Skip to main content
Log in

Better with buy now, pay later?: A competitive analysis

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we study the incentives of vertically differentiated firms to offer Buy Now, Pay Later (BNPL) in a competitive market. BNPL is a relatively new payment mechanism which, at the point of sale, allows consumers to pay for a product in interest-free installments spread out over a few weeks/months. For a monopolist, offering BNPL is essentially about expanding the market by offering financing to the consumers who cannot afford its product. Therefore, a monopolist is always better-off providing BNPL to its consumers. However, in a competitive environment, offering BNPL is a more complex strategic decision because retailers also need to consider strategic reactions from their competitors. We find that in a competitive situation either of the two retailers might refrain from offering BNPL. This is because when one retailer offers BNPL, the other firm not offering BNPL also benefits from competitive spillovers. Although a monopolist’s benefits from offering BNPL increases in its product quality, in a competitive environment, holding all else constant, a low-quality firm might have more to gain from offering BNPL. In addition to asymmetric equilibria, we also find that there is a symmetric equilibrium in which both retailers offer BNPL. In view of public concerns about possible negative impact of BNPL on consumers, we also study how BNPL consumers’ ignoring the cost of using BNPL can adversely affect them. We find that underestimation of these costs lowers consumers’ welfare, and this reduction in welfare stems from three different sources - (i) higher product prices, (ii) excessive purchase, and (ii) excessive upgrades to the higher quality product.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is another variation of Buy Now, Pay Later payments, in which consumers can pay over time but by paying interest. In this paper, we focus exclusively on interest-free BNPL payment arrangements.

  2. See Greenwood (2021) and https://my.sezzle.com/merchant-resources/4-reasons-why-you-need-to-add-a-buy-now-pay-later-solution-to-your-online-store/ (accessed on December 19, 2022).

  3. Please see Section 1.1 for more information about BNPL.

  4. Our understanding is that offering a credit card or consumer credit will require a retailer to start a bank, a credit union, or an industrial bank. That is an extremely complex process subject to extensive regulations governed by the Federal Reserve, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and possibly other state-level agencies.

  5. https://my.sezzle.com/merchant-resources/4-reasons-why-you-need-to-add-a-buy-now-pay-later-solution-to-your-online-store/ (accessed on December 19, 2022).

  6. See https://fortune.com/recommends/credit-cards/buy-now-pay-later-vs-credit-card/.

  7. See https://www.consumerfinance.gov/data-research/research-reports/consumer-use-of-buy-now-pay-later-insights-from-the-cfpb-making-ends-meet-survey/.

  8. Sometimes firms’ incentives change due to reasons other than competitive interactions or strategic consumer behavior. See Liu et al. (2022) for an example in which different revenue formats (advertising-based or subscription-based) create different incentives for a social media platform to moderate its content.

  9. See https://afterpay-corporate.yourcreative.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2021/10/Economic-Impact-of-BNPL-in-the-US-vF.pdf, accessed on December 12, 2022.

  10. Bruce et al. (2006) studies consumer rebates for a monopolist using a similar model.

  11. Throughout the paper, we restrict attention to parameters for which the two firms have positive demands in Segment 1 and non-negative demands in Segment 2.

  12. The term equilibrium here applies to the equilibrium of the NN subgame in the Stage 2 of the full game.

  13. Please note that the effect of \(\delta _{c}\) on various profits is highly non-linear and cannot be generalized from Fig. 3.

  14. Please note that in this case too, the effect of \(\delta _{c}\) on various profits is highly nonlinear and cannot be generalized from Fig. 5.

  15. Note that the condition in Result 1 helps us characterize possible outcomes further with a relatively simple condition, but is not a substitute for either YN or NY conditions.

  16. Similarly, \(\psi _{L}^{*}\) increases as Firm H’s gains from not offering BNPL when Firm L does offer BNPL \((\pi _{H}^{NY*}-\pi _{H}^{YY*})\) relative to Firm H’s gains from offering BNPL when Firm L does not offer BNPL (\(\pi _{H}^{YN*}-\pi _{H}^{NN*}\)).

  17. In calculating \(\triangle \theta _{L}\), we are focusing on the lower-end consumers who would not have made any purchase had they considered the cost of using BNPL.

  18. A not unexpected but perhaps less visible effect is that Segment 1 and Segment 2 consumers would pay higher prices.

  19. We restrict our attention to the cases where \(p_{H}^{Y0*}>p_{L}^{Y0*}\), which requires that \(2q_{H}-(1+2\rho _{2})q_{L}>0\).

References

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the Editor and two anonymous reviewers at the Quantitative Marketing and Economics journal. All errors and omissions are the responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Preyas S. Desai.

Ethics declarations

Funding and Competing Interests

All authors certify that they have no affiliations with or involvement in any organization or entity with any financial interest or non-financial interest in the subject matter or materials discussed in this manuscript.The authors have no funding to report.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Note: The equilibrium prices and profits in different cases are derived as usual. Details are available from the authors upon request.

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

The YN case is an equilibrium if and only if the Condition YN below is satisfied.

Condition YN:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}>1 \end{aligned}$$
(54)

We first show that \(\pi _{H}^{YN*}>\pi _{H}^{NN*}\) and then show that \(\pi _{L}^{YN*}>\pi _{L}^{YY*}\) when the YN condition is satisfied. After substituting \(\delta _{H}=\delta _{F}\) and \(\delta _{L}=\delta _{F}\), the profit expressions are as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{H}^{YN*}= & {} \frac{4q_{H}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(\rho _{1}\!+\!\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}\!+\!\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})q_{L})}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}\\ \pi _{L}^{YN*}= & {} \frac{\rho _{1}q_{H}q_{L}(q_{H}-q_{L})(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}\\ \pi _{H}^{NN*}= & {} \frac{4q_{H}^{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})\rho _{1}}{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}}\\ \pi _{L}^{YY*}= & {} \frac{q_{H}q_{L}(q_{H}-q_{L})(\rho _{1}+(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2}}{(4q_{H}-q_{L}){}^{2}(\rho _{1}+(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})} \end{aligned}$$

\(\frac{\pi _{H}^{YN*}}{\pi _{H}^{YN*}}=\frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})q_{L})}{\rho _{1}q_{H}(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}\). This can be rewritten as

$$ \frac{\pi _{H}^{YN*}}{\pi _{H}^{YN*}}\!=\!\left( \!\frac{\rho _{1}q_{H}\!+\!\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})q_{L}}{\rho _{1}q_{H}}\!\right) \left( \!\frac{(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}\!+\!\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}\!\right) $$

It is easy to see that \(\frac{\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})q_{L}}{\rho _{1}q_{H}}>1\). For \(\theta _{H}^{YN1}\in [0,1]\),

$$ \frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L})(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))}>1, $$

which also means that \(\frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}>1\). \(\square \)

After simplification, \(\frac{\pi _{L}^{YN*}}{\pi _{L}^{YY*}}=\frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L}){}^{2}\rho _{1}(\rho _{1}+(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}\). Therefore,

$$ \frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L}){}^{2}\rho _{1}(\rho _{1}+(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}\gtrless 1\iff \frac{\pi _{L}^{YN*}}{\pi _{L}^{YY*}}\gtrless 1. $$

\(\square \)

1.1.1 Proof of Proposition 2

The NY case is an equilibrium iff the condition NY is satisfied.

Condition NY:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})^{2}\rho _{1}(\rho _{1}\!+\!\rho _{2}(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))(\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F})(2q_{H}(1\!+\!\delta _{c})\!-\!q_{L}(1\!+\!2\delta _{c}))\!+\!2\rho _{1}q_{H})^{2}}{4q_{H}^{2}(\rho _{1}\!+\!\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L}))^{2}}\!>\!1 \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Here again, we first show that \(\pi _{L}^{NY*}>\pi _{L}^{NN*}\) and then show that the NY condition is equivalent to \(\pi _{H}^{NY*}>\pi _{H}^{YY*}\).

After substituting \(\delta _{H}=\delta _{F}\) and \(\delta _{L}=\delta _{F}\), the profit expressions are as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} \pi {}_{H}^{NY*}= & {} \frac{\rho _{1}(q_{H}-q_{L})(2\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(2q_{H}(1+\delta _{c})-q_{L}(1+2\delta _{c})))^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}}\\ \pi _{H}^{YY*}= & {} \frac{4q_{H}^{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(\rho _{1}+(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2}}{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}+(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2}}\\ \pi {}_{L}^{NY*}= & {} \frac{q_{L}(q_{H}-q_{L})(\rho _{1}+2\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}+(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}}\\ \pi _{L}^{NN*}= & {} \frac{\rho _{1}q_{H}q_{L}(q_{H}-q_{L})}{(4q_{H}-q_{L}){}^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

\(\dfrac{\pi _{L}^{NY*}}{\pi {}_{L}^{NN*}}\!=\!\dfrac{(4q_{H}-q_{L}){}^{2}(\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}+(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})}{\rho _{1}q_{H}(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}}\), which can be rewritten as

$$ \frac{\pi _{L}^{NY*}}{\pi _{L}^{NN*}}\!=\!\!\left( \!\frac{\rho _{1}q_{H}\!+\!\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})q_{L}}{\rho _{1}q_{H}}\!\right) \!\left( \!\frac{(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}\!\right) \!. $$

It is easy to see that \(\dfrac{\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})q_{L}}{\rho _{1}q_{H}}>1.\) After simplification and rearranging terms,

$$ \frac{(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}}\!-\!1\!=\!\frac{4(2q_{H}(1\!-\!\delta _{c})\!+\!q_{L}(1\!+\!2\delta _{c}))\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\eta }{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}} $$

where \(\eta =2q_{H}(2\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(3+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))-q_{L}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(3+2\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))>0\). Therefore,

$$ \frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}(\rho _{1}+2\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}>1 $$

and \(\frac{\pi _{L}^{NY*}}{\pi _{L}^{NN*}}>1.\) \(\square \)

\(\frac{\pi {}_{H}^{NY*}}{\pi {}_{H}^{YY*}}=\frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}\rho _{1}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))(2\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(2q_{H}(1+\delta _{c})-q_{L}(1+2\delta _{c})))^{2}}{4q_{H}^{2}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}}\).

Therefore,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{(4q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}\rho _{1}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F}))(2\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(2q_{H}(1+\delta _{c})-q_{L}(1+2\delta _{c})))^{2}}{4q_{H}^{2}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}}&\gtrless 1\\ \iff \frac{\pi {}_{H}^{NY*}}{\pi {}_{H}^{YY*}}&\gtrless 1. \end{aligned}$$

1.1.2 Proof of Proposition 3

A YY equilibrium can occur iff either Condition YN or Condition NY is violated.

As proofs of Propositions 1 and 2 show, for each firm, offering BNPL is the dominant strategy when the other firm does not offer BNPL. When Condition YN is violated, \(\pi _{L}^{YN*}<\pi _{L}^{YY*}\) and Firm L will deviate to offering BNPL when Firm H offers BNPL. Along similar lines, when Condition NY is violated, \(\pi _{H}^{NY*}<\pi _{H}^{YY*}\)and Firm H will deviate to offering BNPL when Firm L offers BNPL. Thus, when either condition is violated, the YY case is an equilibrium.\(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Result 1

If \(\delta _{c}>\frac{q_{L}}{2q_{H}-q_{L}}\), then only YN equilibrium cannot exist. If \(\delta _{c}<\frac{q_{L}}{2q_{H}-q_{L}}\), then only NY equilibrium cannot exist.

We compare Conditions YN and NY to identify the conditions under which one of them is more stringent than the other. We define \(\Lambda \) as

$$ \Lambda =\frac{2\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(2q_{H}(1+\delta _{c})-q_{L}(1+2\delta _{c}))}{2q_{H}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))}. $$
$$ \Lambda -1=\frac{\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(2q_{H}\delta _{c}-q_{L}(1+2\delta _{c}))}{2q_{H}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))}. $$

When \(\delta _{c}>(<)\frac{q_{L}}{2(q_{H}-q_{L})}\), the numerator of \(\Lambda -1\) is positive (negative), and \(\Lambda >(<)1\).

Taking the ratio of the LHS of Condition NY to the LHS of Condition YN, we get,

$$ \frac{(2\rho _{1}q_{H}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(2q_{H}(1+\delta _{c})-q_{L}(1+2\delta _{c})))^{2}}{4q_{H}^{2}(\rho _{1}+\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}}=\Lambda ^{2}. $$

Therefore, when \(\delta _{c}>(<)\frac{q_{L}}{2q_{H}-q_{L}}\), Condition NY is less (more) stringent than Condition YN and it is possible that Condition NY (YN) is satisfied but Condition YN (NY) is not.\(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 4

Firm H prefers the YN equilibrium to the NY equilibrium: \(\pi _{H}^{YN*}>\pi _{H}^{NY*}\), whereas Firm L prefers the NY equilibrium to the YN equilibrium: \(\pi _{L}^{YN*}<\pi _{L}^{NY*}\).

$$ \pi _{L}^{NY*}-\pi _{L}^{YN*}\!=\!\!\frac{q_{L}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})((\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}\!+\!(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})\!-\!\rho _{1}q_{H}(\rho _{1}\!+\!(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2})}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})\!+\!4\rho _{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})){}^{2}\!} $$

The denominator of the above expression is positive. Therefore we need to show that \(((\rho _{1}+2\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}+(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})-\rho _{1}q_{H}(\rho _{1}+(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2})>0\).

$$ \begin{array}{l} ((\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H}\!+\!(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})\!-\!\rho _{1}q_{H}(\rho _{1}\!+\!(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2})\\ =\!((\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(\rho _{1}q_{H})\!-\!\rho _{1}q_{H}(\rho _{1}\!+\!(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})^{2})\!+\!((\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})\\ =\!\rho _{1}\rho _{2}q_{H}(1\!-\!\delta _{F})(2\rho _{1}\!+\!3(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})\!+\!((\rho _{1}\!+\!2\rho _{2}(1\!-\!\delta _{F}))^{2}(q_{H}\!-\!q_{L})(1\!+\!\delta _{c})(1\!-\!\delta _{F})\rho _{2})>0 \end{array} $$

Thus, \(\pi _{L}^{YN*}-\pi _{L}^{NY*}>0\). \(\square \)

$$ \pi _{H}^{YN*}-\pi _{L}^{NY*}=\frac{\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1-\delta _{F})(4\rho _{1}^{2}q_{H}^{2}+k_{1}+k_{2}+k_{3})}{(\rho _{1}(4q_{H}-q_{L})+4\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1+\delta _{c})(1-\delta _{F})){}^{2}},\textrm{where} $$
$$\begin{aligned} k_{1}= & {} \rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(8q_{H}^{2}\rho _{1}-4q_{H}q_{L}\rho _{1}-q_{L}^{2}\rho _{1}+4\rho _{2}q_{H}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1-\delta _{F})),\\ k_{2}= & {} 4(q_{H}-q_{L})\delta _{c}(q_{H}((1-\delta _{F})^{2}-\rho _{1}^{2})+\rho _{1}\rho _{2}q_{L}(1-\delta _{F})),\\ k_{3}= & {} -4\rho _{1}\rho _{2}(q_{H}-q_{L})^{2}\delta _{c}^{2}(1-\delta _{F}). \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(k_{1}>0\) and \(k_{3}<0\). Because \(\delta _{c}\in (0,1)\), \(k_{1}+k_{3}>k_{1}+\frac{k_{3}}{\delta _{c}^{2}}\). It can be shown that \(k_{1}+\frac{k_{3}}{\delta _{c}^{2}}=\rho _{1}\rho _{2}(1-\delta _{F})(4q_{H}^{2}+4q_{H}q_{L}-5q_{L}^{2})+4\rho _{2}^{2}(1-\delta _{F})^{2}q_{H}(q_{H}-q_{L})>0\). Therefore, \(k_{1}+k_{3}>0\). \(k_{2}+4\rho _{1}^{2}q_{H}^{2}=4\rho _{1}^{2}q_{H}^{2}(1-\delta _{c})+4\delta _{c}(q_{H}q_{L}\rho _{1}^{2}+(q_{H}-q_{L})q_{L})(1-\delta _{F})\rho _{1}\rho _{2}+q_{H}(q_{H}-q_{L})(1-\delta _{F})^{2}\rho _{2}^{2})>0.\)Therefore, \(\pi _{H}^{YN*}-\pi _{L}^{NY*}>0\).\(\square \)

1.4 Proof of Proposition 5

For the parameter values for which both asymmetric equilibria can coexist with pure strategies, \(\psi _{H}^{*}=\dfrac{(\pi _{L}^{NY*}-\pi _{L}^{NN*})}{(\pi _{L}^{NY*}-\pi _{L}^{NN*})+(\pi _{L}^{YN*}-\pi _{L}^{YY*})}\) and \(\psi _{L}^{*}=\) \(\dfrac{(\pi _{H}^{YN*}-\pi _{H}^{NN*})}{(\pi _{H}^{YN*}-\pi _{H}^{NN*})+(\pi _{H}^{NY*}-\pi _{H}^{YY*})}.\)

When Firm H plays BNPL with probability \(\psi _{H},\) Firm L’s profit from offering BNPL is

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _{H}\pi _{L}^{YY*}+(1-\psi _{H})\pi _{L}^{NY*} \end{aligned}$$
(56)

Firm L’s profit from not offering BNPL is

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _{H}\pi _{L}^{YN*}+(1-\psi _{H})\pi _{L}^{NN*} \end{aligned}$$
(57)

Equating the above two profits and solving for \(\psi _{H}\), we get the equilibrium value as,

$$ \psi _{H}^{*}\!=\!\frac{(\pi _{L}^{NY*}\!-\!\pi _{L}^{NN*})}{(\pi _{L}^{NY*}\!-\!\pi _{L}^{NN*})\!+\!(\pi _{L}^{YN*}\!-\!\pi _{L}^{YY*})};\;\psi _{L}^{*}\!=\!\frac{(\pi _{H}^{YN*}\!-\!\pi _{H}^{NN*})}{(\pi _{H}^{YN*}\!-\!\pi _{H}^{NN*})\!+\!(\pi _{H}^{NY*}\!-\!\pi _{H}^{YY*})} $$

We can write \(\psi _{H}^{*}=\frac{1}{1+z_{L}}\) where \(z_{L}=\frac{\pi _{L}^{YN*}-\pi _{L}^{YY*}}{\pi _{L}^{NY*}-\pi _{L}^{NN*}}\) and \(\psi _{L}^{*}=\frac{1}{1+z_{H}}\) where \(z_{H}=\frac{\pi _{H}^{NY*}-\pi _{H}^{YY*}}{\pi _{H}^{YN*}-\pi _{H}^{NN*}}\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Desai, P.S., Jindal, P. Better with buy now, pay later?: A competitive analysis. Quant Mark Econ 22, 23–61 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09271-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09271-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation