side with captive users as a loss leader (see Proposition 5). ■

Appendix C

In the symmetric equilibrium, the consumer surplus of Hotelling users on side 1, the consumer surplus of Hotelling users on side 2, and the consumer surplus of captive users can be given by:

$$CS_{1}^{H} = 2\int_{0}^{1/2} {\left( {r_{1} + \alpha_{1} n_{2}^{H} - p_{1}^{H} - t_{1} x} \right)dx} ,$$
$$CS_{2}^{H} = 2\int_{0}^{1/2} {\left( {r_{2} + \alpha_{2} n_{1}^{H} - p_{2}^{H} - t_{2} x} \right)dx} ,$$
$$CS_{c}^{H} = 2\int_{0}^{{\theta \left( {{{\alpha_{1} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\alpha_{1} } 2}} \right. \kern-0pt} 2} + r_{1} - p_{1}^{H} } \right)}} {\left( {r_{1} + \alpha_{1} n_{2}^{H} - p_{1}^{H} - \frac{x}{\theta }} \right)dx} .$$

The profits of two platforms can be described by:

$$\Pi^{H} = 2\left( {p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} } \right)n_{1}^{H} + 2\left( {p_{2}^{H} - f_{2} } \right)n_{2}^{H} .$$

Social welfare can be expressed as the sum of the consumer surplus of Hotelling users on side 1, the consumer surplus of Hotelling users on side 2, the consumer surplus of captive users, and the profits of two platforms:

$$W = CS_{1}^{H} + CS_{2}^{H} + CS_{c}^{H} + \Pi^{H} .$$

The first-order derivative of social welfare with respect to the degree of common ownership can be calculated by:

$$\frac{dW}{{d\lambda }} = \frac{{dCS_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } + \frac{{dCS_{2}^{H} }}{d\lambda } + \frac{{dCS_{c}^{H} }}{d\lambda } + \frac{{d\Pi^{H} }}{d\lambda }.$$

According to Eqs. (22) and (23), we have \(\frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = - \theta \frac{{dp_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda }\) and \(\frac{{dn_{2}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = 0\). Using \(\frac{{dn_{2}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = 0\) and combining Eqs. (22) and (23), we obtain:

$$\frac{{dCS_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = - \frac{{dp_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda },$$
$$\frac{{dCS_{2}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = \alpha_{2} \frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } - \frac{{dp_{2}^{H} }}{d\lambda },$$
$$\frac{{dCS_{c}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = - 2\theta \left( {\frac{{\alpha_{1} }}{2} + r_{1} - p_{1}^{H} } \right)\frac{{dp_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda },$$
$$\frac{{d\Pi^{H} }}{d\lambda } = \left[ {1 + 2\theta \left( {\frac{{\alpha_{1} }}{2} + r_{1} - p_{1}^{H} } \right)} \right]\frac{{dp_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } + \frac{{dp_{2}^{H} }}{d\lambda } + 2\left( {p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} } \right)\frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda }.$$

The above equations imply:

$$\frac{dW}{{d\lambda }} = \alpha_{2} \frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } + 2\left( {p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} } \right)\frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = - \frac{\theta }{{1 - \lambda + 4\theta t_{1} }}\left( {p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} } \right)\left[ {2\left( {p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} } \right) + \alpha_{2} } \right],$$

where we have applied the relations \(\frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = - \theta \frac{{dp_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda }\) and \(\frac{{dp_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda } = \frac{{p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} }}{{1 - \lambda + 4\theta t_{1} }}\).

The calculation suggests that the net effect of common ownership on social welfare depends on \(\alpha_{2} \frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda }\) and \(2\left( {p_{1}^{H} - f_{1} } \right)\frac{{dn_{1}^{H} }}{d\lambda }\), which represent the cross-group effect of additional captive users on the other side, and the profits of platforms made from additional captive users, respectively.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pi, J., Zhang, P. Platform competition with common ownership. J Econ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00864-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-024-00864-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation