Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of consumer’s regret on firms’ decisions in a durable good market

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies how the consumer’s anticipated regret affects the firms’ pricing decisions and profits in a duopoly market. I consider a two-period game with differentiated durable products, where an incumbent sells a basic version over two periods, and an entrant releases an improved version in period 2, of which the improved features are difficult to assess by the consumers. This ambiguity will lead to regret. This paper focuses on two types of regret: a consumer may regret purchasing in period 1 instead of purchasing in period 2 (action regret); a consumer who waited until period 2 might regret not buying in period 1 (inaction regret). The consumers can anticipate the possible regret, which will influence the consumer’s decision-making. The results show that both types of anticipated regret may increase or decrease the incumbent’s profit. In contrast, action (inaction) regret always benefits (harms) the entrant. Besides, the analysis indicates that the improved version’s quality may either strengthen or weaken the impact of regret. Moreover, this paper examines the robustness of the results under different setups.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for instance, Landman (1987), Landman (1993), and Gilovich and Medvec (1995).

  2. The effect of regret on the individual’s behavior is studied and documented by many papers in economics, for instance, Loomes and Sugden (1982), Van de Ven and Zeelenberg (2011), and Giorgetta et al. (2013). Because the original regret theory in Loomes and Sugden (1982) is limited to pairwise choices, Quiggin (1994) extends it to a more general form by assuming that the optimal alternative can be chosen from the alternative set. Moreover, Bakó and Neszveda (2020) introduce the regret-minimizing individuals into the salience theory to overcome the possible issue where the salient thinker may prefer a dominated option in the salience theory.

  3. For instance, in 2016, the Chinese electric vehicle startup Nio claimed to produce a vehicle called ES8, but it was only launched since 2018.

  4. See, Pegoraro et al. (2010), for the study of regret advertisements in the sport industry. The authors show that regret advertisements can influence consumer needs and consumption culture.

  5. Loomes and Sugden (1982) provide the basis for the regret theory as an alternative to the prospect theory by Kahneman and Tversky (1979), which allows explaining some choices under uncertainty that are inconsistent with the traditional utility theory. Loomes and Sugden (1982) and Bell (1982) suggest that some phenomena, which violate the conventional theory, can be explained by anticipated regret or anticipated rejoicing. Gilovich and Medvec (1995) review the evidence of action and inaction regret in psychology.

  6. See, Cavaliere and Crea (2022), for the study of the competition in a duopoly, where the consumers may have information disparity, and the consumers with uninformed information may overestimate the quality of a superior product. The authors use the vertical differentiation model and show that the firms’ decisions and profits in equilibria depend on the share of uninformed consumers and the difference between the estimated level of quality for the superior version and that for the low-quality version from a worse firm. Because we study different issues in behavioral industrial organization, in my paper, to simplify the discussion, I consider all consumers are uninformed about the improved version and exogenize the quality. Moreover, I use a disutility term in the utility function to capture the consumer’s negative feeling of regret.

  7. Including a discount factor will only change the restrictions on the existence of equilibrium and will not affect the main results about regret.

  8. In Section 5, I will briefly discuss how the second-hand market affects the consumer’s purchase behavior and the firm’s profit.

  9. Assuming \(q_{E}\le v\) also allows me to reduce the equilibrium candidates and concentrate on the interesting results with regret. Otherwise, there may exist an extreme case where all consumers may postpone consumption, and there is no action regret.

  10. This timing is usually the one in the real world. Nevertheless, for completeness, I will make a detailed discussion about the timing in Sect. 5.4. I show that the timing may not influence the main results in this paper.

  11. Suppose that \({\hat{\theta }}< {\tilde{\theta }}\), which implies that \(v-p_{I1}+(1-\phi )p_{E2}+\phi p_{I2}<0\). Since \(p_{E2}\ge p_{I2}\), we have \(0>v-p_{I1}+(1-\phi )p_{E2}+\phi p_{I2}>v-p_{I1}+(1-\phi )p_{I2}+\phi p_{I2}=v-p_{I1}+p_{I2}\). Inequality \(v-p_{I1}+p_{I2}<0\) implies that \(u_{I1}(p_{I1})=2v-p_{I1}<u_{I2}(p_{I2})=v-p_{I2}\), which means that it is better for consumers to wait for the incumbent’s version at \(t=2\) rather than buying it at \(t=1\). All consumers postpone purchasing, and this is not the case under Assumption 1. Such pricing is not optimal for the incumbent, and it is not the case in equilibrium. Thus, \({\hat{\theta }}\ge {\tilde{\theta }}\).

  12. Note that some consumers who buy the incumbent’s good I at \(t=1\) and ex-post enjoy the new features never experience action regret. Those are the consumers with \(\theta \le \frac{v+p_{E2}-p_{I1}}{q_{E}}\). Because even though they fully know the new attributes’ valuation and like the new features, buying the incumbent’s good I at \(t=1\) provides a higher utility. This will not influence the results because, in equilibrium, they all buy the incumbent’s product at \(t=1\).

  13. I disregard the consumers who have a positive but very low value for the entrant’s features because their better choice is to buy the incumbent’s product in period 1. They leave the market and will not experience inaction regret.

  14. Consumers may anticipate both types of regret. I will discuss this possibility in Sect. 5. However, we can expect that the influence of each type of regret on the consumer’s behavior and the firm’s profits will be the same, and the conclusion will be the combined effects of the two types of regret in the two extreme cases.

  15. For instance, Pegoraro et al. (2010) study the advertisements in the sport industry. The authors show that the advertisements using the consumer’s option maximization, which is the most frequently used, and those using regret tactics are strongly related. Besides, the authors discuss that these advertisements can influence the consumption culture and consumer needs, for instance, by reminding about the consumer’s regret.

  16. A classic advertisement about regret is from Intel: “You can’t rewind regret.” More advertisements reminding the consumers about regret are, for instance, Bargain Regret ’Blender’ from AAMI Insurance; Hippo v.s. Regret Monster. These advertisements warn the consumers about the ex-post action regret and make the consumers more likely to buy the firm’s superior products and services, which yields a higher profit.

  17. More examples like Apple and Google offer upgrades of their iSO and Android operation systems for a better experience of the smartphones, which are also available for the smartphones of the older generation.

  18. I assume that the upgrade from the incumbent is not better than the new features of product E. Otherwise, all consumers will buy the incumbent’s product I at \(t=1\), and there is no anticipated regret.

  19. The expressions of the prices, demand, and profits at equilibrium are in the Appendix.

  20. For the sake of presenting the main results, I only show the sign of the first derivatives. All the equilibrium prices, demands, profits, and the first derivatives are solved formally.

  21. This means that, in all timings, the entrant’s best response of \(p_{E2}\) only depends on the incumbent’s price \(p_{I1}\).

  22. The expected utility function when the consumers anticipate inaction regret is \(Eu_{E2}^{i}(p_{I1},p_{I2},p_{E2})=v+\phi \theta q_{E}-p_{E2}-r_{i}(1-\phi )\max \{(v-p_{I1}+\min \{p_{I2},p_{E2}\}),0\}\). The function depends on the level of \(p_{I2}\) and \(p_{E2}\), thus, the demand may be also determined by \(p_{I2}\).

  23. It is not a competitor at \(t=1\) because the incumbent can always set the prices such that the consumers are better off buying its product at \(t=1\) than buying its good or a used one at \(t=2\), i.e., \(u_{I1}(p_{I1})>u_{I2}(p_{I2})\) as that in the initial game.

  24. The following example illustrates the firm’s and the consumer’s behavior. The GPU producer NVIDIA just released its GeForce 40 series GPU succeeding the 30 series and competing with the other producer AMD. Clearly, NVIDIA did not provide any information about its future 50 series GPUs. Moreover, there is minimal discussion or prediction about the future 50 series GPU on the internet because the 50 series will be released at least two years after, and consumers want to buy GPUs recently. Consumers are choosing between the old version GPUs from NVIDIA or AMD and waiting for the new GeForce 40 series.

References

  • Bakó B, Neszveda G (2020) The achilles’ heel of salience theory and a way to fix it. Econ Lett 193:109265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bell DE (1982) Regret in decision making under uncertainty. Oper Res 30(5):961–981

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Board S (2008) Durable-goods monopoly with varying demand. Rev Econ Stud 75(2):391–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavaliere A, Crea G (2022) Brand premia driven by perceived vertical differentiation in markets with information disparity and optimistic consumers. J Econ 135(3):223–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feiler D, Müller-Trede J (2022) The one that got away: Overestimation of forgone alternatives as a hidden source of regret. Psychol Sci 33(2):314–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilovich T, Medvec VH (1995) The experience of regret: what, when, and why. Psychol Rev 102(2):379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giorgetta C, Grecucci A, Bonini N, Coricelli G, Demarchi G, Braun C, Sanfey AG (2013) Waves of regret: A meg study of emotion and decision-making. Neuropsychologia 51(1):38–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe HC, Lee IH (2003) Entry deterrence and innovation in durable-goods monopoly. Eur Econ Rev 47(6):1011–1036

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman JJ, Zeelenberg M (2002) Regret in repeat purchase versus switching decisions: the attenuating role of decision justifiability. J Consum Res 29(1):116–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang B, Narasimhan C, Turut Ö (2016) Anticipated regret and product innovation. Manage Sci 63(12):4308–4323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2):263–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landman J (1987) Regret and elation following action and inaction: affective responses to positive versus negative outcomes. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 13(4):524–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landman J (1993). Regret: The persistence of the possible. Oxford University Press

  • Loomes G, Sugden R (1982) Regret theory: an alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Econ J 92(368):805–824

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nasiry J, Popescu I (2012) Advance selling when consumers regret. Manage Sci 58(6):1160–1177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pegoraro AL, Ayer SM, O’Reilly NJ (2010) Consumer consumption and advertising through sport. Am Behav Sci 53(10):1454–1475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quiggin J (1994) Regret theory with general choice sets. J Risk Uncertain 8(2):153–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shih E, Schau HJ (2011) To justify or not to justify: the role of anticipated regret on consumers’ decisions to upgrade technological innovations. J Retail 87(2):242–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonson I (1992) The influence of anticipating regret and responsibility on purchase decisions. J Consum Res 19(1):105–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Syam N, Krishnamurthy P, Hess JD (2008) That’s what i thought i wanted? miswanting and regret for a standard good in a mass-customized world. Mark Sci 27(3):379–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van de Ven N, Zeelenberg M (2011) Regret aversion and the reluctance to exchange lottery tickets. J Econ Psychol 32(1):194–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeelenberg M (1999) Anticipated regret, expected feedback and behavioral decision making. J Behav Decis Mak 12(2):93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeelenberg M, Beattie J, Van der Pligt J, De Vries NK (1996) Consequences of regret aversion: Effects of expected feedback on risky decision making. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 65(2):148–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Qianshuo Liu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I thank Ramon Caminal, Giacomo Corneo, Paula González, Dennis Hutschenreiter, Inés Macho-Stadler, Pau Olivella, David Pérez-Castrillo, Joel Sandonís, Chaoran Sun, two reviewers, and participants at UAB MicroLab seminars, JEI 2019 and SAEe 2021 conferences for their comments. I gratefully acknowledge the grant (PRE2018-084457) from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation and the financial support (PGC2018-094348-B-I00) from the Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness and Feder.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

I first prove the following Claim. \(\square \)

Claim 1

Under Assumption 1, in equilibrium:

The prices are \(p_{I1}^{\star }=\frac{\phi [(2-\phi ){q_{E}}+v]}{1+\phi },\text { } p_{E2}^{\star }= p_{I2}^{\star }=\frac{3\phi {q_{E}}-v}{2(1+\phi )}\).

The demand for the incumbent’s version I at \(t=1\) is \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star }=\frac{v+(2\phi -1)\phi {q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}}.\)

The expected profits are \(\Pi _{I}^{\star }=\frac{v^2+2(2\phi -1)\phi v {q_{E}}+(5-4\phi )\phi ^2{q_{E}}^2}{4(1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}},\text { }\Pi _{E}^{\star }=\frac{(3\phi {q_{E}}-v)^2}{4(1+\phi )^2{q_{E}}}.\)

Proof of Claim 1

Under Assumption 1, at the last stage of the game, the optimal price \(p_{I2}\), as a function of \(p_{E2}\), is the one that maximizes the incumbent’s profit at \(t=2\). The optimal response is \(p^{\star }_{I2}(p_{E2})=p_{E2}\) if \(p_{E2}\le v\), and \(p^{\star }_{I2}(p_{E2})=v\) if \(p_{E2}>v\). Now I move backward and consider the entrant’s decision about the optimal price \(p_{E2}\) given the price \(p_{I1}\) set by the incumbent before, and then I analyze the best response of the incumbent at the first stage of the game \(p_{I1}\). I consider two scenarios: \(p_{E2}\le v\); and \(p_{E2}>v\), and I show that the equilibrium is of the former form.

  1. (1)

    Equilibrium candidate \(p_{E2}\le v\)

    If \(p_{E2}\le v\), consumers in the market are the ones with \(\theta >{\hat{\theta }}=\frac{v-p_{I1}+p_{E2}}{\phi {q_{E}}}\). The demand for the improved version E is \(\phi (1-{\hat{\theta }})\). The entrant’s profit maximization problem is:

    $$\begin{aligned} \max _{p_{E2}}\Pi _{E}=\max _{p_{E2}} \phi \int _{\frac{v-p_{I1}+p_{E2}}{\phi {q_{E}}}}^{1}p_{E2} d\theta . \end{aligned}$$

    From the first order condition (FOC), I have \(p_{E2}^{\star }(p_{I1})=\frac{\phi {q_{E}}+p_{I1}-v}{2}\). Substituting \(p_{E2}^{\star }\) into \({\hat{\theta }}\), I obtain \({\hat{\theta }}(p_{I1})=\frac{v-p_{I1}+\phi q_{E}}{2\phi {q_{E}}}\), the demand of the incumbent’s good at \(t=1\) as a function of \(p_{I1}\). The demand of its good at \(t=2\) is \((1-\phi )(1-{\hat{\theta }}(p_{I1}))\). Then the incumbent’s profit maximization problem at the first stage of the game is:

    $$\begin{aligned} \max _{p_{I1}}\Pi _{I}=\max _{p_{I1}} \int _{0}^{\frac{v-p_{I1}+\phi q_{E}}{2\phi {q_{E}}}}p_{I1} d\theta +(1-\phi )\int _{\frac{v-p_{I1}+\phi q_{E}}{2\phi {q_{E}}}}^{1} \frac{\phi {q_{E}}+p_{I1}-v}{2} d\theta. \end{aligned}$$

    From the FOC, as a function of \(q_{E}\) and \(\phi\), I have \(p_{I1}^{\star }=\frac{\phi [(2-\phi ){q_{E}}+v]}{1+\phi }\), which in turn implies that the equilibrium candidate is \(p_{I1}^{\star }=\frac{\phi [(2-\phi ){q_{E}}+v]}{1+\phi }\), \(p_{I2}^{\star }=p_{E2}^{\star }=\frac{3\phi {q_{E}}-v}{2(1+\phi )}\), \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star }=\frac{v+(2\phi -1)\phi {q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}}\), \(\Pi _{I}^{\star }=\frac{v^2+2(2\phi -1)\phi v {q_{E}}+(5-4\phi )\phi ^2{q_{E}}^2}{4(1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}}\), \(\Pi _{E}^{\star }=\frac{(3\phi {q_{E}}-v)^2}{4(1+\phi )^2{q_{E}}}\). Under Assumption 1, the conditions such that this equilibrium candidate exists are satisfied:

    1. (a)

      The demand for the incumbent’s good at \(t=1\) is positive, \(2v-p_{I1}\ge 0\);

    2. (b)

      Some consumers wait for the second period, and that population is not greater than 1, \(0\le {\hat{\theta }}\le 1\);

    3. (c)

      The entrant can earn a positive profit, \(p_{E2}\ge 0\);

    4. (d)

      The restriction for this scenario, \(v-p_{E2}\ge 0\).

  2. (2)

    Equilibrium candidate when \(p_{E2}>v\) Consider \(p_{E2}>v\), which implies \(p_{I2}=v\). Following the steps as that in the previous case, as functions of \(q_{E}\) and \(\phi\), I obtain the prices, and the demand, \(p^{\star \star }_{I1}=\frac{(2-\phi )v+\phi {q_{E}}}{2}\), \(p^{\star \star }_{E2}=\frac{3\phi {q_{E}}-\phi v}{4}\), \(p^{\star \star }_{I2}=v\), \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star \star }=\frac{v+{q_{E}}}{4{q_{E}}}\). The conditions for this equilibrium candidate to exist are:

    1. (a)

      \(2v-p_{I1}\ge 0\);

    2. (b)

      \(0\le {\hat{\theta }}\le 1\);

    3. (c)

      \(p_{E2}\ge 0\);

    4. (d)

      \(v-p_{E2}\le 0\)

    Condition (d) is violated, thus, this equilibrium candidate does not exist. The equilibrium prices, profits, and demand are those in Case (1). \(\square\)

With Claim 1, we can easily prove Proposition 1: for a given \(q_{E}\), \(\frac{\partial p_{I1}^{\star }}{\partial \phi }, \frac{\partial p_{I2}^{\star }}{\partial \phi }, \frac{\partial p_{E2}^{\star }}{\partial \phi }>0\), \(\frac{\partial {\hat{\theta }}^{\star }}{\partial \phi }<0\), \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial \phi }<0\), and \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial \phi }>0\). In addition, for a given \(\phi\), \(\frac{\partial p_{I1}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}, \frac{\partial p_{I2}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}, \frac{\partial p_{E2}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {\hat{\theta }}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}<0\), and \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}>0\). Besides, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}<0\) if \(q_{E}<\frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}\), and \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial q_{E}}\ge 0\) if \(q_{E}\ge \frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}\). \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 1

I first prove the following Claim.

Claim 2

Under Assumption 1, in equilibrium:

The prices are \(p_{I1}^{\star }=\frac{(2-\phi )\phi (1+r_{a}){q_{E}}+\phi (1+r_{a}\phi )v}{(1+\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )},\) \(p_{I2}^\star =p_{E2}^{\star }=\frac{3(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}-(1+r_{a}\phi )v}{2(1+\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )}.\)

The demand for the incumbent’s product I at \(t=1\) is \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star }=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )v+(2\phi -1)(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}}\).

The profits are \(\Pi _{I}^{\star }=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )^2v^2+(5-4 \phi )(1+r_{a})^2 \phi ^2{q_{E}}^2+2(2 \phi -1)(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a} \phi ) \phi q_{E} v}{4(1+ \phi )(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a} \phi ) \phi q_{E} }\), \(\Pi _{E}^{\star }=\frac{[3(1+r_{a}) \phi q_{E}-(1+r_{a} \phi )v]^2}{4(1+ \phi )^2(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a} \phi ){q_{E}}}.\)

Proof of Claim 2

To prove this Claim, following the same steps as that in the proof of Proposition 1, I consider two possible cases: \(p^{\star }_{I2}(p_{E2})=p_{E2}\) if \(p_{E2}\le v\), and \(p_{I2}^{\star }(p_{E2})=v\) if \(p_{E2}>v\). Then I check the existence of each case.

  1. (1)

    Equilibrium candidate \(p_{E2}\le v\)

    By backward induction and the entrant’s and the incumbent’s profit maximization problems, I obtain the prices, the demand of version I at \(t=1\), and profits for this equilibrium candidate.

    $$\begin{aligned} p_{I1}^{\star }&=\frac{(2-\phi )\phi (1+r_{a}){q_{E}}+\phi (1+r_{a}\phi )v}{(1+\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )},\\ \quad p_{I2}^{\star }=p_{E2}^{\star }&=\frac{3(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}-(1+r_{a}\phi )v}{2(1+\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )},\\ \quad {\hat{\theta }}&=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )v+(2\phi -1)(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}}. \end{aligned}$$

    The profits are easy to obtain. Most importantly, under Assumption 1, the conditions such that this equilibrium candidate exists are satisfied: (a) \(u_{E2}=v+\phi {\hat{\theta }}{q_{E}}-p_{E2}\ge 0\), which is equivalent to \(u_{I1}(p_{I1})\ge 0\); (b) \(0\le {\hat{\theta }}\le 1\); (c) \(p_{E2}\ge 0\); (d) \(v-p_{E2}\ge 0\).

  2. (2)

    Equilibrium candidate \(p_{E2}>v\)

    Consider the case \(p_{E2}>v\), which implies \(p_{I2}=v\). Following the same steps, I obtain the prices and the demand \(p_{I1}^{\star \star }=\frac{(2-\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )v+\phi (1+r_{a}) {q_{E}}}{2(1+r_{a}\phi )}\), \(p_{E2}^{\star \star }=\frac{3(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}-\phi (1+r_{a}\phi ) v}{4(1+r_{a}\phi )}\), \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star \star }=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )v+(1+r_{a}){q_{E}}}{4(1+r_{a}){q_{E}}}\). I need to check the existence of this equilibrium candidate, the prices and demand have to satisfy the following conditions: (a) \(v+\phi {\hat{\theta }}{q_{E}}-p_{E2}\ge 0\); (b) \(0\le {\hat{\theta }}\le 1\); (c) \(p_{E2}\ge 0\); (d) \(p_{E2}>v\). Condition (d) is not satisfied since \(p_{E2}>v\rightarrow q_{E}>\frac{(4+\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )}{3(1+r_{a})\phi }v>v\), which contradicts with Assumption 1. Therefore, Case (1) is the equilibrium in this scenario.◻

This Claim allows me to analyze the equilibrium prices and the demand of version I at \(t=1\), stated in Lemma 1. We can obtain that \(\frac{\partial p^{\star }_{I1}}{\partial r_{a}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial p^{\star }_{I2}}{\partial r_{a}}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial p^{\star }_{E2}}{\partial r_{a}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {\hat{\theta }}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}<0\). \(\square \vspace{0.2cm}\)

Remark 1

The incumbent’s profit at \(t=1\) always decreases in \(r_{a}\) and that at \(t=2\) increases in \(r_{a}\).

Proof of Remark 1

\(\Pi _{I2}\) increases in \(r_{a}\) since more consumers wait for \(t=2\) and \(p_{I2}\) is higher. I can obtain \(\Pi _{I1}\) and first order with respect to \(r_{a}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ^{\star }_{I1}&=\frac{(2-\phi )(2\phi -1)\phi (1+r_{a})^2q_{E}^2+(1+r_{a}\phi ) ^2v^2+2(\phi ^2-\phi +1)(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )q_{E}v}{2(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )q_{E}}, \\ \quad \frac{\partial \Pi _{I1}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}&=\frac{(1-\phi )[(2-\phi )(2\phi -1)\phi (1+r_{a})^2q_{E}^2-(1+r_{a}\phi )^2v^2]}{2(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})^2(1+r_{a}\phi )^2q_{E}}<0, \end{aligned}$$

one can easily check that it is always negative under Assumption 1. Thus, \(\Pi _{I1}^{\star }\) decreases in \(r_{a}\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

From the first order of the incumbent’s profit with respect to \(r_{a}\) I have:

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}=\frac{(1-\phi )[(5-4\phi )(1+r_{a})^2\phi ^2{q_{E}}^2-(1+\phi r_{a})^2v^2]}{4(1+\phi )\phi (1+r_{a})^2(1+r_{a}\phi )^2{q_{E}}}\gtrless 0\Rightarrow \\ & \quad \underbrace{[q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v]}_{\gtrless 0 }\phi r_{a}\gtrless \underbrace{v-\phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }}_{\gtrless 0 }. \end{aligned}$$
  1. (1)

    If \([q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v]\le 0\), which implies that \(v-\phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }>0\), thus, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{a}}<0\). This case requires \(q_{E}\le \frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}\). Using Assumption 1: \(\phi \ge \frac{13}{20}\) and \(q_{E}\ge \frac{v}{3\phi }\). Therefore, I need \(\frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}\ge \frac{v}{3\phi }\Rightarrow \phi \ge \frac{5}{9}\), which is satisfied. For case (1), I have \(q_{E}\in [\frac{v}{3\phi },\frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}]\).

  2. (2)

    If \([q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v]\ge 0\) and \(v-\phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }\le 0 \Rightarrow q_{E}\ge \frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }}\), which implies \(\frac{\partial \Pi ^{\star }_{I}}{\partial r_{a}}\ge 0\). Notice that \(q_{E}\le v\), thus, case (2) requires \(\frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }}\le v\Rightarrow \phi \ge \frac{\sqrt{17}+1}{8}\), which is satisfied under Assumption 1. The condition guaranteeing the existence of case (2) is: \(q_{E}\in [\frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }},v]\).

  3. (3)

    If \([q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v]\ge 0\) and \(v-\phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }\ge 0 \Rightarrow \frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}\le q_{E}\le \frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }}\). If \(r_{a}\ge \frac{v-\phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }}{\phi (q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v)}\), \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{a}}\ge 0\), otherwise \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{a}}<0\). Combined with Assumption 1, the conditions such that case (3) exists are: \(\frac{13}{20}\le \phi \le 1\) and \(\max \{\frac{v}{3\phi },\frac{v}{\sqrt{5-4\phi }}\}\le q_{E} \le \min \{v,\frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }}\}\).

As for the entrant, the first order derivative of its profit with respect to \(r_{a}\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}=\frac{(1-\phi )[3(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}+(1+r_{a}\phi )v]*[3(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}-(1+r_{a}\phi )v]}{4(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})^2(1+r_{a}\phi )^2 {q_{E}}}. \end{aligned}$$

Under Assumption 1, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}\) is always positive. In addition, we can check that \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}\partial q_{E}}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}\partial q_{E}}>0\), which means that when action regret increases both firms’ profits, the positive influence is greater if \(q_{E}\) is higher. But when action regret reduces the incumbent’s overall profit, this negative effect is mitigated when \(q_{E}\) is larger. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 2

I first prove the following Claim.

Claim 3

Under Assumption 1 and 2, in equilibrium:

The prices are \(p_{I1}^{\star }=\frac{\phi (2-\phi ){q_{E}}+\phi [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}] v}{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )}, p_{I2}^{\star }=p_{E2}^{\star }=\frac{3\phi {q_{E}}-[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v}{2[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )}\).

The demand for product I at \(t=1\) is \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star }=\frac{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v+(2\phi -1)\phi {q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}}\).

The profits are: \(\Pi _{I}^{\star }=\frac{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2v^2+2(2\phi -1)[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]\phi v {q_{E}}+(5-4\phi )\phi ^2{q_{E}}^2}{4[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}}\), \(\Pi _{E}^{\star }=\frac{[3\phi {q_{E}}-(1+(1-\phi )r_{i})v]^2}{4(1+\phi )^2[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]{q_{E}}}\).

Proof of Claim 3

Under Assumption 1 and 2, as I did in the proofs of Proposition 1, I identify the equilibrium prices and demand from two candidates:

  1. (1)

    Equilibrium candidate \(p_{E2}<v\)

    I follow the same steps in L 1.1, by backward induction, I obtain the prices, demand for the incumbent’s version I in the first period, and profits: \(p_{I1}^{\star }=\frac{\phi (2-\phi ){q_{E}}+\phi [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}] v}{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )}\), \(p_{I2}^{\star }=p_{E2}^{\star }=\frac{3\phi {q_{E}}-[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v}{2[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )}\), \({\hat{\theta }}^{\star }=\frac{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v+(2\phi -1)\phi {q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )\phi {q_{E}}}\).

    The profits are easy to obtain from the demand and prices. This equilibrium candidate satisfies the following conditions for the existence under Assumption 1 and 2: a) \(2v-p_{I1}\ge 0\); b) \(0\le {\hat{\theta }}\le 1\); c) \(p_{E2}\ge 0\); d) \(v-p_{E2}\ge 0\).

  2. (2)

    Equilibrium candidate when \(p_{E2}>v\)

    I solve the prices and demand: \(p_{I1}=\frac{(2-\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )v+\phi (1+r_{a}) {q_{E}}}{2(1+r_{a}\phi )}\), \(p_{E2}=\frac{3(1+r_{a})\phi {q_{E}}-\phi (1+r_{a}\phi ) v}{4(1+r_{a}\phi )}\), \({\hat{\theta }}=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )v+(1+r_{a}){q_{E}}}{4(1+r_{a}){q_{E}}}\). This equilibrium candidate never exists since it will violate the assumption \(q_{E}\le v\).

    Therefore, the equilibrium prices and demand are the ones in Case (1). \(\square\)

Claim 3 allows me to analyze the characteristics of the prices and demand in equilibrium, which are stated in Lemma 2. \(\square\)

Remark 2

The incumbent’s profit at \(t=1\) increases in \(r_{i}\) and that at \(t=2\) decreases in \(r_{i}\).

Proof of Remark 2

\(\Pi _{I2}^{\star }\) decreases in \(r_{i}\) since fewer consumers wait for \(t=2\) and the price \(p_{I2}\) is lower. The incumbent’s profit at \(t=1\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{I1}^{\star }&=\frac{\phi [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2v^2+\phi ^2(2\phi -1)(2-\phi )q_{E}^2+2\phi [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](\phi ^2-\phi +1)q_{E}v}{2(1+\phi )^2\phi q_{E}[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]}, \\ \quad \frac{\partial \Pi _{I1}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}&=\frac{(1-\phi )\{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2v^2-\phi (2\phi -1)(2-\phi ) q_{E}^2\}}{2(1+\phi )^2\phi [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2q_{E}}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Obviously, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I1}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}\) is always positive under Assumption 1. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 3

The first order derivative of the incumbent’s profit with respect to \(r_{i}\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}=\frac{(1-\phi )\overbrace{\{ [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v-\sqrt{5-4\phi }\phi {q_{E}}\}}^{\gtrless 0}\overbrace{\{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v+\sqrt{5-4\phi }\phi {q_{E}}\}}^{>0}}{4\phi (1+\phi )[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2 {q_{E}}}. \end{aligned}$$

The sign of first order derivative depends on \([1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v-\sqrt{5-4\phi }\phi {q_{E}}\). This term is non-negative if

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\phi )r_{i}v\ge \phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v \end{aligned}$$
  1. (1)

    If \(q_{E}\le \frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }}\), this inequality always holds. Thus, given Assumption 2, when \(\frac{v}{3\phi }\le q_{E}\le \min \{\frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }},v\}\), \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{i}}\ge 0\).

  2. (2)

    When the right-hand side of the inequality is positive, that is \(\frac{v}{\phi \sqrt{5-4\phi }}< q_{E} \le v\), which requires that \(\phi \ge \frac{\sqrt{17}+1}{8}\), which is satisfied under Assumption 1. Under this circumstance, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{i}}< 0\) if \(r_{i}<\frac{\phi q_{E}\sqrt{5-4\phi }-v}{(1-\phi )v}={\hat{r}}_{i}\); \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{i}}\ge 0\) if \(r_{i}\ge {\hat{r}}_{i}\). Note that \({\hat{r}}_{i}<\frac{3\phi q_{E}-v}{(1-\phi )v}\), thus, threshold \({\hat{r}}_{i}\) exists under Assumption 2.

The first order derivative of the entrant’s profit w.r.t. \(r_{i}\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}=\frac{(1-\phi )\overbrace{\{ 3\phi q_{E}-[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v\}}^{\ge 0} \overbrace{\{-3\phi q_{E}-[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}v] \}}^{<0}}{4(1+\phi )^2[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2q_{E}}\le 0. \end{aligned}$$

In addition, \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}\partial q_{E}}<0\) and \(\frac{\partial ^2 \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}\partial q_{E}}<0\). A higher \(q_{E}\) weakens the positive effect of inaction regret on the incumbent’s profit but strengthens the negative impact on both firms’ profits. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4

The utility functions are as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Eu_{I1}(p_{I1},p_{E2})&=2v-p_{I1}-\phi r_{a}(\theta {q_{E}}-p_{E2}-v+p_{I1}), \\ \quad u_{I2}(p_{I2})&=v-p_{I2}, \\ \quad Eu_{E2}(p_{I1},p_{E2})&=v+\phi \theta {q_{E}}-p_{E2}-(1-\phi )r_{i}(v-p_{I1}+p_{E2}). \end{aligned}$$

By backward induction, I obtain the equilibrium prices, demand, and profits:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{I1}^{\star }&=\frac{\phi (1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})v+(2-\phi )\phi (1+r_{a})q_{E}}{(1+\phi )(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})},\\ \quad p_{I2}^{\star }=p_{E2}^{\star }&=\frac{3\phi (1+r_{a})q_{E}-(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})v}{2(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})(1+\phi )},\\ \quad {\hat{\theta }}^{\star }&=\frac{(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})v+(2\phi -1)\phi (1+r_{a})q_{E}}{2\phi (1+\phi )(1+r_{a})q_{E}},\\ \quad \Pi _{I}^{\star }&=\frac{(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2v^2+2(2\phi -1)\phi (1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})(1+r_{a})q_{E}v+(5-4\phi )\phi ^2(1+r_{a})^2{q_{E}}^2}{4(1+\phi )\phi (1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})(1+r_{a})q_{E}},\\ \quad \Pi _{E}^{\star }&=\frac{[3(1+r_{a})\phi q_{E}-(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})v]^2}{4(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})q_{E}}. \end{aligned}$$

The first order derivatives of profits w.r.t. regret are:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}&=\frac{[(5-4\phi )\phi ^2(1+r_{a})^2{q_{E}}^2-(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2v^2]}{4(1+\phi )\phi (1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2(1+r_{a})^2q_{E} },\\ \quad \frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}&=\frac{(1-\phi )[(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2v^2-(5-4\phi )\phi ^2(1+r_{a})^2{q_{E}}^2]}{4(1+\phi )\phi (1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2(1+r_{a})q_{E} },\\ \quad \frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}&=\frac{(1-\phi )(1+r_{i})(9(1+r_{a})^2\phi ^2 {q_{E}}^2-(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2v^2)}{4(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})^2(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2q_{E}},\\ \quad \frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}&=-\frac{(1-\phi )(1+r_{a})(9(1+r_{a})^2\phi ^2 {q_{E}}^2-(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2v^2)}{4(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})^2(1+\phi r_{a}+(1-\phi )r_{i})^2q_{E}}. \end{aligned}$$

Obviously, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}=-\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}*\frac{1}{(1-\phi )(1+r_{a})}\). Therefore, \(|\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}|\ge |\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}|\) if and only if \((1-\phi )(1+r_{a})\le 1\Rightarrow r_{a}\le \frac{\phi }{1-\phi }\). I can easily obtain that \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}<0\). Besides, \(|\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}|\ge |\frac{\partial \Pi _{E}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}|\) if and only if \(r_{i}\ge r_{a}\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 5

Let \(\Delta q\) denote \(({q_{E}}-{q_{I}})\). Following the same steps in previous Claims, the incumbent’s profit is:

  1. (a)

    When \(r_{a}>r_{i}=0\): \(\Pi _{I}^{\star }=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )^2v^2+(5-4\phi )(1+r_{a})^2\phi ^2\Delta q^2+2(2\phi -1)(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )\phi \Delta q v}{4(1+\phi )(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )\phi \Delta q}\). Then

    \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}>0(<0)\) iff \(\sqrt{5-4\phi }(1+r_{a})\phi \Delta q-(1+\phi r_{a})v>0(<0)\). Also, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial {q_{I}}}>0(<0)\) iff \(\sqrt{5-4\phi }(1+r_{a})\phi \Delta q-(1+\phi r_{a})v<0(>0)\). Note that anticipated action regret and the free upgrades of \(q_{I}\) have opposite effects on the incumbent’s profit.

  2. (b)

    When \(r_{i}>r_{a}=0\): \(\Pi _{I}^{\star }=\frac{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2v^2+2(2\phi -1)[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]\phi \Delta q v+(5-4\phi )\phi ^2\Delta q^2}{4[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )\phi \Delta q}\). Then \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{i}}>0(<0)\) iff \([1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v-\sqrt{5-4\phi }\phi \Delta q>0(<0)\). Also, \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial {q_{I}}}>0(<0)\) iff \([1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v-\sqrt{5-4\phi }\phi \Delta q>0(<0)\). Anticipated inaction regret and the free upgrades have the same effect on the incumbent’s profit. It is easy to see that the effect of \(q_{I}\) on the entrant’s profit is the same as the one of inaction regret. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 6

  1. (i)

    When consumers anticipate action regret:

    $$\begin{aligned} Eu_{I1}(p_{I1},p_{E2})&=k v-p_{I1}-\phi r_{a}[(k-1)\theta {q_{E}}-p_{E2}-v+p_{I1}],\\ \quad u_{I2}(p_{I2})&=(k-1)v-p_{I2},\\ \quad Eu_{E2}(p_{E2})&=(k-1)(v+\phi \theta {q_{E}})-p_{E2}. \end{aligned}$$

    In equilibrium, the prices, demand and profits are:

    $$\begin{aligned} p_{I1}^{\star }&=\frac{(2-\phi )\phi (1+r_{a})(k-1){q_{E}}+\phi (1+r_{a}\phi )v}{(1+\phi )(1+r_{a}\phi )},\\ \quad p_{E2}^{\star }&=p_{I2}^{\star }=\frac{3(1+r_{a})\phi (k-1){q_{E}}-(1+r_{a}\phi ) v}{2(1+r_{a}\phi )(1+\phi )},\\ \quad {\hat{\theta }}^{\star }&=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )v+(2\phi -1)(1+r_{a})\phi (k-1){q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )(1+r_{a})\phi (k-1){q_{E}}},\\ \quad \Pi _{I}^{\star }&=\frac{(1+r_{a}\phi )^2v^2+(5-4\phi )(1+r_{a})^2\phi ^2(k-1)^2{q_{E}} ^2+2(2\phi -1)(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )\phi (k-1) {q_{E}}v}{4(1+\phi )(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )\phi (k-1){q_{E}}},\\ \quad \Pi _{E}^{\star }&=\frac{[3(1+r_{a})\phi (k-1) {q_{E}}-(1+r_{a}\phi )v]^2}{4(1+\phi )^2(1+r_{a})(1+r_{a}\phi )(k-1){q_{E}}}. \end{aligned}$$

    Under Assumption 1, the condition such that \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial r_{a}}\ge 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}^{\star }}{\partial k}\ge 0\) is the same, which is:

    $$\begin{aligned} \sqrt{5-4\phi }(1+r_{a})\phi (k-1)q_{E}-(1+r_{a}\phi )>0. \end{aligned}$$

    Therefore, the effect of a longer duration of the product is the same as that of the anticipated action regret.

  2. (ii)

    When consumers anticipate inaction regret:

    $$\begin{aligned} u_{I1}(p_{I1})&=k v-p_{I1},\\ \quad u_{I2}(p_{I2})&=(k-1)v-p_{I2},\\ \quad Eu_{E2}(p_{I1},p_{E2})&=(k-1)(v+\phi \theta {q_{E}})-p_{E2}-(1-\phi )r_{i}(v-p_{I1}+p_{E2}). \end{aligned}$$

    In equilibrium, the prices, demand and profits are:

    $$\begin{aligned} p_{I1}^{\star }&=\frac{(2-\phi )\phi (k-1){q_{E}}+\phi [1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v}{(1+\phi )[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]},\\ \quad p_{E2}^{\star }=p_{I2}^{\star }&=\frac{3\phi (k-1){q_{E}}-[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v}{2[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )},\\ \quad {\hat{\theta }}^{\star }&=\frac{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v+(2\phi -1)\phi (k-1){q_{E}}}{2(1+\phi )\phi (k-1){q_{E}}},\\ \quad \Pi _{I}^{\star }&=\frac{[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]^2v^2+2(2\phi -1)[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]\phi v (k-1){q_{E}}+(5-4\phi )\phi ^2(k-1)^2{q_{E}}^2}{4[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](1+\phi )\phi (k-1){q_{E}}},\\ \quad \Pi _{E}^{\star }&=\frac{(3\phi (k-1){q_{E}}-[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}]v)^2}{4(1+\phi )^2[1+(1-\phi )r_{i}](k-1){q_{E}}}. \end{aligned}$$

    Given Assumption 1 and Assumption 4, the condition such that \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial r_{i}}\le 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi _{I}}{\partial k}\ge 0\) is the same, which is: \(\sqrt{5-4\phi }\phi (k-1)q_{E}-(1-\phi )r_{i}-1\ge 0\). Note that the effect of a longer duration of the product is opposite to that of the anticipated inaction regret. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, Q. The impact of consumer’s regret on firms’ decisions in a durable good market. J Econ 139, 125–157 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-023-00819-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-023-00819-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation