1 Introduction

Justas the PR China took its first steps towards economic reforms and modernization in the 1970s, a study on the Chinese labor market conjectured that ”the growth rate of non-agricultural employment is a crucial determinant of China’s future labour scene” as unemployment was a real danger for developing economies (Rawski 1979). The hypothesis certainly proved correct, but for reasons different from those the author imagined. The role of agriculture in the Chinese economy declined rapidly, its employment share falling below 25% of the labor force by 2014 while its contribution to value added fell from a third in the 1970s to below 10% in 2014 (see Fig. 1). This was accompanied by a period of unprecedented growth, profound economic reorganization, and China’s rise into the group of technological advanced societies. For details on the reforms and the resulting changes in economics and policy, see, e.g. Brandt and Rawski (2008) and Fan et al. (2003). Unemployment was not a major concern, although large parts of the population moved to urban regions; the share of the industrial sector in the economy remained roughly constant in terms of output (value addedFootnote 1) while the service sector grew at the expense of the agricultural sector (Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Changes in value added shares by sectors (data from Holz (2006) until 1999, after that from WIOD). Period covered in our micro-data and sectoral data shaded

The details are more complicated, however. Growth of output and growth of employment differ significantly between sectors, labor productivities diverge, and unique dynamics emerge, setting the developing Chinese economy apart from the other extensively studied economies of developed countries. What is more, sectors are also not homogeneous entities but rich ecosystems of a variety of firms the characteristics of and growth dynamics of which differ widely, although firm-level variables can be recovered by regular distributional models with great accuracy. The present paper aims to shed light on the details of this structural change.

We propose a multi-level framework of structural change that connects sectoral level and firm-level, the two levels on which we have empirical data. The framework is stated in equation form, it is testable and it will be used for the econometric analysis in Section 5. Further, we investigate whether a variety of correlation laws known from the literature as Fabricant’s laws (Fabricant 1942; Scott 1991; Metcalfe et al. 2006) hold at the sectoral and at the micro-level. Assessing whether empirical laws hold across multiple levels of aggregation allows us to understand where the regularities originate; whether they are universal properties of a self-organizing system, that might hold at every level, or emergent patterns, that arise at a specific level.

If the economy is characterized by fractal, self-similar structures, we might assume that empirical observations at aggregated levels are mirrored in more detailed data, at the micro-level. Scaling relationships, for which this is the case, have indeed been found in many economic phenomena, from financial market time series (Marsili et al. 2002) to price developments (Farmer and Lafond 2016) to economic geography (Bustos et al. 2012; Haldane 2019) to industrial organization and firm-level data (Schwarzkopf et al. 2010). While this view is typical for a complex systems perspective in economics, Metcalfe et al. (2006), writing from an evolutionary economic perspective, appear to consider a similar view when forging their empirical findings into a general model of structural change and economic growth. Martin and Sunley (2007) offer a comprehensive overview over the complex systems perspective and potential synergies to evolutionary economics. Of course, scaling laws do not have to extend to the micro-level. Sometimes empirical laws emerge from phenomena at intermediate levels, in which case the characterization of these intermediate levels and the associated phenomena are of particular interest.

While we can mostly confirm these laws at the sectoral level, we will show that they do, in fact, fall apart at the micro-level. We will characterize the properties and the dynamic processes at work in this multi-level system of structural change. Further, we address some related questions such as the nature of distributions of variables at the firm level and the autocorrelation and dispersion of the sectoral composition of the Chinese economy. We also show the development of some of the larger sectors in detail and offer some policy implications in the context of development economics, evolutionary economics, and industrial organization.

China’s structural reforms were clearly a driving factor in China’s structural change. There were extensive privatization efforts, private enterprises were legalized and encouraged, rural industry was privatized, and state-owned enterprises (SOEs) were reformed. The PR China also increasingly encouraged foreign investments starting in the late 1970s, first promoting joint venture type ownership structures before allowing more direct foreign investments in Special Economic Zones, several of which were established starting in the 1980s. In 1988, the constitution was revised to legalize the private sector; private enterprises were now considered to be complementary to the socialist economy. Amendments in 1999 and 2004 further protected and encouraged private entrepreneurship and strengthened the private sector. Significant reforms of SOEs and TVEs (Township and Village Enterprises) were undertaken starting in the 1990s. Efforts were also made to stimulate innovation and to bolster R&D (Hu and Jefferson 2008); this included tax incentives and grants, improved formal procedures and legal framework in economic policy, enterprise law and patenting, consolidation and privatization of research institutes as well as some focused public research programs in basic and high-tech research (such as Program 863 and Program 973). There was also a focus on modernization of manufacturing sectors that aided productivity growth in this field (Brondino 2019).

However, China’s development and transformation to a market economy was in many ways not spontaneous or unorganized, different perhaps from other transformation economies in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. There was structural change towards a market oriented system, but the transformation was government-organized and the economy remains partly under the control of the planned economic system (Shen et al. 2019). For example, early reforms in the 1970s and 1980s encouraged local management and stakeholders to assume a more active role in defining the firms’ objectives and strategy, first in agricultural TVEs, later in other SOEs (Naughton 2008).Footnote 2 Before 1998, the ownership type of the firms was rarely changed and state ownership was typically retained. The more radical and substantial SOEs reform in 1998 allowed privatizing SOEs and layoffs of substantial numbers of employees. TVEs were subject to a similar reform; the TVEs share of China’s GDP dropped from 65.1% in 1993 to 9.1% in 2000.

This had multiple obvious effects for the industry structure: Large SOEs quickly lost ground, a multitude of private start-ups were established and the firm population became much younger across the board (see Section 4 and in particular Fig. 8). The layoffs likely also fueled the rise of the services sector the employment share of which grew from 30% in 2000 to 45% in 2014.

China’s entry into the WTO in 2001 brought increased international integration of the Chinese economy, reduced tariff uncertainty, and fueled productivity growth of especially those regions and sectors with more reliance on exports and exposure to foreign investment (Erten and Leight 2019; Brandt et al. 2017). Unlike most countries, China also increasingly relies on domestic inputs for exportation, despite its deepening global engagement (Kee and Tang 2016).

Finally, a four trillion Yuan fiscal stimulus program in the wake of the financial crisis in 2008, while averting larger fallouts of the crisis, may have extended the life-span of many struggling firms, SOEs in particular (Yan 2020).

It is to be expected that these processes would have had an impact on the dynamics of structural change at various levels. The fact that economic growth was rapid in China in the 1990s and 2000s, reaching growth rates around 10%, probably accelerated the structural change brought about by modernization and the reforms towards a market economy. At the same time, the Chinese case is unique in that detailed micro-level data are available that permit us to investigate structural change not just at the sectoral but also at the firm level (see Section 4).

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews previous literature contributions, Section 3 offers some considerations on modeling of structural change at the sectoral and the micro-level with a focus on empirical applicability. Section 4 discusses empirical regularities, Section 5 fits some of the models introduced in Section 3. Section 6 concludes.

2 Literature review: Structural change in China and the world

Economists and statisticians first started to categorize economic activity in sectors of different characteristics in the last years of the 19th century. Year-books in Australia and New Zealand began distinguishing primary - agricultural, pastoral, mineral production - and secondary - derived manufacturing - sectors, later adding a tertiary sector for services; from there the terms spread through the commonwealths and around the world (Fisher 1939). Other scholars had, at the time already recognized that parts of the economy and of the industry may be subject to different fluctuations (Robertson 1915) and different dynamics (involving, e.g., decreasing and increasing returns (Clapham 1922)). However, it was Fabricant (1942), who offered the first detailed study covering 50 industry sectors in the US over a period of 40 years.

The rise and fall of industrial and sectoral shares indicate fundamental structural change in the long-term economic growth (Baumol 1967; Maddison 1983), with industrialization, urbanization, and technological change being crucial factors in structural change (Syrquin 1988). Maintaining high rates of economic growth has been linked to keeping the sectoral composition balanced (Chenery and Syrquin 1950; Rostow 1960).

2.1 Regularities

Fabricant (1942) identified a variety of correlation laws in sectoral accounts:

  • positive correlation of output growth and labor productivity growth,

  • negative correlation of output growth and growth of wage bill per output,

  • positive correlation of output growth and capital growth,

  • positive correlation of output growth and employment growth,

  • positive correlation of value added per output growth and wage growth,

  • positive correlation of value added per output and output price,

  • positive correlation of output growth and capital intensity growth,

  • negative correlation of the wage bill per unit of output and labor productivity,

  • negative correlation of value added growth and output price growth.

Other scholars have attempted to confirm and extend the correlation laws (Scott 1991). The first law, correlation of output and productivity growth, corresponds to Verdoorn’s law and has sparked discussions on the causality behind this relation (cf. Scott (1991)) while the other laws were less influential in the literature. Besides genuine increase in efficiency the correspondence may be due to either labor and capital reallocation or due to characteristics of the sector. Such characteristics may involve different rates of technological change, economies of scale, or other aspects.

2.2 Productivity growth and structural change

General equilibrium approaches in neoclassical or neo-Keynesian tradition have generally favored the factor re-allocation explanation. TFP growth rates across industrial sectors are conjectured to function as a valid predictors of labor moving among sectors. Employment share drops in different rates among the sectors; specifically, labor tends to move away from technology intensive sectors and towards sectors with low growth (Ngai and Pissarides 2007).

Evolutionary scholars, on the other hand, often view sectors as interdependent systems with specific characteristics (Nelson and Winter 1975; Montobbio 2002). Fagerberg (2000), for instance, argues that structural change on average has not been conducive to productivity growth, which instead may be determined by technological change. Metcalfe et al. (2006) offer an extensive analysis of structural change and economic growth which they then try to relate back to the macroeconomic level via income and demand.Footnote 3 Crucially, Metcalfe et al. show that there is a wide variety of compositions of growth rates of employment on the one hand and output on the other, which they find to be correlated although the autocorrelations decay with the time lag.

Another strand of literature is devoted to the investigation of the sources of innovation that drives technological change and arguably, on occasion, structural change. Schumpeter (1943 [2003]) placed the desire to create temporary competitive advantages at the centre of entrepreneurship. Later evolutionary thinkers (Nelson and Winter 1982) extended this to formal and stochastic models with innovative research and imitation creating a complex dynamic of cutting-edge technological progress and the diffusion of technologies to the rest of the industry. This was found to be able to conveniently recover business cycles (Silverberg and Lehnert 1993) and highly skewed firm size distributions (Kwaśnicki 1998) in simulation models.Footnote 4

Freeman and Perez (1988) conjectured technological paradigms to be at the centre of such long-wave processes. This would imply long periods of relative structural stability interspersed by periods of relatively rapid replacement of the technological infrastructure. While structural change is not necessarily bound to technological change, an interaction between these processes may be assumed. Saviotti and Pyka (2013) model industry sector life cycles and economic development such that the number of industry sectors increases when earlier sectors are sufficiently developed to support the emergence of new ones.

2.3 The transformation economy and economic development in China

A substantial literature has addressed productivity growth in China. While productivity growth has implications for structural change, most analyses that consider this question are limited to the classical three-sector model (Fisher 1935; Clark 1967). Few contributions attempt to investigate structural change from a micro-perspective. Recent examples include (Hsieh and Klenow 2009; Brandt et al. 2012; Ding et al. 2016), where firm level data is applied to calculate total factor productivity (TFP).

Another branch of literature (Duschl and Peng 2015; Yu et al. 2015) investigates the distribution of growth rates in China (computed using value added growth or sales growth) in the tradition of Bottazzi and Secchi’s analysis (Bottazzi and Secchi 2006; 2011) where the distribution is conjectured to belong to the family of Asymmetric Exponential Power (AEP) distributions. However, there is also strong evidence that both growth rates and many other quantities at the firm level are heavy-tailed (Axtell 2001; Heinrich and Dai 2016; Yang et al. 2019; Heinrich et al. 2020), such that the tails could be severely underestimated by AEP fits.

What is not in doubt is that China experienced impressive growth accompanied by significant increases in productivity. This mirrors the development in other developing countries.

Fan et al. (2003) construct a multi-sector model to investigate how production factors reallocate among urban industry, urban services, agriculture, and rural enterprises in China. They find that labor movements from low-productivity sectors to high-productivity sectors have significantly contributed to China’s structural change. Dong and Xu (2009) find that China experienced a more synchronized pace of job destruction and creation, compared to the other transition economies while (Wang and Szirmai 2008) finds no regional divergence of productivity trends.

Two main points of contention in the literature on structural change in China are (1) if growth could have been even faster if resources were not misallocated and (2) which factors were driving the growth in output and the increase in labor productivity.

Question (1) is based on the conjecture that productivity dispersion indicates misallocation of resources, as there are evidently many firms in the same country and sector with widely different productivities. Should resources not be reallocated to the most productive firms, if the less productive ones refuse to learn and copy better technologies? And indeed, evidence for dispersion and thus misallocation is then found for China as well (Hsieh and Klenow 2009; Brandt et al. 2012; Song et al. 2011). What is more, standard measures of productivity dispersion (the variance, the Olley-Pakes gap, the inter-quantile range) may make it appear that dispersion is increasing over time. Would this not be bad, even if there was an unavoidable baseline misallocation due to bounded rationality? However, labor productivities (and total factor productivities, TFPs) follow heavy-tailed distributions, which makes these dispersion measures unreliable (Yang et al. 2019). Other dispersion measures, that are robust with respect to heavy tails, such as the scale parameter of Lévy alpha stable fits, show no sign of increasing, at least not relative to the median of the distribution (Yang et al. 2019; Heinrich et al. 2020).

No consensus has emerged with respect to the sources of productivity growth in China (question (2)). Yang and Lahr (2010) suggest that structural change is the primary reason for productivity growth. Nabar and Yan (2013) claim that the low labor productivity growth in services is a unique compared to other transformation economies. They suggest that credit and labor market frictions are the primary inhibiting reasons. Brandt et al. (2013) come to similar conclusions with respect to total factor productivity (TFP) growth in China and argue that labor mobility restrictions a distorted incentive structure are at fault. However, Brondino (2019), applying the ”growing subsystems” developed by Pasinetti (1988), argues that aggregate productivity growth in China in 1995-2002 was driven by technological progress rather than sectoral reallocation of labor. Wang and Szirmai (2008) find that shifts in firm ownership can explain a substantial part of the productivity growth after 1985. Reforms not only increased efficiency by encouraging private entrepreneurship, also SOEs exhibited significant productivity growth. Fu et al. (2008) demonstrate that some reforms in SOEs have improved SOEs’ productivity level during the period of 1986-2003 even when taking macroeconomic growth into account. Especially corporate governance reforms have led SOEs to make improvements in innovation, technological change and adoption of new technologies. Dekle and Vandenbroucke (2012) argue that tax reduction also helped labor mobility for productivity growth. Institutional frictions may also have jeopardized productivity growth. Chen et al. (2011) find that structural change does not significantly contribute the continuing TFP growth since 2001, because the privileges state-owned institutions enjoy discouraged private capital.

3 Modelling structural change at multiple levels

With the period 1998-2014, we are investigating an interesting case involving both economic development (China still being a developing country), technological change, and transformation to a market economy. If we aim to address questions of deep structural change in this context, we must be able to relate multiple dimensions - employment, output, and productivity - of economic structure as well as multiple levels - the sectoral and the firm level. In the present section, we offer some considerations in this regard, starting with a sector level model (Section 3.1), before moving to the firm-level (Section 3.2) and adding some technical considerations regarding variable densities at the firm level (Section 3.3).

3.1 Sector-level dynamics

We aim to study structural change at both the sectoral level and the firm-level and will for this start with a framework inspired by Metcalfe et al. (2006)

Labor productivity Qt is the quotient of output Yt and employment Lt at time t,

$$Q_{t} = Y_{t}/L_{t}.$$

Let disaggregated - sectoral and firm-level - quantities be denoted by lower case letters, labor productivity qt, value added yt and employment lt. We will omit time index t for now. Hence, for sector k,

$$\begin{array}{r l} q_{k} &= y_{k}/l_{k} \\ &= \frac{s_{Y,k} Y}{s_{L,k}L} \end{array}$$

where sY,k is the value added share of sector k and sL,k is its employment share. For growth rates denoted as \(\dot {Q}\), \(\dot {Y}\), \(\dot {L}\), etc., and using the approximation

$$ \log\left( \frac{x_{t+1}}{x_{t}}\right)\approx\frac{x_{t+1}-x_{t}}{x_{t}} $$
(1)

that holds in the vicinity of zero \(\left (\frac {x_{t+1}-x_{t}}{x_{t}}\approx 0\right )\), we have approximately

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{Q} &=& \dot{Y} - \dot{L}\\ \dot{q_{k}} &=& \dot{s_{Y,k}} - \dot{s_{L,k}} + \dot{Y} - \dot{L}\\ \dot{q_{k}} - \dot{Q} &=& \dot{s_{Y,k}} - \dot{s_{L,k}}, \end{array} $$

where the left side has unit money per employee while the right-hand side terms are shares. The three elements can then be compared to one another by sectors. While two of the three terms could be statistically independent or could depend on one another in a relationship that could take any number of functional forms, Metcalfe et al. (2006) conjecture that there is a linear relationship between \(\dot {L}\) and \(\dot {Y}\) and similarly on disaggregated levels between \(\dot {l}\) and \(\dot {y}\), although they find wildly different slopes between 0.1 and 1.2.

While Metcalfe et al. (2006) have reasonably long data series with 39 observations each for the sectoral accounts of the United States, we have to work with much shorter time series of less than 15 years at the sectoral level and considerably less for the firm-level. The wide range of different coefficient values in Metcalfe et al. (2006) may also indicate that the relationship is, in fact, not linear. Further, and this is also true for Metcalfe et al. (2006) study, fitting along time series leads to resampling problems as growth rates can reasonably be assumed to be autocorrelated. We therefore choose to remain agnostic with regard to the connection of the two growth dimensions, employment and value added (as a proxy for output) growth. We will show the relationships that we find between these variables and others and report correlation coefficients.

3.2 Relating sector- and firm-level dynamics

We now move on to the micro-level. Let yi,t and li,t denote value added and employment in firm i, which belongs to sector k, at time t. Let sY,i,t be the share of the firm in the economy’s total value added (hence, output), while sL,i,t is the firm’s share in total employment. It is not convenient to take the same approach following Metcalfe et al. (2006) as for the sector above, not least because output or value added can be negative at the firm level. This brings the singularity of the growth rates around level zero into the domain, which makes it inconvenient and counter-intuitive to work with growth rate. Since the approximation (1) holds only in the vicinity of zero and the expression will be arbitrarily far away from zero in the vicinity of the singularity at xt = 0, the above approximation will also not hold any longer.

We are now interested in the dynamic development of these variables. Since we are agnostic with respect to the relation between the variables, employment and value added, and the respective growth rates, we will in the following use the abstract term xi,t. x stands for either employment or value added, but can also be applied to other accounts. We will use dxi,t = xi,txi,t− 1 for the first difference, \(\dot {x_{i,t}}=dx_{i,t}/x_{i,t-1}\) for the growth rate, \(X_{t}={\sum }_{j} x_{j,t}\) for the economy’s total, \(\dot {X_{t}}\) for the growth of the economy total, si,t = xi,t/Xt for the share in the economy’s total, dsi,t for the first difference of the share, and \(\dot {s_{i,t}}\) for the growth of the share.

Consider the standard replicator equation (Nowak 2006; Mulder et al. 2001)

$$ ds_{i,t}/dt=s_{i,t}\left( f_{i,t}-\phi_{t}\right) $$
(2)

where fi,t is the fitness of i at time t and \(\phi _{t}={\sum }_{j} s_{j,t} f_{j}\) is the economy average of the fitness term. The dynamical system given by the shares s and fitnesses f for all firms has the desirable characteristic that the dynamic it defines leads to shares that always sum to 100%. Fitness is, however, an abstract quantity that denotes the firm’s evolutionary success in terms of realized growth in variable x. Since relative fitness (fi,tϕt) is not directly observable, this is simply an identity stating that relative fitness is equal to the growth rate

$$ \frac{ds_{i,t}/dt}{s_{i,t}}=\left( f_{i,t}-\phi_{t}\right). $$
(3)

In theoretical models (e.g., those in Nelson and Winter (1982)), it can be identified with existing variables that may be exposed in the model, such as capabilities of the firm, market share, or productivity. The model can also be empirically fitted to understand which quantities impact it.

The same dynamical system can equally be applied to the sector shares instead of the firm shares:

$$ ds_{k,t}/dt=s_{k,t}\left( f_{k,t}-\phi_{t}\right). $$
(4)

Further, the replicator system can equivalently be written in terms of absolutes x instead of shares s:

$$ dx_{k,t}/dt= X_{t}s_{k,t}\left( f_{k,t}-\phi_{t}\right) + s_{k,t}\left( X_{t}-X_{t-1}\right) $$
(5)

where the first term simply scales the dynamics of the sectoral shares to the macro-level quantity Xt and the second term accounts for the growth of the macro level quantity. This reduces to the approximationFootnote 5

$$ dx_{k,t}/dt=X_{t}s_{k,t}\left( \dot{X_{t}} + f_{k,t}-\phi_{t}\right) $$
(6)

which corresponds to

$$ \frac{dx_{k,t}/dt}{X_{t}s_{k,t}}=\dot{x_{k,t}}=\dot{X_{t}} + \dot{s_{k,t}}. $$
(7)

With Eq. 7, we obtain the functional form of the replicator in absolute terms (i.e., growth of x rather than shares) as an additive combination of aggregate growth and dynamics of sectoral shares. Applying this equation equivalently to the firm level,Footnote 6 we obtain

$$ dx_{i,t}/dt=X_{t}s_{k,t}s_{i,t}\left( \dot{X_{t}} + \dot{s_{k,t}} + f_{i,t}-\phi_{k,t}\right) $$
(8)

and

$$ \frac{dx_{i,t}/dt}{X_{t}s_{k,t}s_{i,t}}=\dot{x_{i,t}}=\dot{X_{t}} + \dot{s_{k,t}} + \left( f_{i,t}-\phi_{k,t}\right). $$
(9)

While the anchoring of growth at different levels is useful, it should be noted that this is a very simple model and only a first approximation. In effect, the growth rates at higher levels are there as additive versions of capacity boundary terms. A standard equation with capacity boundary term (Nowak 2006; Heinrich 2017) could, for instance, take the form

$$ dx_{i,t}/dt=x_{i,t}\left( f_{i,t}-\phi_{k,t}\right)\left( 1-\frac{{\sum}_{i\in k}x_{i,t}}{z_{k}}\right) $$
(10)

where zk is the sectoral capacity boundary. We choose not to work with this form for the regressions below, since it is difficult to estimate capacity boundaries and since the multiplicative form introduces additional complications.Footnote 7

The functional form in Eq. 9 can be employed as a regression equation in Section 5 below, since we know \(\dot {x_{i,t}}\), \(\dot {X_{t}}\), and \(\dot {s_{k,t}}\) as well as several terms that can reasonably be assumed to be related to \(\left (f_{i,t}-\phi _{t}\right )\). We avoid relating the two absolute variables employment and value added as well as other quantities that are highly correlated with either (capital, wage bill, gross output, returns, revenue, etc., see Figs. 1119). Other variables such as labor productivity, labor productivity change, and firm age remain. Different combinations of these variables can be attempted. In cases in which capacity boundaries and other idiosyncratic effects dominate the growth rates of higher aggregation levels, the regression should find that these growth rates are less significant than fixed effects for sectors and (for the macro level) years.

The regression analysis will serve a twofold purpose:

  1. 1.

    It verifies the consistency of the model by showing that \(\dot {s_{k,t}}\) is a predictor for \(\dot {s_{i,t}}\).

  2. 2.

    More importantly, it allows us to shed more light on the differences between the dynamics governing employment and those governing the development of value added (and closely correlated variables).

3.3 Distributions of firm level variables

As detailed below in Section 4.5, the relevant variables at the firm level are heavy-tailed. This is true for employment (cf. Heinrich and Dai (2016)), for labor productivity (cf. Yang et al. (2019)), and value added (see Section 4.5). While employment is strictly positive and the heavy tail therefore only occurs on one side, value added and labor productivity are two-sided. We find that Lévy alpha-stable distributions (Nolan 1998; 2019) with tail indices α < 2 are good empirical models for these variables (cf. Yang et al. (2019) and Section 4.5). First differences of heavy-tailed variables will also be heavy-tailed, but will always be two-sided. Quotients of two heavy-tailed variables may yield different types of variables (Rathie et al. 2016), but in our case, for both labor productivity, qi,t = yi,t/li,t, and value added growth, \(\dot {y_{i,t}}=\frac {y_{i,t}-y_{i,t-1}}{y_{i,t-1}}\), we obtain another heavy-tailed distribution. In fact, these quotients themselves are fitted very well by Lévy alpha-stable distributions with tail indices α < 2.

Lévy alpha-stable distributions follow the characteristic functionFootnote 8

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \varphi(h)={\mathbb{E}}\left[e^{(ihx)}\right] =\left\{\begin{array}{lll} e^{(-\gamma^{\alpha}|h|^{\alpha}[1+i\beta \tan\left( {\tfrac {\pi \alpha }{2}}\right) \operatorname {sgn}(h)\left( (\gamma|h|)^{1-\alpha}-1 \right))] + i\delta h)} &\alpha \neq 1 \\e^{(-\gamma|h|[1+i\beta{\tfrac {2}{\pi}} \operatorname {sgn}(h)\log(\gamma|h|)] + i\delta h)}&\alpha =1 \end{array}\right. \end{array} $$
(11)

where h is the frequency, the equivalent to variable x in frequency space. It can be parametrized as S(0,α,β,γ,δ) where the four variables stand for the tail index (α), the skew parameter (β), the scale (γ) and the location shift (δ). For details on the fitting, see Yang et al. (2019) and Heinrich et al. (2020).

For value added, value added change, value added growth, and labor productivity, the distribution densities can be seen in Fig. 15.

Lévy alpha-stable distributions are special in that they are the only continuous distribution class that fulfills the stable criterion: Adding two (or arbitrarily many) Lévy alpha-stable distributions yields another Lévy alpha-stable distributions. The distribution class is the attractor of the generalized central limit theorem. While summing over short tailed random variates leads to a normal distribution (a member of the Lévy alpha-stable distribution class with α = 2), summing over heavy tailed variates yields heavy tailed members of the Lévy alpha-stable class. From an evolutionary perspective, it would appear that natural Lévy alpha-stable distributions (e.g., when encountered in form of value added or labor productivity, etc.) may be the result of aggregation processes occurring in economic systems.

The Lévy alpha-stable distributions are furthermore the entropy maximizing distributions for constraint \(h^{\alpha }=\overline {\alpha }\), i.e. finiteness of the statistical momentFootnote 9 of order α Frank (2009). All moments of order > α will be infinite.

This has consequences for quantities that follow these distributions and for statistics performed on such quantities: While for samples drawn from Lévy alpha-stable distributions, sample moments can be computed, they will diverge with the sample size, and are therefore contaminated by information that does not belong to the moment. Operating with sample moments m when the corresponding distribution does not have finite moment m will lead to invalid and misleading conclusions.

Note that aggregates over samples from a distribution S are essentially linear functions of the mean of S. If S is Lévy alpha-stable distributed with α ≤ 1 so that the mean does not exist, the aggregate will become volatile. Even if the distribution has α > 1 such that the mean is finite, Lévy alpha-stable moments may converge slowly and the aggregate may still show a volatile behavior compared to quantities that are subject to the classical central limit theorem without heavy-tailed influences. This is highly relevant in our case, as it applies to sectoral as well as macro-level value added (output) and value added changes as well as other quantities. Because of autocorrelation, the quantities will remain relatively stable over short time periods. However, across countries, sectors, and long time spans, the volatility is high. This is in stark contrast to quantities that are based on aggregations of Normally distributed or other short-tailed random variates, e.g., effective monthly work hours per employee, or prices of homogeneous goods at any one point in time.

Finally, in regression analyses involving heavy-tailed (especially Lévy alpha-stable distributed) quantities, heavy-tailedness may in many cases be inherited by the residuals of the regression. In such event, the assumptions of the OLS regression methodology (normality of residuals) are violated and the OLS results become invalid. Such cases require a robust regression approach that allows for heavy-tailed errors.

4 Empirical evidence

In the model section above (Section 3), we conjectured that economic growth is neither homogeneous across different sectors nor does it align when measured in different variables. Specifically changes and growth rates in employment on the one hand and output or value added on the other differ wildly (Figs. 2 and 3). In this section, we will show this in detail.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Changes (Growth rates and first differences) in employment shares vs. changes in value added shares by sectors over the period 2000-2014

Fig. 3
figure 3

Growth rates of value added (absolute value, not shares) vs. labor productivity growth by sectors over the period 2000-2014. While value added growth and productivity growth seem roughly negatively related for all sectors, in industry sectors only, the variables appear to be roughly positively associated

4.1 Data

We use firm level data from the Chinese Industrial Enterprise Database (CIE DB) for the years 1998-2013 and sector level data from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) for the years 2000-2014.

The CIE DB includes various micro-data for several hundreds of thousands of firms per year. It is, however, subject to a quickly changing panel (the overwhelming majority of firms are not present for all years), changes in data collection and in the variables recorded. For a more detailed discussion of problems with this data set, see Brandt et al. (2014). The database does, however, also offer excellent coverage that is absolutely unique for a country and time period at this development stage. With the years of the opening to foreign capital, the transition to a market economy, the appearance of numerous start-ups, and the closure of a significant number of state-owned enterprises, it also covers a rather crucial period of economic development and economic transition in the PR China. The database includes primary sector classifications following different versions (1994 and 2002) of the Chinese GuóBiāo (). At the 2-digit level that we work with, most sectors are consistent, but we omit some few sectors the designation of which changes for different years in the database. For details, see Table 6 in Appendix C.

The WIOD includes a range of sector level accounts for the PR China; it employs the ISIC Revision 4 sector classification (International Standard Industrial Classification). For details, see Timmer et al. (2015b). Throughout the present paper, we will also report sectors according to ISIC Rev.4. The correspondence table between GuóBiāo 1994/2002 and ISIC Rev.4 can be found in in Appendix C.

The variables we employ and the corresponding symbols mostly follow the usual standard in economics. However, for convenience, we include a variable and symbol table in in Appendix A.

4.2 Sectoral dynamics

Figure 1 shows the long-term development of value added Y in the PR China in six aggregated sectors as reported in the statistical yearbooks and summarized in Holz (2006). The six sectors are 1. primary, i.e., agriculture, 2. industry, 3. construction, 4. trade and catering, 5. communication and transportation, and 6. other services. As the figure shows, the contribution of industry sectors has remained remarkably stable since the 1970s at around 40% while the tertiary sectors have been growing rapidly at the expense of agriculture. This is consistent with the pattern reported in the literature and seen across developing economies around the globe for both value added and employment (Timmer et al. 2015a).

Our sectoral and firm-level data sets cover a relatively recent part, 1998-2014. We therefore can not expect to see major shifts to or away from industry, but structural change within and between industry sectors may be present. Figure 4 shows the employment and value added shares of the 16 largest sectors between 2000 and 2014 while the bivariate development and changes (employment share vs. value added share) of the 12 largest industry sectorsFootnote 10 are depicted in Fig. 5. Both figures reveal a certain volatility while the general levels remain unsurprisingly stable.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Development of employment and value added shares by sector

Fig. 5
figure 5

Development of employment vs. value added by sector

In particular, Fig. 5 shows that there is no direct connection between changes in value added and employment, at least in the short term,Footnote 11 they seem almost independent from one another. What is remarkable, though, is that the movements performed by the sectors in Fig. 5 tend to be clockwise, i.e., growth in value added precedes growth in in employment (and similar for decline). However, they are far from regular.

15-year aggregates in Fig. 2 do reveal a trend that may suggest that in the long run and on average, employment and value added growth have a positive relationship (cf. Fabricant (1942) and Metcalfe et al. (2006)). However, these are again driven by changes in the primary and tertiary sectors, the growth and decline of which far outpaces the industry sectors in the period covered by the data set. Industry sectors, shown in yellow to green color shade, are in both panels of Fig. 2 clustered around the origin with no clear dependence between the dynamics of the two variables within industry (i.e., without primary and tertiary sectors) even in the aggregate. The sectors on the growing side tend to be the more sophisticated industries (special purpose machinery C29, transportation equipment C30, IT and optical equipment C26, fuel C19).

Figures 6 and 7, depicting the bivariate development of labor productivity and value added and employment shares respectively, do not reveal any systematic short runFootnote 12 connection between these variables. While the three variables are locked in the identity qi = yi/li, the development patterns appear to be highly sector specific. Similarly, as shown in Fig. 3 the relationship between (absolute) value added growth and labor productivity growth takes a different form in industry sectors (positive slope) and in the whole economy (negative or no slope).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Development of employment vs. labor productivity by sector

Fig. 7
figure 7

Development of value added vs. labor productivity by sector

There is a clear signature of the events in the recent economic history of China. The average firm ages dropped significantly in the late 1990s and early 2000s in all industry sectors as seen in Fig. 8. This corresponds to the dissolution of some of the SOEs and the simultaneous emergence of startups during this time period. The difference is less pronounced for sector D35 (electricity and gas supply), a sector that should be expected to include larger firms because of natural monopolies and public companies because of strategic importance. Furthermore, aggregated data in Fig. 4 shows turbulence in time periods 2003 and 2008, 2009.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Development of average firm ages by sector in firm level data

4.3 Correlation laws

Next, we investigate correlation laws between quantities at both the firm-level and the sectoral level, the latter corresponding to Fabricant’s laws (Fabricant 1942; Scott 1991; Metcalfe et al. 2006).

Figures 9 and 10 show the correlation matrices between the quantities included in one or the other correlation law proposed in the literature as discussed in Section 2 above. While Fig. 10 shows the correlations between growth rates, in which the laws are generally expressed in the literature, we include the correlations between the levels in Fig. 9 to convey an idea of what dependencies exist in the data. Intuitively, in the levels size variables (employment, value added, capital) are correlated. Also, hallmarks of sophisticated industry sectors (labor productivity, capital intensity, average wage, and input price) are correlated among each other while being negatively correlated to employment and wage share of output.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Correlations in macro-level data (levels)

Fig. 10
figure 10

Correlations in macro-level growth rate data

Figure 10 confirms most of Fabricant’s laws:

  • Value added growth (i.e., output growth) and labor productivity growth are positively correlated.

  • Value added growth is negatively correlated to the growth of wage per output quantity (i.e., output growth dominates wage growth).

  • Value added growth is positively correlated with both employment and capital growth.

  • Growth of value added per unit of output and wage costs per unit of output are correlated.

  • Growth of value added per unit of output is correlated with growth of output prices.

Indeed, these correlation laws hold with impressive regularity and have been confirmed in many different countries (Fabricant 1942; Scott 1991; Metcalfe et al. 2006), times and contexts at the sectoral level, including in our case. However, we shall show below that they disintegrate at the micro-level, i.e. when observing firms.

Some other aspects proved to be different already at the sectoral level in the present case:

  • Capital intensity ki/li growth and value added growth are strongly negatively correlated, not positively. This is an interesting and counter-intuitive aspect, which arises mainly because the fast growing services sectors have lost capital intensity by expanding employment while at the same time boosting value added growth.

  • The correlation between the wage bill per unit of output and the labor productivity (output per worker) is positive, not negative. This implies that wages are growing with output, but may be a special effect of the China’s rapid total growth in the time frame covered by the study. It can be seen that the correlation between labor productivity growth and the growth of the wage share of income is indeed negative, which implies that profits per output were growing even faster.

  • There is no negative correlation between output price growth and value added growth. We conjecture that while Fabricant (1942) found such a negative correlation, this may not hold in the context of rapid demand-driven growth. If rising demand from rising wages played a significant part in China’s growth in the period of study, both wages and output prices and value added would have increased, yielding the positive correlation we see in Fig. 10.

  • Factor price correlation laws attributed by Scott (1991) to Salter, negative correlations between factor prices changes (wage and input prices) on the one hand and value added growth because of retirement of old, inefficient techniques, do not hold.

At the micro-level, considering data for individual firms from the CIE DB, many of these correlation laws fall apart, however. We consider first differences instead of growth rates because many quantities can take negative values at the micro-level, leading to counter-intuitive and misleading growth rate computations. The correlations are reported in Fig. 11. Increase in value added is still associated with increase in capital. Higher value added will normally feed into profits and then into the capital stock unless the profits are paid out to capital owners. Both value added and reinvestment will also be autocorrelated, therefore this correspondence is intuitive. However, no correlation exists between increases in value added and in either labor productivity or employment. The correlation between increases in value added and those in wages per value added (the latter used as proxy for wages per output quantity) is either zero (for value added computed as the difference between output and intermediate inputs) or positive (for value added imputed as the sum of wages and profits).Footnote 13 Other remarkable correlations include those between labor productivity and capital intensity as well as wages.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Correlations in firm-level data. All rows and columns except for the wage level in the last column represent first differences

What does this mean for our analysis? Two interpretations are possible. Either micro-level data is noisy enough to mask the true effect, be that because of idiosyncratic shocks or because of data collection issues, while everything averages out nicely at the aggregated, sectoral level. This explanation is doubtful, especially in the light of heavy tailed data in the relevant quantities (see Section 4.5). Heavy-tailed quantities may exactly not average out in the aggregate as the law of large numbers does not apply. Even for existing, non-infinite moments in heavy-tailed data, the convergence may be quite slow.

On the other hand, Fabricant’s law may not be a property of the firm, but one of the industry sector. Industry sectors share a lot of infrastructure: the same labor force, largely the same capabilities and technologies, as well as procedural knowledge. They also share the same communication and transportation networks and the same input and output markets. Labor mobility of skilled labor within an industry is typically quite high, especially if the industry is concentrated in a geographical region. The fortunes of an individual company may grow and fall; the company may choose to hire or to expand at particular times. However, the labor force and infrastructure available to the sector remains the same and only changes slowly. As a consequence, it would not be expected that Fabricant’s laws manifest themselves at the firm level, except for the correspondence of output and capital growth. It should, however, be expected that they are evident on average, across a longer time frame, for the sectors of an economy.

This is consistent with the hypothesis that Fabricant’s correlation of labor productivity growth and output (or value added) growth is rooted in different rates of technological change or in economies of scale at the sector level (Scott 1991), while other explanations such as factor substitution or increased personal efficiency of employees would suggest that there should be an observable effect at the micro-level. We will return to this point in the regression analysis in Section 5.

While this is an interesting result, our analysis is, of course, limited to a very particular case: The economy of the PR China in the decades when its development reached the highest levels of growth, and when the fastest and most intense processes of transformation towards a market economy took place. As pointed out, this may have an effect on some of the usual correlation laws that may be absent in such fast growing developing economies. It is also possible that the micro-level may show more regular characteristics in slow-growing developed economies.

4.4 Autocorrelation of sectoral and micro-level quantities

Metcalfe et al. (2006) reported that industry sectors in their sample (the post-war USA) show differential growth in employment and in output - very much in line with our findings above - and that these have a significant degree of rigidity. The sectoral shares are highly autocorrelated and do not change quickly. Our results in Section 4.2 and specifically in Fig. 6 already point in the same direction. In this section, we briefly discuss autocorrelation sprectra of the relevant variables, employment and value added at the sectoral level in shares (Fig. 12) and in first differences of shares (Fig. 13) as well as at the firm level (levels only shown in Fig. 14). The autocorrelation is

$$ {\varrho}_{X}(\tau) = \frac{\mathop{\mathbb{E}}[(X_{t}-\mathop{\mathbb{E}}(X_{t}))(X_{t+\tau}-\mathop{\mathbb{E}}(X_{t+\tau}))]}{\sigma_{X_{t}}\sigma_{X_{t+\tau}}} $$
(12)

where \({\mathbb {E}}(X)\) is the expectation and \({\sigma ^{2}_{X}}\) is the variance of X. Note that we use broad range autocorrelations, i.e., we re-sample observations at different time periods to get more statistical power. The autocorrelation functions are therefore not functions of specific times, but merely of the time lag. The number of observations (and the rate of resampling) decreases with time lag. Since resampling does not allow us to use standard confidences, we bootstrap the standard errors (for 95% confidence intervals) for the sectoral data.Footnote 14

Fig. 12
figure 12

Autocorrelations of sectoral shares

Fig. 13
figure 13

Autocorrelations of the changes in sectoral shares

Fig. 14
figure 14

Autocorrelations of shares of employment and value added at the firm-level

We find very high and slowly decreasing levels of autocorrelation for the levels of the sectoral quantities, with employment decreasing slightly faster and with wider confidence margins (Fig. 12). For employment, positive autocorrelations are still present in the first differences (and possibly with no decay with increasing lags), while for value added this is not the case (Fig. 13). That is, increasing employment shares tend to continue to increase and vice versa, potentially bringing about strong and increasing differences between sectors. For value added the short term trend can reverse while the levels evidently remain stable over long periods. Positive and high autocorrelations in employment and especially in value added are also present at the firm level (Fig. 14).

4.5 Micro-level distributions and their functional forms

Elsewhere (Yang et al. 2019; Heinrich et al. 2020), we have shown that both labor productivities and labor productivity changes follow Lévy alpha-stable distributions. Specifically, the Lévy alpha-stable distribution is a much better distributional model than asymmetric exponential power distributions suggested for firm level growth (for which labor productivity or labor productivity changes may be proxies) elsewhere in the literature (Bottazzi and Secchi 2006; 2011). We chose to focus on linear first differences instead of growth rates, as growth rates may be misleading and counter-intuitive for variables that can be negative like value added yk and labor productivity qk = yk/lk at the firm level.Footnote 15

For the present study, employment and value added are equally relevant. While we may remain agnostic with respect to the specific distributional model of each of the variables, they are all heavy tailed. In the case of the value added as well as value added change, value added growth, and labor productivity (which is value added divided by employment, a quotient of two heavy tailed variables) the Lévy alpha stable seems to fit the distribution rather well, the densities and fits to Lévy alpha-stable are shown in Fig. 15.

Fig. 15
figure 15

Density of value added and derived variables by year

We perform finite moment tests using Trapani’s approach (Trapani 2016) and R’s finity package (Heinrich and Winkler 2020), yielding infinite moments for the second moments in all relevant variables, see Table 1. A consequence is that sample moments corresponding to the non-existing moments should not be used since they are contaminated by information about the sample sizes and do not offer an unbiased reading of the moment. There does not appear to be an average employment or a variance of labor productivity, value added, etc. This must be taken into account for any regressions run with these variables: There is a strong possibility that the errors inherit the heavy-tailedness of the variables, which would render OLS assumptions violated and OLS results invalid.

Table 1 Finiteness tests for the first two moments (i.e., mean, variance) for value added (Y ), value added change (dY), value added growth (\(\dot {Y}\)), value added (L), value added change (dL), value added growth (\(\dot {L}\)), labor productivity (Q), and labor productivity change (dQ) following Trapani’s approach (Trapani 2016) and R’s finity package (Heinrich and Winkler 2020)

Finally, we investigate the bivariate dispersion of the first differences in employment and value-added. Figure 17 reveals that the two variables have a unimodal joint distribution with the highest density area (mode) centers around at zero. The degree of dispersion of one variable conditional on the other tends to decrease as it moves away from the mode. Further, there is no visually discernible correlation between the two variables (different from the aggregated level; see Section 4.3).

5 Regression analysis: the micro-macro connection in sectoral growth

In Section 4, we have shown the characteristics of structural change for the PR China in the period of study (1998-2014) at both the sectoral and the micro-level. We have discussed the likely distributions of data, connections between variables, the stark difference between employment growth and output (value added) growth, and have discussed some implications and interpretations. We have also demonstrated that there is, unsurprisingly, a connection between sectoral and micro-level variables. We will now investigate this connection in more detail and will for this return to the evolutionary approach discussed in Section 3.

Fig. 16
figure 16

Density of value added growth by firm size categories (S - small, M - medium sized, L - large, VL - very large)

Fig. 17
figure 17

2d histogram of dli and dyi in CIE DB firm-level data

5.1 Model specification

Following the model in Eq. 9, we will in this section run regressions on firm level growth \(\dot {x_{i}}\) (where xi can be employment li and value added yi) with sectoral level growth \(\dot {x_{k}}\) as predictors in a linear (additive) combination with other possible predictors. We will continue to highlight differences between growth processes in employment and in value added. We avoid using multiple highly correlated predictors (as shown in see Fig 11) to avoid multicolinearities. This leads us to avoid capital and wage bill (correlated with value added), revenue (correlated with value added and employment), as well as wages, profitability, and capital intensity (correlated with labor productivities).

We do, however, include three predictors besides the sectoral growth: labor productivity, qi, labor productivity change dqi, and firm age ai.

There is a broad literature connecting productivities and profitabilities to either growth potential or to realized growth (Goddard et al. 2004; Coad 2007; Bottazzi et al. 2008); the coefficient is expected to be positive.Footnote 16

Furthermore, especially the evolutionary literature expects growth to depend on relative performance or relative capabilities of the firm. In many contributions to evolutionary economics, fitness terms, as they appear in Eq. 2 and similar models, are identified as productivity (Nelson and Winter 1982; Silverberg and Lehnert 1993; Mulder et al. 2001).Footnote 17 For a discussion of the empirical literature, see Coad (2007). In the present case, working with relative productivity is not appropriate for two reasons: First, computing relative productivity would require computing the first moment. However, as the variable is heavy tailed, that moment may in samples be unreliable, since even if it exists, it will converge only slowly with sample size. Second, we only have sample data, not the full population. In light of this, it appears appropriate to use the first difference of labor productivity as a proxy. Under a wide range of assumptions changes in productivity should lead to dynamic adaptations of the growth process in evolutionary models. Labor productivity change is available for a sizable subset of our observations.Footnote 18

A substantial literature also connects firm ages to growth (cf. Coad (2007)), often with a focus on potentially more dynamic startups (Coad 2007; Pugsley et al. 2019). However, a weakening of this has been observed in the recent past (Pugsley et al. 2019). Crucially for our study, the effect of firm age has also been found to be reversed for developing countries, specifically India, with older firms having better growth prospects (Das 1995).

Finally, effects of size, geography, sector, and other context may also be expected (Coad 2007), some studies going as far as ascribing a crucial impact on the distribution of growth rates to firm size (Bottazzi et al. 2019). While a visual inspection of our data (see Fig. 16) does not confirm a significant impact of size, we will include fixed effects for size categories (small, medium sized, large, very large), firm typesFootnote 19, years, provinces, and also sectors, although sector fixed effects may interfere with the sectoral growth estimator (\(\dot {x_{k}}\)).

Figure 18 shows the filtered mean and median of growth rate of employment (left panel) and value added (right panel) at the firm-level conditional on the corresponding employment and value added growth at the sectoral level, respectively. The mean filter picks up a positive relationship between the firm-level and sector level employment growths. However, this result is somewhat misleading considering that the firm-level distribution of employment growth is heavy-tailed so its mean is less informative than the median. When we use the median filter, the positive relationship disappears. For the value-added case, both mean and median filters pick up a positive relationship between the firm-level and sectoral level growths. The following regression attempts to look into the relationship between the firm-level and sectoral growth of employment and value-added in a more systemic manner.

Fig. 18
figure 18

Filtered mean and median of growth rate of employment (left panel) and value added (right panel) at the firm-level conditional on the corresponding employment and value added growth at the sectoral level

Starting from Eq. 9 and taking into account hypotheses from the literature and characteristics of the data as explained in the present section, we consider the following models:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{x_{i}}&=& \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} \dot{s_{k}} + \varepsilon \end{array} $$
(13)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{x_{i}}&=& \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} \dot{s_{k}} + \beta_{2} q_{i} + \beta_{3} dq_{i} + \beta_{4} a_{i} + \varepsilon \end{array} $$
(14)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{x_{i}}&=& \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} \dot{s_{k}} + \beta_{2} q_{i} + \beta_{3} dq_{i} + \beta_{4} a_{i} + YearFE + ProvinceFE \\ & &+ FirmTypeFE + FirmSizeFE + \varepsilon \end{array} $$
(15)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{x_{i}}&=& \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} \dot{s_{k}} + \beta_{2} q_{i} + \beta_{3} dq_{i} + \beta_{4} a_{i} + YearFE + ProvinceFE \end{array} $$
(16)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&+ FirmTypeFE + FirmSizeFE + SectorFE + \varepsilon \end{array} $$

where we run the regressions for both employment growth (\(\dot {x_{i}}\) and \(\dot {x_{k}}\) then being \(\dot {l_{i}}\) and \(\dot {l_{k}}\)) and for value added growth as the appropriate indicator of output growth at the firm level (\(\dot {x_{i}}\) and \(\dot {x_{k}}\) then being \(\dot {y_{i}}\) and \(\dot {y_{k}}\)). The FE variables are fixed effects.

5.2 Estimation results

Performing OLS fits of models (13), (14), (15), and (16) for both employment growth and value added growth reveals that the residuals of each of the regressions belong to a heavy-tailed distribution with infinite second moment. As a consequence, the underlying assumptions of OLS fitting are violated and the regression results have to be treated as unreliable. The results are reported for comparison in Tables 4 and 5 in Appendix B. The last lines of the tables also give the results of the finiteness test following (Trapani 2016) for the second moments.Footnote 20

Consequently, the models were fitted using robust regression with Cauchy distributed errorsFootnote 21 using the R package heavy (Osorio 2019). Table 2 gives the the results of robust regressions for employment and value added growth.

Table 2 Robust regression results for models (1), (2), (3), (4) with firm-level employment growth \(\dot {l_{i}}\) (left hand side) and value added growth \(\dot {y_{i}}\) (right hand side) as dependent variable

All coefficients across all models are statistically significant at the 0.01% level except for the coefficient of \(\dot {y_{k}}\) in model (4) (Eq. 16) for value added growth.

Sectoral growth coefficients are in every case positive. Firm-level growth proves to be associated with sectoral growth in the same direction as per our hypothesis from Section 3. In all employment growth models this coefficient is significant, albeit small. For value added, the coefficient becomes non-significant when sector fixed effects are included, but is otherwise positive and significant. This indicates that there is indeed a sectoral effect - the effect may just not have a linear form (cf. also Fig. 18). It may be subject to other sector-specific influences besides the sector level growth, although these influences are sufficiently close to the sector level growth to capture its impact on the dependent variable and render its coefficient non-significant. Sector fixed effects tend to be lower for most industry sectors (C sectors), than for either mining (B) or electricity and water distribution (D35, E36).

The coefficient for labor productivity is equally present and significant. It is positive but small for employment growth (higher labor productivity being associated with employment growth), but negative for value added growth. The latter is surprising but may constitute a saturation effect (if high productivity firms have mostly reached their capacity), while the positive impact of productivity is captured by the productivity growth term. The coefficient for labor productivity change is positive for value added growth, but negative and of relatively small magnitude for employment growth. We suspect that this reflects productivity increases through changes in capital intensity, which may occasionally be accompanied by a reduction or the labor force.

Firm age has a negative coefficient in all eight models, indicating that start-ups have higher growth potential than older firms.

Type,Footnote 22 size,Footnote 23 and yearFootnote 24 fixed effects are significant. Province fixed effects are only significant for some provinces.Footnote 25

These results are dramatically different from those of OLS regressions, which we discuss in the Appendix B. In the OLS regression, sectoral employment growth has a statistically significant impact on the firm-level growth across all 4 models as shown in Table 4. In contrast, the impact of sectoral value-added growth on the firm-level value-added growth is positive but is statistically insignificant (Table 5). Various other effects are reversed compared to the robust regression.

6 Discussion and conclusion

While structural change has been extensively studied in developed economies, not all aspects of it are well-understood for developing countries. Yes, it is obvious that modernization and the development of advanced industriesFootnote 26 (Hidalgo et al. 2007; Hidalgo and Hausmann 2009) is a crucial factor and yes, institutional rigidities play a role. But why did the rapid development succeed in China and some other countries while it continues to be elusive in many cases? Can lessons be learned from China? Are policies applicable elsewhere? Did China’s situation as a transformation economy moving from central planning to a market-based system play a part?

In this paper, we investigated the nature of China’s structural change in the period 1998-2014 and any patterns and empirical regularities therein. We fitted a multi-level model inspired by considerations from evolutionary economics, and confirmed that growth at the micro-level and the sectoral level are connected. Sectoral level growth terms are a predictor of firm level growth. This may seem obvious, but it underlines the coherence of the model and the coefficients and the robustness to fixed effects shed light on the nature of this connection. For employment growth, the connection is robust and significant. For value added growth, the effect appears to be larger and remains robust and significant unless sector fixed effects are added, which then capture the sectoral effect better. This is likely due to either a nonlinear coupling of firm-level and sectoral terms or to the presence of other sector level specificities.

Second, we found that well-known correlation laws from sectoral decompositions (Fabricant’s laws) fall apart at the micro-level. Crucially, there is no positive correlation between labor productivity and output variables (value added). In regressions, a significant association is found, but contrary to the sectoral level, it has a negative coefficient. The fact that the correlation law does not extend to the micro level indicates that they instead emerge from phenomena at some intermediate level. We conclude that it arises due to a property of the sectors (sector-specific rates of technological change, infrastructure, etc.), and is not a direct micro-level correspondence, a finding that corresponds to evolutionary economic theory (Nelson and Winter 1975; Montobbio 2002).

Third, we find that many variables at the firm level - including value added, employment, and labor productivity - follow heavy-tailed distributions, often two-sided Lévy alpha-stable distributions (cf. Yang et al. (2019)), but occasionally other functional forms. This must be taken into account in econometric studies and generative models alike, if these variables are utilized. We concluded that robust regressions with Cauchy-distributed errors had to be run in order for our econometric models to yield valid results.

Fourth, we find that in growth processes in industry sectors, output growth tends to lead employment growth - at the sectoral level anyway.

Beyond these findings, we were able to confirm a range of known regularities at the sectoral level including Fabrciant’s laws (Fabricant 1942; Scott 1991) and Metcalfe et al.’s (2006) findings regarding autocorrelations of sectoral shares and dispersion measures (normalized Hirschman-Herfindahl indices and entropy).

Our findings underline that modern economies are not as modular as it may seem at first glance. It is not possible to develop some particularly productive firms in isolation or even one sector without allowing a supporting infrastructure and firm ecosystem to develop. Nor is it advisable to think of firms as homogeneous entities such that a growing spread of productivities would be symptomatic for misallocation.

That said, it was in the Chinese case beneficial to focus modernization efforts on industry sectors in particular and to enable the reallocation of economic resources both by reforming SOEs (with unavoidable layoffs at a significant scale) and by permitting private entrepreneurship and foreign investment and strengthening the legal basis for this (Brandt et al. 2012). The fact that sectoral output growth (and sectoral characteristics in the model in Eq. 16) were found to be strongly associated to firm level growth might suggest that support for certain strategic sectors is crucial. This would be in line with Hidalgo et al.’s product space and economic complexity analysis (Hidalgo et al. 2007; Hidalgo and Hausmann 2009). Other institutional factors as well as changes to patent law and incentives for innovation and R&D were certainly also conductive of China’s development (Hu and Jefferson 2008).

Whether these findings can easily be applied to other developing countries is doubtful because of the unique nature of China’s economic system as both a developing economy and a transformation economy in a geographic region that is characterized by relative stability compared to other parts of our world. For many countries, micro-level data are furthermore not available, which makes it difficult to assess, to what extent the micro-levels of these economies are similar to either the Chinese one or those of developed countries. It should also be noted that our analysis excluded the input-output network within and across sectors, which may lead to additional important insights. With more detailed data, which may allow to confirm that processes for some countries are indeed similar to what is observed here for the PR China, it may become possible to recommend support for specific sectors or specific intensities of resource reallocation (that is, supporting labor and capital mobility without upending the economic and social structure of the country).