Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal revenue-sharing mechanisms with seller commitment to ex-post effort

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study considers the characterization and implementation of the optimal revenue-sharing mechanism when the seller’s ex-post effort affects the final outcome. In the optimal revenue-sharing mechanism with the seller’s full commitment to effort exertion, the seller commits to the first-best effort. Under the regularity condition guaranteed by the assumption of log-concave density, the optimal mechanism selects the bidder with the highest type, provided that the associated virtual surplus with the seller’s commitment to the first-best effort is positive. A first-price share auction with an appropriate reserve share and an effort commitment scheme can implement the optimal revenue-sharing mechanism. However, a second-price share auction might fail for implementation, such as in a case with two bidders and a uniform type distribution. Lastly, we introduce a sealed-bid share auction called the first-second price share auction, which can implement the optimal mechanism in dominant strategy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We say a bidding strategy is (quasi) strictly increasing if it is strictly increasing in all participating types.

  2. The multiplicative form captures the complementarity between the operator’s productivity and the seller’s input. Kogan and Morgan (2010) adopt a similar specification.

  3. See Riordan and Sappington (1988) and DeMarzo et al. (2005).

  4. The assumption regarding the quadratic form of disutility does not cause a loss of economic insight and is only for expositional ease. Our results could be extended to general convex forms of disutility.

  5. Without confusion, “effort” here has a general meaning, including input, investment, capacity, (see, Dixit 1987).

  6. See DeMarzo et al. (2005) for the argument regarding limited liability. The full-rent-extracting mechanism proposed by Riordan and Sappington (1988) generally violates the limited liability constraint.

  7. The term “full commitment” means that the seller commits to an allocation rule, an effort commitment scheme, and a revenue-sharing rule. Without full commitment, the seller’s sequential rationality leads to moral hazard issues, and the revelation principle fails (see, Bester and Strausz 2001; Doval and Vasiliki 2020). We will consider this issue extensively in a future study.

  8. See Bagnoli and Bergstrom (2005).

  9. A bidding strategy for a bidder is (quasi) strictly increasing if a participating type’s bid specified by this strategy increases as the type rises.

  10. Since \(J^*(\theta _r) \ge 0\), it holds that \(\frac{\theta _r^2}{\uplambda k} \ge 2+ \frac{2}{\theta _r}\cdot \frac{1-F(\theta _r)}{f(\theta _r)}\cdot \frac{\int ^{{\overline{\theta }}}_{{\theta }_r}\theta f(\theta ) d\theta }{\theta _r [1-F(\theta _r)]}\), thus we have \(s_r \in (1/2, 1)\).

  11. In any equilibrium with the symmetric (quasi) strictly increasing bidding strategy of the proposed first-price auction, each bidder i with type \(\theta _i \ge \theta _r\) earns an equilibrium expected payoff \(\pi _i(\beta (\theta _i), \theta _i) = k\theta _i \int _{\theta _r}^{\theta _i} \frac{g(\tau )}{\tau }d\tau\) obtained by Condition IC2 and the zero-payoff argument for type \(\theta _r\). Accordingly, the equilibrium bid for type \(\theta _i\) must be \(\beta (\theta _i) = 1-\frac{\uplambda k}{\theta _i^2}-\frac{\uplambda k}{G(\theta _i)\theta _i}\int _{\theta _r}^{\theta _i}\frac{G(\tau )}{\tau ^2}d\tau = \beta ^{I}(\theta _i)\).

  12. As \(\epsilon <1\), the type threshold \(\epsilon< \theta _r = \sqrt{\frac{\epsilon + \sqrt{\epsilon ^2 + 4\epsilon (1+\epsilon )^2}}{2}} < 2\epsilon ^{\frac{1}{4}}\). Thus, \(\frac{ 2 \epsilon }{\theta _r} - \ln \frac{\theta }{\theta _r}< \epsilon ^{\frac{3}{4}} - 2 \ln \frac{\theta }{2\epsilon ^{\frac{1}{4}}} < 1 - 2 \ln \frac{\theta }{2\epsilon ^{\frac{1}{4}}}\).

References

  • Bagnoli M, Bergstrom T (2005) Log-concave probability and its applications. Econ Theor 26:445–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bester H, Strausz R (2001) Contracting with imperfect commitment and the revelation principle: the single agent case. Econometrica 69:1077–1098

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che Y, Kim J (2009) Bidding with securities: comment. Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper 0809–10

  • Chen X, Wang D, Zeng X (2020) Equity auctions with the seller’s moral hazard. Nanjing University Discussion Paper

  • DeMarzo PM, Kremer I, Skrzypacz A (2005) Bidding with securities: auctions and security design. Am Econ Rev 95:936–959

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (1987) Strategic behavior in contests. Am Econ Rev 77:891–898

    Google Scholar 

  • Doval L, Skreta V (2020) Mechanism design with limited commitment. arXiv preprint arXiv:1811.03579

  • Jun BH, Wolfstetter EG (2014) Security bid auctions for agency contracts. Rev Econ Design 18:289–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogan S, Morgan J (2010) Securities auctions under moral hazard: an experimental study. Rev Financ 14:477–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu T, Bernhardt D (2021) Rent extraction with securities plus cash. J Financ (Forthcoming)

  • Liu T (2016) Optimal equity auctions with heterogeneous bidders. J Econ Theory 166:94–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu T, Bernhardt D (2019) Optimal equity auctions with two-dimensional types. J Econ Theory 184:104913

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P, Segal I (2002) Envelope theorems for arbitrary choice sets. Econometrica 70:583–601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R (1981) Optimal auction design. Math Oper Res 6:58–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan MH, Sappington DEM (1988) Optimal contracts with public ex post information. J Econ Theory 45:189–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skrzypacz A (2013) Auctions with contingent payments—an overview. Int J Ind Organ 31:666–675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun W, Wang D, Zhang Y (2018) Optimal profit sharing mechanisms with type-dependent outside options. J Math Econ 75:57–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dazhong Wang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank the editor Francois Maniquet, anonymous associate editor and referee, Bin Chen, Stephen Chiu, Maria Goltsman, Wei He, Mingshi Kang, Tingjun Liu, Charles Zheng and Kun Zhu for helpful comments. All errors are our own. Wang gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Youth Program of National Science Foundation of China (72003207), and Youth Fund Project of Humanities and Social Sciences Research of Ministry of Education of China (19YJC790129). Wang also thanks the hospitality of the Waseda Institute for Advanced Study during his visit.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

First show “only if.” For any feasible revenue-sharing mechanism \((q,e, s) \in {\mathcal {M}}\), incentive compatibility implies that \(Q_i(\theta _i)\) is nondecreasing. By the general envelope theorem (Milgrom and Segal 2002), incentive compatibility also implies

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(\theta _i)= \alpha _i(\theta _i)\theta _i-Q_i(\theta _i)k =\pi _i({\underline{\theta }}) + \int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\alpha _i(\tau )d\tau . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Following Liu (2016), dividing (15) by \(\theta _i^2\) and integrating both sides yield

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{\alpha _i(\theta ) }{\theta }d\theta - \int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{Q_i(\theta )k }{\theta ^2}d\theta =\int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }}) }{\theta ^2}d\theta +\int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{ \int ^{\theta }_{{\underline{\theta }}}\alpha _i(\tau )d\tau }{\theta ^2}d\theta , \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

then we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{Q_i(\theta )k }{\theta ^2}d\theta = \frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})}{\theta _i} - \frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})}{{\underline{\theta }}} +\frac{\int ^{\theta _i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\alpha _i(\tau )d\tau }{\theta _i}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Substituting \(\int ^{\theta _i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\alpha _i(\tau )d\tau\) from (15) into (16) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(\theta _i)&= \frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})\theta _i}{{\underline{\theta }}} +k\theta _i\int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{Q_i(\theta )}{\theta ^2}d\theta . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(17)

Furthermore, individual rationality requires \(\pi _i({\underline{\theta }}) \ge 0\) for all i.

Now prove “if.” For any \(\theta _i, \theta '_i \in [{\underline{\theta }}, {\overline{\theta }}]\), if \(Q_i(\theta _i)\) is nondecreasing, then

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\pi _i(\theta _i) -( \alpha _i( \theta '_i)\theta _i-Q_i( \theta '_i)k) \\ & = \theta _i\left( \frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})}{{\underline{\theta }}}+\int ^{{\theta }_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{Q_i(\theta )k }{\theta ^2}d\theta \right) - {\theta }_i\left( \frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})}{{\underline{\theta }}} +\int ^{{ \theta }'_i}_{{\underline{\theta }}}\frac{Q_i(\theta )k }{\theta ^2}d\theta +\frac{Q_i(\theta '_i)k}{\theta _i'}\right) +Q_i( \theta '_i)k\\ & = -\theta _i\int ^{\theta '_i}_{{\theta }_i}\frac{Q_i(\theta )k }{\theta ^2}d\theta +\left( \frac{1}{\theta _i}-\frac{1}{\theta '_i}\right) {\theta }_iQ_i( \theta '_i)k\\ \ge&-\theta _iQ_i(\theta '_i)\int ^{\theta '_i}_{{\theta }_i}\frac{k }{\theta ^2}d\theta +\left( \frac{1}{\theta _i}-\frac{1}{\theta '_i}\right) {\theta }_iQ_i( \theta '_i)k\\ & = 0. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

This implies that the revenue-sharing mechanism (qes) is incentive compatible. If \(\pi _i({\underline{\theta }}) \ge 0\), then \(\frac{\pi _i(\theta _i)}{\theta _i} > \frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})}{{\underline{\theta }}}\ge 0\), and thus \(\pi _i(\theta _i) >0\) for all \(\theta _i > {\underline{\theta }}\). \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 2

Given that

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} J^*(\theta _i)&= \frac{\theta _i^2}{2 \uplambda }-\frac{k }{\theta _i}\cdot \frac{1-F(\theta _i)}{f(\theta _i)}\cdot \frac{\int ^{{\overline{\theta }}}_{{\theta }_i}\theta f(\theta ) d\theta }{\theta _i [1-F(\theta _i)]} - k \\&= \frac{\theta _i^2}{2 \uplambda }-\frac{k }{\theta _i}\cdot \frac{1-F(\theta _i)}{f(\theta _i)}\Big \{1 + \frac{\int ^{{\overline{\theta }}}_{{\theta }_i}[1- F(\theta )]d\theta }{\theta _i [1-F(\theta _i)]} \Big \} - k. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(18)

The log-concavity of density f implies the log-concavity of \(1- F(\theta )\) and \(\int _{\theta }^{{\overline{\theta }}}1-F(t)dt\), which further implies that the hazard rate \(\frac{f(\theta )}{1-F(\theta )}\) and \(\frac{1-F(\theta )}{\int _{\theta }^{{\overline{\theta }}}[1 - F(t)]dt}\) are both increasing in \(\theta\) (see, Bagnoli and Bergstrom 2005). Therefore, \(J^*(\theta )\) is strictly increasing over \([{\underline{\theta }}, {\overline{\theta }}]\). \(\square\)

Proof of Theorem 1

We first consider a relaxed problem as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \max _{(q,s)}\;\;\;&\int _{{\varvec{\theta }}}\sum _{i=1}^nq_i({\varvec{\theta }})J^*(\theta _i)f({\varvec{\theta }})d{\varvec{\theta }} -\sum _{i=1}^n\frac{\pi _i({\underline{\theta }}){\mathbb {E}}[\theta _i]}{{\underline{\theta }}},\\ s.t. \;\;&\pi _i({\underline{\theta }}) \ge 0, \;\; \forall i \in N. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

By Lemma 2, a revenue-sharing mechanism \((q^*,e^*, s^*)\) maximizes the seller’s expected payoff if and only if \(\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})=0\) for each bidder i, and the associated optimal winning rule is

$$\begin{aligned} q_i^*({\varvec{\theta }})={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 1&{} \;\text {if}\; \theta _i > \max \{\max _{j\ne i}{\varvec{\theta }}_{-i}, \theta _r\}\\ 0 &{}\;\text {otherwise}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(19)

for all i and \({\varvec{\theta }}\). Ties are randomly broken. As a result, bidder i’s expected winning probability

$$\begin{aligned} Q^*_i(\theta _i)= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} G(\theta _i)&{} \;\text {if}\; \theta _i \ge \theta _r\\ 0 &{}\;\text {otherwise} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

is monotonic. Therefore, the allocation rule \(q^*\) is also optimal for the seller’s original program (P). The optimal sharing rule \(s^*\) is generally not unique, and can be constructed by Condition IC2 and \(\pi _i({\underline{\theta }})=0\) for all i. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 1 and Corollary 1

We first show the monotonicity and upper-boundedness of \(\xi\). We see that \(\xi (\theta )\) is strictly increasing over \([\theta _r,{\overline{\theta }}]\), as for each \(\theta \in (\theta _r,{\overline{\theta }})\),

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \xi '(\theta ) & = \frac{\uplambda k}{\theta ^3}\Big [\Big ( \frac{\theta ^2 g(\theta )}{G^2(\theta )} + \frac{\theta }{G(\theta )}\Big )\int _{\theta _r}^{\theta }\frac{G(\tau )}{\tau ^2}d\tau + 1 \Big ]\\ >&0. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

In addition, the upper-boundedness is obviously satisfied, since \(\xi (\theta ) =1-\frac{\uplambda k}{\theta ^2}-\frac{\uplambda k}{G(\theta )\theta }\int _{\theta _r}^{\theta }\frac{G(\tau )}{\tau ^2}d\tau < 1\) for all \(\theta \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}]\).

We then show that the first-price share auction with the reserve share \(s_r\) and the effort commitment scheme \(e^{I}\) admits a symmetric bidding equilibrium \((\beta ^I, \ldots , \beta ^I)\), in which \(\beta ^I\) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \beta ^{I}(\theta )={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \xi (\theta )&{} \;\;\text {if}\; \theta \ge \theta _r \\ \text {non-participation} &{}\;\;\text {otherwise}. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

Given the other bidders following the bidding strategy \(\beta ^{I}\), each bidder i with type \(\theta _i\) obtains an expected winning probability given by

$$\begin{aligned} Q^{I}(b) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} G(\beta ^{I-1}(b)) &{} \; \text {if}\;\; b\in [s_r, \xi ({\overline{\theta }}] \\ 1 &{} \; \text {if} \;b \in (\xi ({\overline{\theta }}), 1]\\ 0 &{} \; \text {if} \; b = \text {non-participation}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

and earns an expected payoff \(\pi ^{I}(b, \theta _i)\) given by

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^{I}(b,\theta _i)= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} G\big (\xi ^{-1}(b)\big )[ \frac{(1-b)\theta _i\xi ^{-1}(b)}{\uplambda }-k] &{}\;\text {if} \; b \in [s_r, \xi ({\overline{\theta }})]\\ \frac{(1-b)\theta _i{\overline{\theta }}}{\uplambda }-k &{} \;\text {if} \; b \in [\xi ({\overline{\theta }}), 1]\\ 0, &{} \;\text {if}\; b = \text {non-participation} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(20)

from bidding \(b \in \{\beta ^{I}(\theta )| \theta \in [{\underline{\theta }}, {\overline{\theta }}]\}\). By the expression of \(\xi\), we then see that following the bidding strategy \(\beta ^I\) yields bidder i a winning probability

$$\begin{aligned} Q^{I}(\beta ^{I}(\theta _i)) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} G(\theta _i) &{} \; \text {if}\;\; \theta _i \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}] \\ 0 &{} \; \text {otherwise}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

which is weakly increasing in \(\theta _i\), and an expected payoff

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^{I}(\beta ^{I}(\theta _i), \theta _i)= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} k \theta _i \int _{\theta _r}^{\theta _i}\frac{G(\theta )}{\theta ^2}d\theta &{} \;\text {if} \; \theta _i \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}]\\ 0 &{} \;\text {otherwise}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

if the other bidders adopt the same bidding strategy. By the revelation principle and Lemma 1, it holds that

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^{I}(\beta ^{I}(\theta _i), \theta _i) \ge \pi _i^{I}(b,\theta _i), \end{aligned}$$

for all \(b \in \big \{\beta ^{I}(\theta )| \theta \in [{\underline{\theta }}, {\overline{\theta }}]/\{\theta _i\}\big \}\); that is, bidder i with type \(\theta _i\) has no incentive to deviate from bidding \(\beta ^{I}(\theta _i)\) to other types’ bids specified by the strategy \(\beta ^{I}\). Moreover, we have that

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^{I}(\beta ^{I}(\theta _i), \theta _i) \ge \pi _i^{I}(\beta ^{I}({\overline{\theta }}),\theta _i) > \pi _i^{I}(b,\theta _i) \end{aligned}$$

for all \(\theta _i\) and all \(b \in (\beta ^{I}({\overline{\theta }}), 1]\). Therefore, the strategy profile \((\beta ^I, \ldots , \beta ^{I})\) is a symmetric bidding equilibrium of the first-price share auction with the reserve price \(s_r\) and the effort commitment scheme \(e^{I}\). In this equilibrium, the bidder with the highest type wins, provided that it is not less than the threshold type \(\theta _r\), and each bidder i earns an expected equilibrium payoff that is the same as that in in the optimal mechanism \((q^*, e^*, s^*)\). Hence, we conclude that the proposed first-price share auction can implement the optimal revenue-sharing mechanism. \(\square\)

The derivation of equation (12). Suppose that the second-price share auction with the reserve share \(s_r\) and an appropriate effort commitment scheme \(e^{II}\) can implement the optimal mechanism, then it should admit a symmetric bidding equilibrium \((\beta ^{II}, \ldots , \beta ^{II})\), in which participating bidders follow a strictly increasing bidding strategy \(\gamma\). Accordingly, the effort commitment scheme satisfies \(e^{II}(b_w)=\frac{\gamma ^{-1}(b_w)}{\uplambda }\) for all \(b_w\in \{ \gamma (\theta )| \theta \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}] \}\). Bidding a share \(b \in \{ \gamma (\theta )| \theta \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}]\) yields bidder i with type \(\theta _i\) an expected payoff \(\pi ^{II}(b,\theta _i)\) given by

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^{II}(b,\theta _i)= \Big [G(\theta _r)(1-s_r)+\int _{\theta _r}^{\gamma ^{-1}(b)}(1-\gamma (\theta )) dG(\theta )\Big ]\cdot \frac{\gamma ^{-1}(b)\theta _i}{\uplambda }- k G(\gamma ^{-1}(b)). \end{aligned}$$

Furthermore, the equilibrium payoff of bidder i with type \(\theta _i\in [\theta _r,\overline{\theta }]\) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i^{II}(\gamma (\theta _i), \theta _i)& = \Big [G(\theta _r)(1-s_r) + \int _{\theta _r}^{\theta _i} \big (1-\gamma (\tau )) dG(\tau )\Big ]\frac{\theta _i^2}{\uplambda }- G(\theta _i)k\\ & = k \theta _i \int _{ \theta _r}^{\theta _i}\frac{ G(\tau )}{\tau ^2} d\tau \\ & = \pi _i^{I}(\xi (\theta _i),\theta _i) \\ & = G(\theta _i)\big [(1-\xi (\theta _i))\frac{\theta _i^2}{\uplambda } - k\big ], \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where the second equality holds from the general envelope theorem (Milgrom and Segal 2002) and the zero-payoff argument for the threshold type \(\theta _r\), and the third equality is obtained from Eq. (20). From Eq. (21), the expression of \(\gamma\) can be derived out as

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \gamma (\theta )&=1-\frac{\uplambda k}{\theta ^2}+\frac{\uplambda k}{\theta ^2 g(\theta )}\left[ \frac{G(\theta )}{\theta }+\int _{ \theta _r}^{\theta } \frac{G(\tau )}{\tau ^2}d\tau \right] \\&= \xi (\theta ) + \frac{G(\theta )}{g(\theta )}\xi '(\theta ). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Note that the equilibrium bid for the threshold type may be higher than the reserve share, as \(\lim \nolimits _{\theta \rightarrow \theta _r}\gamma (\theta )=1-\frac{\uplambda k}{\theta ^2}+\frac{\uplambda k}{\theta ^2 g(\theta )}\frac{G(\theta _r)}{\theta _r}> s_r\). Hence, the prescribed equilibrium bidding strategy \(\beta ^{II}\) satisfies:

$$\begin{aligned} \beta ^{II}(\theta )={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} b_r \in [s_r, \gamma (\theta _r)]&{} \;\;\text {if}\; \theta = \theta _r\\ \gamma (\theta )&{} \;\;\text {if}\; \theta > \theta _r \\ \text {non-participation} &{}\;\;\text {otherwise}. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Proof of Proposition 2

The proof proceeds in two steps.

Step 1: We show that \(\beta ^{12}\) is a weakly dominant strategy for each bidder under the share auction \({\mathcal {A}}^{12}\). Fix a bidder i. Let \(b_{(1,-i)}\) denote the highest bid of the bidders other than i. If no other bidder participates, set \(b_{(1,-i)} = s_r\). Bidding \(b_i\) yields bidder i with \(\theta _i\) a payoff given by

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 0 &\text {if} \;\; b_i < b_{(1, -i)}\\ \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})(1-b_i)}\cdot e^{12}(b_i) -k & \text {if} \;\;b_i> b_{(1, -i)} \\ \frac{1}{1 + m(b_{(1,-i)})}\big (\theta _i\cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})(1-b_i)}\cdot e^{12}(b_i) -k\big ) & \text {if} \;\;b_i = b_{(1, -i)}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

where \(m(b_{(1,-i)}) = |\{j \ne i|b_j = b_{(1, -i)}\}| \ge 1\) is the cardinality of the set of bidder i’s opponents with the highest bid.

It holds that

$$\begin{aligned} \sqrt{(1-b_i)} e^{12}(b_i) {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} = \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} &{}\text {if} \;\; b_i \in [s_r, \beta ^{12}(\overline{\theta })]\\ < \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} &{}\text {if} \;\;b_i \in (\beta ^{12}(\overline{\theta }),1]. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(24)

We then claim that for \(\theta _i \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}]\), bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\) weakly dominates submitting any other bid \(b_i\in [s_r, 1]\) and not participating. To prove it, we consider three cases as follows.

Case 1: \(b_i>\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\). Bidding \(b_i\) is weakly dominated by bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\), since:

(i) If \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)<b_{(1, -i)}< b_i\), then

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i)&=\theta _i \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})(1-b_i)}\cdot e^{12}(b_i) -k\\&\le \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k \\&<0\\&=\pi _i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i), \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

where the first inequality is due to Condition (24), which applies to (i), (ii), (iv) and (v) in this case.

(ii) If \(b_{(1, -i)}= b_i\), then

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i)&\le \frac{1}{1 + m(b_{(1,-i)})}\left( \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k\right) \\&<0\\&=\pi ^{12}_i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1,-i)}; \theta _i). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

(iii) If \(b_{(1, -i)}> b_i\), he loses and obtains the same zero payoff as bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\).

(iv) If \(b_{(1, -i)} < \beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\), then

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i) \le&\theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k \\ & = \pi _i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

(v) If \(b_{(1,-i)} = \beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\), his payoff is

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i) \le&\theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k \\ & = 0\\ & = \pi _i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Case 2: \(b_i<\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\). Bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\) is weakly better than bidding \(b_i\), since:

(i) If \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\ge b_{(1, -i)}>b_i\), then bidder i loses and obtains zero payoff that is worse off than bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\), i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i)&=0\\&<\theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k\\&=\pi _i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

(ii) If \(b_{(1, -i)}>\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\), then bidder i loses and obtains the same zero payoff as bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\).

(iii) If \(b_{(1, -i)}= b_i\), then bidder i obtains payoff

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i)&=\frac{1}{1 + m(b_{(1,-i)})}\left( \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k\right) \\&< \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k\\&=\pi _i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

(iv) If \(b_{(1, -i)}<b_i\), then bidder i obtains the same payoff as bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\), i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i(b_i, b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i) & = \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1- b_{(1, -i)})} -k \\ & = \pi _i(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i), b_{(1, -i)};\theta _i). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Case 3: Non-participation. Obviously, not participating that yields zero payoff is weakly dominated by \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\).

Consequently, for type \(\theta _i \in [\theta _r, {\overline{\theta }}]\), bidding \(\beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\) is weakly better than submitting any other bid \(b_i \ne \beta ^{12}(\theta _i)\) and not participating.

In addition, we have that for \(\theta _i \in [{\underline{\theta }}, \theta _r)\), participating and making a bid \(b_i \in [s_r, 1]\) yields him a non-positive payoff upon winning, since

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _i\sqrt{(1- b_{(1,-i)})(1-b_i)}e(b_i) - k \le \theta _i \cdot \sqrt{\frac{k}{\uplambda }} \cdot \sqrt{(1 - b_{(1,-i)})} -k \le \left( \frac{\theta _i}{\theta _r}-1\right) \cdot k <0. \end{aligned}$$

The above demonstration shows that \(\beta ^{12}\) is a weakly dominant strategy for each bidder under the first-second share auction with reserve price \(s_r\) and effort exertion \(e^{12}\).

Step 2: we consider the implementation. If all bidders adopt the weakly dominant strategy \(\beta ^{12}\), then the winning bidder if there is any is the bidder with the highest type (denoted by \(\theta _w\)), which is not less than \(\theta _r\), and the seller’s effort exertion equals to \(\frac{\theta _w}{\uplambda }\). Recall that the seller’s expected payoff in the optimal mechanism is determined by the optimal allocation rule and the first-best effort commitment with respect to the winner’s type (see Theorem 1). We then conclude that the proposed share auction \({\mathcal {A}}^{12}\) can implement the optimal mechanism in dominant strategy. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, X., Li, S. & Wang, D. Optimal revenue-sharing mechanisms with seller commitment to ex-post effort. Soc Choice Welf 58, 141–159 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01351-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01351-w

Navigation