Skip to main content
Log in

Credible spatial preemption in a mixed oligopoly

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we consider a public incumbent firm who produces multiple products and a private potential foreign entrant who contemplates on entering the market. Contrary to Judd (Rand J Econ 16:153–166, 1985) that preemption of the private incumbent by overcrowding the product space is not a credible threat of intense postentry competition if the exit cost of the incumbent is low, we show that if the incumbent is a public firm who cares about consumer surplus as well, the public incumbent’s preemption can credibly threaten an entrant with intense postentry competition without exiting after entry into the same location as the incumbent’s. Paradoxically, entering the identical location as the incumbent does not occur in the case of a public incumbent who relatively favors entry (inducing low consumer prices), whereas entry can occur in the case of a private incumbent who does not want entry. However, we also show that the incumbent can encourage entry by choosing its locations to leave enough room for the entrant so that the entrant can profitably enter locations far from the incumbent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Canadian government approved of Verizon’s acquisition of Wind Mobile or Mobilicity for entry into the Canadian mobile telecommunications market, while it did not approve of Canadian carrier Telus’ acquisition of Mobilicity.

  2. It is known as the multi-store paradox in the literature of industrial organization. Briefly speaking, the multi-store paradox means that economic theory can hardly support the real-world observations of many firms establishing multiple stores selling substitutes, because firms prefer to open one store rather than multiple stores in equilibrium to avoid competition. Martinez-Giralt and Neven (1988) and Judd (1985) are two prominent articles that capture the economic insight. The multi-store paradox has been resolved by Ishibashi (2003), Tabuchi (2012), Murooka (2013), Hirose and Matsumura (2016) etc. Ishibashi (2003) shows that preemption by crowding can be a credible entry barrier if multiple potential entrants choose the timing of entry endogenously. Tabuchi (2012) demonstrates that the paradox can be resolved if three or more firms are allowed to enter the market. Murooka (2013)shows that spatial preemption can be a credible entry barrier if the incumbent can build its store on five or more locations. Hirose and Matsumura (2016) show that firms can maintain multiple stores if firms have interdependent payoffs so that they do not maximize their own profits but maximize their relative profit to the rival’s profit.

  3. Here, we interpret cream skimming broadly. If an entrant enters the identical location to the incumbent, we interpret it as cream skimming from the implicit assumption that the incumbent chose the location due to high profitability. Although we do not assume an uneven population distribution across locations just as in usual literature, this insight that a public incumbent will not give up the location whenever an entrant enters the identical location around which the market demand is centered will be valid even if the distribution is uneven.

  4. Earlier, Harris and Wiens (1980) also analyze a mixed oligopoly with differentiated products.

  5. Under the assumption of a circular city, \((x_A , x_{B})=(0, \frac{1}{2})\) is equivalent to \((x_{A}, x_{B})=(x, x+\frac{1}{2})\) for any x. So, we normalize \(x_A\) to zero.

  6. This is not a unique optimal location. For more details, see Footnotes 9 and 10.

  7. We focus only on the symmetric equilibrium following the spirit of Farrell (1987). He argues that an asymmetric Nash equilibrium in a symmetric situation represents a considerable feat of coordination between players so that such an asymmetric coordination is hardly achieved, even if it exists. Note that this game is symmetric between \(x_A\) and \(x_B\).

  8. Ishibashi (2003) also considers a firm’s strategic manipulation of its locations in the case of entry threat. In his model, however, the incumbent manipulates its location by crowding the space in such a way that the first entrant cannot enter profitably and the second entrant can enter only after the first entrant’s entry, and the first entrant manipulates the location to deter the second entry, whereas the incumbent manipulates the location by opening the space to accommodate entry in our model. Manipulation by an entrant does not occur in equilibrium in his model, because entry occurs only off the equilibrium path, while manipulation occurs in equilibrium in our model. Also, the strategically manipulated location of either the incumbent or the entrant is not explicitly solved in their model, whereas it is explicitly solved in our model.

  9. We can focus on the welfare-maximizing outcome \(x_2 =\frac{1}{2}\) on the ground that the entrant has no reason to reject the incumbent’s request to choose the location, insofar as he is indifferent.

  10. This result is shared with Kats (1995) who shows that the equilibrium locations are \(x_1 = 0\) and \(x_2 \in [1/4, 1/2]\) on a unit circle in a model in which two private firms compete. The main reason for this multiplicity is that \(q=\frac{1}{2}-\frac{p_{2}-p_{1}}{t}\) does not depend on x, neither does the profit \(\pi _2 =p_2 q\). If consumers have quadratic transportation costs, however, the optimal location is unique. With quadratic costs, \(z_1 =\frac{x}{2}+\frac{p_{2}-p_{1}}{2xt}\) and \(z_2 =\frac{x+1}{2}+\frac{p_{2}-p_{1}}{2t(x-1)}\), so \(q=z_2 -z_1 =\frac{1}{2}-\frac{p_{2}-p_{1}}{2tx(1-x)}\). Note that q depends on x. If the entrant chooses x, the Nash equilibrium prices \(p_{1}^{*}\) and \(p_{2}^{*}\) are subsequently determined. The entrant’s profit given x is \(\pi _{2}^{*} (x) =p_{2}^{*} q = \frac{p_{2}^{*2}}{2tx(1-x)}\) by using its best response function, \(p_{2}^{*}-p_{1}^{*}=tx(1-x)-p_{2}^{*}\). Thus, the optimal location \(x^*\) is determined by the first order condition of the optimization problem, \(\max _{x} \pi _{2}^{*}(x)\). By the Envelope Theorem, we obtain \(x^* =\frac{1}{2}\).

  11. If \(\frac{4}{225}t<f<\frac{1}{16}t\), firm 2 enters when \(n=1\) but does not enter when \(n=2\). However, since firm 1 produces two products in equilibrium in this case, firm 2 does not enter at any rate.

  12. Suppose the entrant produces \(m(<n)\) goods, say \(m=1\). Even if the entrant enters the midpoint of a pair of adjacent locations of the incumbent, those two products and other products cannot be symmetric. In this case, it involves quite complicated computations to find all the prices of different products.

  13. It is possible that \(n^{**}=n^{*}\), considering the integer constraint.

References

  • Anderson S, Neven D (1991) Cournot competition yields spatial agglomeration. Int Econ Rev 32:793–808

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz J, Garzón M (2003) Mixed duopoly, merger and multiproduct firms. J Econ 80:27–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beato P, Mas-Colell A (1984) The marginal cost pricing as a regulation mechanism in mixed markets. In: Marchand M, Pestieau P, Tulkens H (eds) The performance of public enterprises. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, Marchand M, Thisse JF (1991) Mixed oligopoly with differentiated products. Int J Ind Org 9:43–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1979) On Hotelling’s ‘stability in competition’. Econometrica 47:1045–1050

    Google Scholar 

  • DeFraja G, Delbono F (1989) Alternative strategies of a public enterprise in oligopoly. Oxf Econ Pap 41:302–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton BC, Lipsey RG (1979) The theory of market preemption: the persistence of excess capacity and monopoly in growing spatial markets. Economica 46:149–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides N, White L (1995) Access and interconnection pricing: How efficient is the efficient component pricing rule? Antitrust Bull 40:557–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell J (1987) Cheap talk, coordination, and entry. RAND J Econ 18:34–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell K, Pal D (1996) A mixed oligopoly in the presence of foreign private firms. Can J Econ 29:737–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell K, Heywood J (2002) Public Stackelberg leadership in a mixed oligopoly with foreign firms. Aust Econ Pap 41:267–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JH, Thisse J-F, Weskamp A (1989) Spatial discrimination: Bertrand versus Cournot in a model of location choice. Reg Sci Urban Econ 19:87–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haraguchi J, Matsumura T (2016) Cournot–Bertrand comparison in a mixed oligopoly. J Econ 117:117–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris R, Wiens E (1980) Government enterprise: an instrument for the internal regulation of industry. Can J Econ 13:125–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirose K, Matsumura T (2016) Payoff interdependence and the multi-store paradox. Asia Pac J Account Econ 23:256–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishibashi I (2003) A note on credible spatial entry deterrence. Int J Ind Org 21:283–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd K (1985) Credible spatial preemption. Rand J Econ 16:153–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kats A (1995) More on Hotelling’s stability in competition. Int J Ind Org 13:89–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Giralt X, Neven DJ (1988) Can price competition dominate market segmentation? J Ind Econ 36:431–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T (1998) Partial privatization in mixed duopoly. J Public Econ 70:473–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T (2003) Stackelberg mixed duopoly with a foreign competitor. Bull Econ Res 55:275–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Matsushima N (2003) Mixed duopoly with product differentiation: sequential choice of location. Aust Econ Pap 42:18–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima N, Matsumura T (2003) Mixed oligopoly and spatial agglomeration. Can J Econ 36:62–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima N, Matsumura T (2006) Mixed oligopoly, foreign firms, and location choice. Reg Sci Urban Econ 36:753–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merrill WC, Schneider N (1966) Government firms in oligopoly industries: a short-run analysis. Q J Econ 80:400–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murooka T (2013) A note on credible spatial preemption in an entry-exit game. Econ Lett 118:26–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal D (1998) Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly. Econ Lett 61:181–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salop S (1979) Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell J Econ 10:141–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee R (1978) Entry deterrence in the ready-to-eat breakfast cereal industry. Bell J Econ 9:305–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabuchi T (2012) Multiproduct firms in Hotelling’s spatial competition. J Econ Manag Strategy 21:445–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ye G (2016) Leadership and privatization in a mixed multi-product oligopoly: an endogenous timing model. Aust Econ Pap 55:170–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeong-Yoo Kim.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no known conflict of interest or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix, we consider the case that the public incumbent locates \(n (\ge 2)\) products equidistantly and the entrant enters with a single product. The interaction between the public incumbent and the private entrant is the same as in Sect. 5. Because of the analytic complexity as put in Footnote 3, we will assume that price discrimination among its substitutable products is not allowed.

From Lemma 1, we know that the entrant will not enter one of the locations of the incumbent, because the public incumbent will not leave the location even after the entry. Rather, it will enter the midpoint between two adjacent locations which are farthest apart. We assume that the entrant enters between the first two products of the incumbent if it enters. If the incumbent has n products, it will locate their products at \({\mathbf {x}}_{1}=(x_{11}, x_{12}, \ldots , x_{1n})=(0, 2x, 2x +\frac{1-2x}{n-1}, \ldots , 2x+(n-2)\frac{1-2x}{n-1})\) where the distance between two neighboring locations is \(\frac{1-2x}{n-1}\) except the distance between \(x_{11}\) and \(x_{12}\), knowing that it is socially optimal for \((n+1)\) products to be located equidistantly after entry. Assume that \(2x >\frac{1-2x}{n-1}\). By abusing notation, we denote the marginal consumer between 0 and x by \(z^{**}\). Then, \(z^{**}\) is determined by

$$\begin{aligned} tz +p_1 = t(x-z)+ p_{2}. \end{aligned}$$
(45)

So, we have \(z^{**}=\frac{x}{2}+\frac{p_{2}-p_{1}}{2t}\). Then, the demand for the entrant is

$$\begin{aligned} q=2(x-z^{**})=x-\frac{p_{2}-p_{1}}{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(46)

and the profits are \(\pi _2 =p_2 q\) and \(\pi _1 =p_1 (1-q)\). The average transportation cost and consumer surplus are appropriately modified as

$$\begin{aligned}&\tilde{T}=\frac{1}{4}\left[ \frac{(1-2x)^{2}}{n-1}+4x^2 -4xq+2q^2 \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(47)
$$\begin{aligned}&CS = r-\tilde{p}-t\tilde{T}, \end{aligned}$$
(48)

where \(\tilde{p}=p_1 (1-q)+p_2 q\). Thus we have

$$\begin{aligned} SW^E (n) = r-\left[ \frac{(1-2x)^{2}}{4(n-1)}+x^2 \right] t -(p_2 -xt)q -\frac{1}{2}tq^2 -nf. \end{aligned}$$
(49)

Given n, 2x is determined by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial SW^{E}(n)}{\partial x}=-\frac{t}{8}\left[ 14x - \frac{8(1-2x)}{n-1}\right] = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(50)

Therefore, \(x=\frac{4}{7n+1} (<\frac{1}{n+1})\), implying that \(1-2x=\frac{7(n-1)}{7n+1}\). Thus, we have

$$\begin{aligned} SW^{E}(n) &= {} r-\frac{t}{8}\left[ \frac{112}{(7n+1)^{2}}+\frac{98(n-1)}{(7n+1)^{2}}\right] -nf \nonumber \\ &= {} r-\frac{t}{4}\left[ \frac{7}{7n+1}\right] -nf \nonumber \\ & >{} r-\left[ \frac{t}{4n}+nf \right] =SW (n). \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Let \(n^{**}\) be the socially optimal number of products provided by the incumbent. Then, \(n^{**}\) is determined by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial SW^{E}(n)}{\partial n}=\frac{49t}{4(7n+1)^{2}}-f =0. \end{aligned}$$
(52)

Therefore, \(n^{**}=\frac{1}{2}\left( \frac{t}{f }\right) ^{1/2}-\frac{1}{7}<n^{*}\).Footnote 13 As a result, we have \(SW^{E}(n^{**})=r-(tf )^{1/2}+\frac{f }{7}>SW (n^{*})\).

Proposition 3

(i) \(n^{**}\le n^{*}\) and (ii) \(SW^E (n^{**})>SW (n^{*})\).

This proposition confirms the main insight of this paper that it is possible for the incumbent to encourage entry by under-crowding the product space.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kang, S., Kim, JY. Credible spatial preemption in a mixed oligopoly. J Econ 137, 171–190 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-022-00790-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-022-00790-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation