Skip to main content
Log in

Team incentives with imperfect mutual inference

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Journal of Game Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I study the optimal team incentive when the agents can coordinate private actions through repeated interaction with imperfect public monitoring. The agents are able to imperfectly infer each other’s private actions via the stochastically correlated measurements. Correlation of measurement noise, besides its risk sharing role in the conventional multiple-agent moral hazard problem, is crucial to the accuracy of each agent’s inference. The principal’s choice of performance pay to provide incentive via inducing competition or coordination among the agents thus exhibits the trade-off between risk sharing and mutual inference between the agents. I characterize the optimal form of performance pay with respect to the correlation of measurement noise. Whether the conventional theoretical prediction holds depends on how the agents form the mutual inference, based on an exogenous standard or formed endogenously.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Please refer to Holmström (1982), Mookherjee (1984), and Ramakrishnan and Thakor (1991) for pioneer research on team incentive with non-cooperative agents, and Holmström and Milgrom (1990), Itoh (1992, 1993), Che and Yoo (2001), Kim and Vikander (2015), and Rayo (2007) for that with agents coordinating actions with either a side contract or repeated interaction with perfect monitoring. Fleckinger and Roux (2012) surveyed this literature.

  2. For clarity, throughout this paper I use the term coordination when the principal induces the agent to coordinate actions, while the term collusion is used when the principal deters such activity. The term coalition is referred to the team of agents who coordinate or collude.

  3. An alternative way to model is to assume that the agents exert private actions to produce a non-contractible noisy output, and that each agent’s private action is measured separately and imperfectly by a contractible indicator, which is stochastically correlated among the agents. Modeling in this way, conclusions would be qualitatively the same even with synergy in production.

  4. A stationary contract can be justified as the existence of a sequentially optimal short-term contract. Fudenberg et al. (1990) constructed sufficient conditions for such existence. In brief, the principal and the agents are symmetrically informed of future history-independent contingent outcomes and technologies, and that preferences are time separable, in which case a long-term contract has no extra value beyond a sequence of its short-term counterpart. Given the nature of the agents’ repeated game in this paper as will be introduced shortly, the future outcomes are not history-independent and the team of agents is better informed of these future outcomes than is the principal. I thus briefly discuss qualitative robustness when relaxing the restriction to allowing a menu of stationary contracts later as well.

  5. On general repeated games with imperfect public monitoring, please refer to Abreu et al. (1990) and Fudenberg et al. (1994). Threshold grim trigger strategies were traditionally adopted in the study of repeated Cournot games to enforce collusion, e.g. Porter (1983) and Green and Porter (1984) as pioneer works and Aoyagi and Fréchette (2009) for a recent theoretical and experimental work.

  6. Fudenberg et al. (1994) derived conditions under which a grim trigger strategy can yield efficient payoff. In brief, not only a unilateral deviation of a given player is detected stochastically as in this paper (individual full rank), but also the player who has deviated can be detected stochastically (pairwise full rank).

  7. As raised by Ishiguro (2002), under the non-cooperative benchmark, the implemented action profile \((a_{H},a_{H})\) is not the unique Nash equilibrium with binding \((IC_{n})\). Nevertheless, optimality of RPE would still hold, because the principal can increase \(\alpha _{n}\) by an infinitesimal amount to implement \((a_{H},a_{H})\) as the unique Nash equilibrium within the team, which does not change the fact that the contract exhibits RPE.

  8. If the agents are not protected by the legal right to opt out from the contract at an interim stage, what is relevant to the coordination-inducing contract is the ex-ante participation constraint, \((1-\delta )\overline{u}_{i}(a_{H},a_{H}|\mathbb {C})+\delta \left( (1-q_{i}^{n})\overline{u}_{i}(a_{H},a_{H}|\mathbb {C})+q_{i}^{n}\overline{u}_{i}(a_{L},a_{L}|\mathbb {C})\right) \ge 0\). This allows negative payoff in the punishment phase and reduces the cost to induce the agents to coordinate actions, without affecting the principal’s optimal contract to deter collusion.

References

  • Abreu D, Pearce D, Stacchetti E (1986) Optimal Cartel equilibrium with imperfect monitoring. J Econ Theory 39:251–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abreu D, Pearce D, Stacchetti E (1990) Toward a theory of discounted repeated games with imperfect monitoring. Econometrica 58(5):1041–1063

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoyagi M, Fréchette G (2009) Collusion as public monitoring becomes noisy: experimental evidence. J Econ Theory 144:1135–1165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai H, Obara I (2009) Firm reputation and horizontal integration. RAND J Econ 40(2):340–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che Y-K, Yoo S-W (2001) Optimal incentive for teams. Am Econ Rev 91(3):525–541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deb J, Li J, Mukherjee A (2016) Relational contracts with subjective peer evaluations. RAND J Econ 47(1):3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleckinger P (2012) Correlation and relative performance evaluation. J Econ Theory 147(1):93–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleckinger P, Roux N (2012) Collective versus relative incentives: the agency perspective, Working Paper

  • Fudenberg D, Levine D, Maskin E (1994) The folk theorem with imperfect public information. Econometrica 62(5):997–1039

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Holmström B, Milgrom P (1990) Short-term contracts and long-term agency relationships. J Econ Theory 51(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green E, Porter R (1984) Non-cooperative Collusion Under Imperfect Price Information. Econometrica 52(1):87–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B (1982) Moral hazard in teams. Bell J Econ 13(2):324–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B, Milgrom P (1987) Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica 55(2):303–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B, Milgrom P (1990) Regulating trade among agents. J Inst Theor Econ 146:85–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Ishiguro S (2002) Optimal incentives for teams: comment. Am Econ Rev 92:1711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishiguro S (2004) Collusion and discrimination in organizations. J Econ Theory 116:357–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itoh H (1992) Cooperation in hierarchical organizations: an incentive perspective. J Law Econ Organ 8(2):321–345

    Google Scholar 

  • Itoh H (1993) Coalitions, incentives, and risk sharing. J Econ Theory 60:410–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim J (2011) Collusion and discrimination in organizations: comment. J Econ Res 16:309–317

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim J-H, Vikander N (2015) Team-based incentives in problem-solving organizations. J Law Econ Organ 31(2):262–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer M, Vickers J (1997) Performance comparisons and dynamic incentives. J Political Econ 105(3):547–581

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee D (1984) Optimal incentive schemes with many agents. Rev Econ Stud 51(3):433–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter RH (1983) Optimal cartel trigger price strategies. J Econ Theory 29(2):313–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramakrishnan R, Thakor A (1991) Cooperation versus competition in agency. J Law Econ Organ 7(2):248–283

    Google Scholar 

  • Rayo L (2007) Relational incentives and moral hazard in teams. Rev Econ Stud 74:937–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Suggestions by the co-editor, the associate editor and two anonymous referees have greatly improved this paper. I am grateful to Fahad Khalil, Jacques Lawarrée, Charles Hill, Wei Li, Dennis O’Dea, Luis Rayo, Lan Shi, and Quan Wen, as well as participants at the 44th EARIE, for their helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from the Ministry of Science and Technology (Grant number MOST 105-2410-H-305-012-) is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alice Peng-Ju Su.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A Proof of Propositions

1.1.1 A.1 Proof of Lemma 1

Suppose that the agents coordinate to exert \((a_{i}^{0},a_{j}^{0})\) when the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium is \((a_{i}^{'},a_{j}^{'})\). Agent j detects agent i’s deviation correctly with probability

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}^{d}={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} Pr\left( x_{it}(a_{i}^{'})|x_{jt}(a_{j}^{0})<a_{it}^{0}+\sigma (x_{jt}-a_{jt}^{0})-s\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}\right) =\Phi \left( \frac{a_{i}^{0}-a_{i}^{'}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}-s\right) &{} for\,a_{i}^{0}>a_{i}^{'}\\ Pr\left( x_{it}(a_{i}^{'})|x_{jt}(a_{j}^{0})>a_{it}^{0}+\sigma (x_{jt}-a_{jt}^{0})+s\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}\right) =1-\Phi \left( \frac{a_{i}^{0}-a_{i}^{'}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}+s\right) &{} for\,a_{i}^{0}<a_{i}^{'} \end{array}\right. }, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Phi (\cdot )\) is the standard normal CDF. It is increasing in correlation as \(\frac{\partial q_{i}^{d}}{\partial \sigma }=\phi (\cdot )\frac{\sigma |a_{i}^{0}-a_{i}^{'}|}{\sqrt{(1-\sigma ^{2})^{3}}}>0\), where \(\phi (\cdot )\) is the standard normal PDF. Agent j mistakenly detects agent i of deviation with probability

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}^{n}={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} Pr\left( x_{it}(a_{i}^{0})|x_{jt}(a_{j}^{0})<a_{it}^{0}+\sigma (x_{jt}-a_{jt}^{0})-s\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}\right) =\Phi (-s) &{} for\,a_{i}^{0}>a_{i}^{'}\\ Pr\left( x_{it}(a_{i}^{0})|x_{jt}(a_{j}^{0})>a_{it}^{0}+\sigma (x_{jt}-a_{jt}^{0})+s\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}\right) =1-\Phi (s) &{} for\,a_{i}^{0}<a_{i}^{'} \end{array}\right. }, \end{aligned}$$

which is straightforward that \(\frac{\partial q_{i}^{n}}{\partial \sigma }=0\). \(\square \)

1.1.2 A.2 Proof of Proposition 1

The optimal contract to implement \((a_{H},a_{H})\) and to deter collusion solves the expected transfer minimization problem \(\min _{\alpha ,\beta ,\gamma }\mathbb {E}(\alpha x_{i}+\beta x_{j}+\gamma )\) subject to \((IR_{n})\), \((IC_{n})\), and (CP), \(i=1,2\) and \(i\ne j\). Given binding \((IR_{n})\), \((\alpha +\beta )a_{H}+\gamma =R(\alpha ,\beta )\), this contracting problem is reduced to

$$\begin{aligned} \mathscr {P}_{CP}:\qquad \min _{\alpha ,\beta }R(\alpha ,\beta )\equiv \frac{r}{2}(\alpha ^{2}+\beta ^{2}+2\sigma \alpha \beta ) \end{aligned}$$

subject to \((IC_{n})\) and (CP). \(\Delta =\Delta _{s}\) with exogenous inference and \(\Delta =\Delta ^{*}\) with endogenous inference.

Constraint \((IC_{n})\) can be reduced to \(\alpha \ge \eta \), where \(\eta \equiv \frac{c_{H}-c_{L}}{a_{H}-a_{L}}\). If \(\beta \ge 0\), \(\alpha +h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta \ge \alpha \ge \eta \) as \(0\le h(\delta ,\Delta )\equiv \frac{\delta \Delta }{1-\delta +\delta \Delta }\le 1\). \((IC_{n})\) is binding while (CP) slacks except at \(\beta =0\). With binding \((IC_{n})\), ignoring (CP) and \(\beta \ge 0\), the problem is that of the non-cooperative benchmark, in which the optimal \(\beta _{n}=\arg \min _{\beta }\eta ^{2}+\beta ^{2}+2\sigma \eta \beta =-\sigma \eta <0\). Among all \(\beta \ge 0\), \(\beta _{CP}=0\) is thus optimal to deter collusion. If \(\beta <0\), \(\alpha >\alpha +h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta \ge \eta \). (CP) is the only binding constraint, i.e. \(\alpha +h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta =\eta \). Solving the first order condition, \(\left( h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta -\eta \right) h(\delta ,\Delta )+\beta +\sigma \left( \eta -2h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta \right) =0\), the optimal contract with exogenous inference has \(\beta _{CP}=\frac{(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})-\sigma )\eta }{1+h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})^{2}-2\sigma h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})}<0\) if \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})<\sigma \), and \(\beta _{CP}=0\) if \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})\ge \sigma \). Rearranging \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})<\sigma \) yields \(\delta <\delta _{CP}\equiv \frac{\sigma }{(1-\sigma )\Delta _{s}+\sigma }\).

The optimal contract to implement \((a_{H},a_{H})\) and to induce coordination solves the expected transfer minimization problem \(\min _{\alpha ,\beta ,\gamma }\sum _{i=1,2}\left( \mathbb {E}(\alpha x_{i}+\beta x_{j}+\gamma )\right) \) subject to \((IR_{c})\), \((IC_{c})\), and (CI). Given binding \((IR_{c})\), \((\alpha +\beta )a_{L}+\gamma =R(\alpha ,\beta )\), this contracting problem is reduced to

$$\begin{aligned}&\mathscr {P}_{CI}:\quad \min _{\alpha ,\beta }(\alpha +\beta )(a_{H}-a_{L})+R(\alpha ,\beta )\equiv (\alpha +\beta )(a_{H}-a_{L})\\&\qquad \quad \,\,\quad +\frac{r}{2}(\alpha ^{2}+\beta ^{2}+2\sigma \alpha \beta ) \end{aligned}$$

subject to \((IC_{c})\) and (CI). \(\Delta =\Delta _{s}\) with exogenous inference and \(\Delta =\Delta ^{*}\) with endogenous inference.

Constraint \((IC_{c})\) can be reduced to \(\alpha +\beta \ge \eta \). If \(\beta \le 0\), \(\alpha +h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta \ge \alpha +\beta \ge \eta \) as \(0\le h(\delta ,\Delta )\equiv \frac{\delta \Delta }{1-\delta +\delta \Delta }\le 1\). \((IC_{c})\)is binding while (CI) slacks except at \(\beta =0\). With binding \((IC_{c})\), ignoring (CI) and \(\beta \le 0\), the problem is reduced to that of the cooperative benchmark in terms of the choice of \((\alpha ,\beta )\), in which the optimal \(\beta _{c}=\arg \min _{\beta }\eta ^{2}-2(1-\sigma )\left( \eta -\beta \right) \beta =\frac{\eta }{2}>0\). Among all \(\beta \le 0\), \(\beta _{CI}=0\) is thus optimal to induce coordination. If \(\beta >0\), \(\alpha +\beta >\alpha +h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta \ge \eta \). (CI) is the only binding constraint, \(\alpha +h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta =\eta \). Solving the first order condition, \((a_{H}-a_{L})\left( 1-h(\delta ,\Delta )\right) +r\left( \left( h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta -\eta \right) h(\delta ,\Delta )+\beta +\sigma \left( \eta -2h(\delta ,\Delta )\beta \right) \right) =0\), the optimal contract with exogenous inference has \(\beta _{CI}=\frac{r(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})-\sigma )\eta -(1-h(\delta ,\Delta _{s}))(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r(1+h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})^{2}-2\sigma h(\delta ,\Delta _{s}))}>0\) if \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})-\sigma >\frac{(1-h(\delta ,\Delta _{s}))(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r\eta }\), and \(\beta _{CI}=0\) if otherwise. Rearranging \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})-\sigma >\frac{(1-h(\delta ,\Delta _{s}))(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r\eta }\) yields \(\delta >\delta _{CI}\equiv \frac{r\sigma \eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r((1-\sigma )\Delta _{s}+\sigma )\eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}\).

As \(\frac{\sigma }{(1-\sigma )\Delta _{s}+\sigma }<1\), \(\delta _{CI}>\delta _{CP}\). For \(\delta <\delta _{CP}\), the optimal collusion-proof RPE is preferred to an IPR and the optimal coordination-inducing contract has IPR. Collusion-proof RPE is thus preferred to coordination-inducing JPE for \(\delta <\delta _{CP}\). For \(\delta >\delta _{CI}\), the optimal coordination inducing JPE is preferred to an IPR and the optimal collusion-proof contract has IPR. Coordination-inducing JPE is thus preferred to collusion-proof RPE for \(\delta >\delta _{CI}\). For \(\delta _{CI}\ge \delta \ge \delta _{CP}\), coordination is induced with IPR and collusion is deterred with IPR; IPR is optimal. \(\square \)

1.1.3 A.3 Proof of Proposition 2

It is easy to verify that \(\delta \gtreqless \delta _{CI}\) is merely a rearrangement of \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})\gtreqless \varphi (\sigma )\) and \(\delta \lesseqgtr \delta _{CP}\) is a rearrangement of \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})\lesseqgtr \sigma \). Proposition 2 holds if there exists parameters s and \(a_{H}-a_{L}\) such that \(\delta _{CI}\) and \(\delta _{CP}\) are diminishing in \(\sigma \) for \(\sigma _{0}<\sigma <\sigma ^{*}\), and are increasing in \(\sigma \) for \(\sigma _{1}>\sigma >\sigma ^{*}\), where \((\sigma _{0},\sigma _{1})\subseteq [0,1]\). Differentiate \(\delta _{CI}\equiv \frac{r\sigma \eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r((1-\sigma )\Delta _{s}+\sigma )\eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}\) with respect to \(\sigma \) finds \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CI}}{\partial \sigma }\gtreqless 0\) if \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{1-\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}\lesseqgtr \frac{r\eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}{\sigma r\eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}\equiv \frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\), or \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}\lesseqgtr \frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\frac{\sigma }{1-\sigma }\) for \(\sigma \in (0,1)\). Differentiate \(\delta _{CP}\equiv \frac{\sigma }{((1-\sigma )\Delta _{s}+\sigma )}\) with respect to \(\sigma \) finds \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CP}}{\partial \sigma }\gtreqless 0\) if \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{1-\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}\lesseqgtr \frac{1}{\sigma }\), or \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}\lesseqgtr \frac{1}{1-\sigma }\) for \(\sigma \in (0,1)\). For all \(\sigma \in (0,1)\) such that \(\delta _{CI}\) is increasing in \(\sigma \), \(\delta _{CP}\) is increasing in \(\sigma \) as well, and for all \(\sigma \in (0,1)\) such that \(\delta _{CP}\) is diminishing in \(\sigma \), \(\delta _{CI}\) is diminishing in \(\sigma \) as well, because \(\frac{\sigma }{\varphi (\sigma )}<1\). To see the non-monotonicity result, it is sufficient to focus on the existence of parameters such that \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CI}}{\partial \sigma }>0\) for sufficiently high correlations and \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CP}}{\partial \sigma }<0\) for some intermediate correlations.

Since \(\frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\ge 1\) with equality at \(\sigma =1\), and \(\lim _{\sigma \rightarrow 1}\Delta _{s}=1\) if s is finite, \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}<\frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\frac{\sigma }{1-\sigma }\) and \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CI}}{\partial \sigma }>0\) for sufficiently correlated measurement noise. If \(a_{H}-a_{L}\) and s are such that there is sufficiently high percentage improvement in the accuracy of inference with respect to higher correlation, captured by \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}>\frac{1}{1-\sigma }\), \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CP}}{\partial \sigma }<0\) for some correlation. Given these parameters, \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CP}}{\partial \sigma }<0\) and \(\frac{\partial \delta _{CI}}{\partial \sigma }<0\) for \(\sigma \in (\sigma _{0},\sigma ^{*})\), with \(\sigma ^{*}\) satisfying \(\frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta _{s}}=\frac{1}{1-\sigma }\). There then exists \(\delta \in \left( \delta (\sigma ^{*}),\,\min \left\{ \delta (\sigma _{0}),\delta (\sigma _{1})\right\} \right) \) at which \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})>\varphi (\sigma )\) for \(\sigma \in \left( \widehat{\sigma },\overline{\sigma }\right) \) and \(h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})<\varphi (\sigma )\) otherwise, where \(\left( \widehat{\sigma },\overline{\sigma }\right) \subseteq \left( \sigma _{0},\sigma _{1}\right) \). Examples of such parameters are easily found, Figure 1 as one of which. \(\square \)

1.1.4 A.4 Proof of Lemma 2

Given a contract that deters collusion with accuracy of inference \(\Delta <\max _{s}\Delta \), the agents have incentive to adjust s to raise the accuracy of inference to \(\widetilde{\Delta }>\Delta \) such that (EF) is satisfied at \(\widetilde{\Delta }\), which allows them to benefit from collusion. A contract is collusion-proof only if (EF) is weakly violated at \(\max _{s}\Delta \). To induce coordination, the principal is better off to implement a higher \(\Delta \) that satisfies (EF). If the contract \(\mathbb {C}\) is such that (EF) holds with equality at \(\Delta <\max _{s}\Delta \), the principal has incentive to lower \(\beta \), anticipating that the agents will have incentive to adjust s to raise the accuracy of inference to \(\widetilde{\Delta }>\Delta \) such that (EF) is satisfied at \(\widetilde{\Delta }\). Coalition would be enforced to exert \((a_{H},a_{H})\) at a lower transfer. If it is optimal for her to induce coordination, it is optimal for her to implement the level of trust such that \(\Delta \) is maximized. Thus, the optimal coordination-inducing contract is where (EF) is binding at \(\max _{s}\Delta \).

Given standard normal distribution of the measurement noise,

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta =\left\{ \begin{array}{cc} \Phi \left( \frac{a_{i}^{0}-a_{i}^{'}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}-s\right) -\Phi (-s) &{} \;for\,a_{i}^{0}>a_{i}^{'}\\ -\Phi \left( \frac{a_{i}^{0}-a_{i}^{'}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}+s\right) +\Phi (s) &{} \;for\,a_{i}^{0}<a_{i}^{'} \end{array}\right. , \end{aligned}$$

where the agents collude/coordinate to exert \((a_{i}^{0},a_{j}^{0})\) when the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium is \((a_{i}^{'},a_{j}^{'})\). A contract that deters collusion implements \(a_{i}^{'}>a_{i}^{0}\) while a contract that induce coordination implements \(a_{i}^{0}>a_{i}^{'}\). In the former case, \(\frac{\partial \Delta }{\partial s}\gtreqless 0\) if \(\phi (s)\gtreqless \phi \left( s-\frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\right) \), which holds if \(s\lesseqgtr \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\). In the latter case, \(\frac{\partial \Delta }{\partial s}\gtreqless 0\) if \(\phi (-s)\gtreqless \phi \left( \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}-s\right) \), which holds if \(s\lesseqgtr \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\). The optimal threshold of believed unilateral deviation satisfies \(s^{*}\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}=\frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2}\) , at which the maximum accuracy of mutual inference is \(\Delta ^{*}=\Phi \left( \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\right) -\Phi \left( -\frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\right) \). It is then straightforward that the optimal threshold of believed unilateral deviation \(s^{*}\) and the maximum accuracy of mutual inference \(\Delta ^{*}\) are both increasing in the correlation of measurement noise. \(\square \)

1.1.5 A.5 Proof of Proposition 3

The enforcement constraint is rearranged as \(\Delta ^{*}\ge \frac{1-\delta }{\delta }\left( \frac{\eta -\alpha }{\alpha +\beta -\eta }\right) \) when collusion is deterred or when coordination is induced to implement \((a_{H},a_{H})\) in equilibrium. Rearranging (CP) and (CI) given \(\Delta ^{*}\) results in the same constraint. The optimal team incentive is then straightforward from Lemma 2 and the proof of Proposition 1 in A.2, with \(\widehat{\beta }_{CP}=\frac{(h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*})-\sigma )\eta }{1+h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*})^{2}-2\sigma h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*})}<0\) when \(\delta <\widehat{\delta }_{CP}\equiv \frac{\sigma }{(1-\sigma )\Delta ^{*}+\sigma }\) and \(\widehat{\beta }_{CI}=\frac{r(h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*})-\sigma )\eta -(1-h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*}))(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r(1+h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*})^{2}-2\sigma h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*}))}\) when \(\delta >\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\equiv \frac{r\sigma \eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}{r((1-\sigma )\Delta ^{*}+\sigma )\eta +(a_{H}-a_{L})}\), IPR is optimal if otherwise. As \(\Delta ^{*}=\max _{s}\Delta \ge \Delta _{s}\) for any \(\sigma \) by definition, \(h(\delta ,\Delta ^{*})>h(\delta ,\Delta _{s})\), so \(\widehat{\beta }_{CP}>\beta _{CP}\) and \(\widehat{\beta }_{CI}>\beta {}_{CI}\). In addition, \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\le \delta _{CI}\) and \(\widehat{\delta }_{CP}\le \delta _{CP}\) as \(\Delta ^{*}\ge \Delta _{s}\). \(\square \)

1.1.6 A.6 Proof of Proposition 4

By the proof of Proposition 2 in A.3, \(\widehat{\delta }_{CP}\) and \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\) are increasing (decreasing) in \(\sigma \) if \(\frac{\partial \Delta ^{*}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta ^{*}}<(>)\frac{1}{1-\sigma }\) and \(\frac{\partial \Delta ^{*}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{\sigma }{\Delta ^{*}}<(>)\frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\frac{\sigma }{1-\sigma }\). Since \(\frac{\sigma }{\varphi (\sigma )}<1\), for all \(\sigma \)such that \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\) is increasing in \(\sigma \), \(\widehat{\delta }_{CP}\) is also increasing in \(\sigma \). As \(\lim _{\sigma \rightarrow 1}\Delta ^{*}=1\) and \(\frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\ge 1\) with equality at \(\sigma =1\), \(\frac{\partial \Delta ^{*}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{1-\sigma }{\Delta ^{*}}<\frac{1}{\varphi (\sigma )}\) and \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\) is increasing for sufficiently high correlations. As \(\lim _{\sigma \rightarrow 0}\left( \frac{\partial \Delta ^{*}}{\partial \sigma }\frac{1-\sigma }{\Delta ^{*}}\right) =0<\frac{1}{\varphi (0)}\), \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\) is increasing for sufficiently low correlations as well.

For intermediate level of correlations, due to the special form of normal CDF, I proceed by fixing the exogenous threshold s and \(\sigma \) at the levels such that \(\delta _{CP}\) is decreasing in \(\sigma \) and compare \(\Delta _{\sigma }^{*}\equiv \frac{\partial \Delta ^{*}}{\partial \sigma }=\phi \left( \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\right) \frac{\sigma (a_{H}-a_{L})}{2\sqrt{(1-\sigma ^{2})^{3}}}\) with \(\Delta _{\sigma }^{s}\equiv \frac{\partial \Delta _{s}}{\partial \sigma }=\phi \left( \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}-s\right) \frac{\sigma (a_{H}-a_{L})}{\sqrt{(1-\sigma ^{2})^{3}}}\). The ratio \(\frac{\Delta _{\sigma }^{s}}{\Delta _{\sigma }^{*}}\gtreqless 1\) if \(\frac{\phi \left( 2x-s\right) }{\phi \left( x\right) }\gtreqless \frac{1}{2}\) where \(x\equiv \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\). Define y such that \(\phi (y)\equiv \frac{1}{2}\cdot \phi \left( \frac{a_{H}-a_{L}}{2\sqrt{1-\sigma ^{2}}}\right) \). For \((a_{H}-a_{L})\) such that \(2x-s\in (-y,y)\), \(\frac{\Delta _{\sigma }^{s}}{\Delta _{\sigma }^{*}}>1\), so that whenever \(\delta _{CI}\) and \(\delta _{CP}\) are increasing, \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\) and \(\widehat{\delta }_{CP}\) are increasing as well, and when \(\delta _{CI}\) and \(\delta _{CP}\) are decreasing, it is not necessary that \(\widehat{\delta }_{CI}\) and \(\widehat{\delta }_{CP}\) are decreasing as well. This condition rules out extreme cases in which \(a_{H}-a_{L}\) is so large or so small that how inference is made becomes trivial. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Su, A.PJ. Team incentives with imperfect mutual inference. Int J Game Theory 48, 687–712 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-018-00656-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-018-00656-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation