Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The ins and outs of unemployment over different time horizons

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We devise a decomposition for the level of the unemployment rate that allows the assessment of the contributions of the various flow rates in the labor market over different time horizons. In particular, the decomposition allows one to recover the contributions of the flow rates in the long-run projection of the unemployment rate as in the steady-state decomposition widely used in the literature. We apply our methodology for data from the USA and Brazil. The results show that the relative contribution of the flows to the variance of the cyclical component of unemployment is sensitive to the time horizon of the projected unemployment rate. The changes in relative contributions of some flows are so prominent that their rankings change over time. These qualitative changes are more significant for Brazil than for the USA. Our results also evince that the steady-state approximation of the unemployment rate performs relatively worse in the former country. We take these findings as supporting evidence for considering the use of projected unemployment rate over shorter time horizons as an alternative to the steady-state approximation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, e.g., Darby et al. (1986), Blanchard and Diamond (1990), Hall (2005), Shimer (2007, 2012), Yashiv (2007), Petrolongo and Pissarides (2008), Elsby et al. (2009), Fujita and Ramey (2009), Smith (2011), Elsby et al. (2013), Hertweck and Sigrist (2015) and Gomes (2015).

  2. Shimer (2007) was eventually published in 2012, but the 2007 version had a great influence on the papers published before 2012.

  3. The sample of countries considered by Elsby et al. (2013) are as follows: Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, the UK and the USA.

  4. Elsby et al. (2013) had an earlier working paper version: Elsby et al. (2008). Building on their work, Smith (2011) develops a non-steady-state decomposition method for a three-state labor market that is similar to their decomposition.

  5. In particular, their expressions (15) and (16) (p. 541) explicit the structure of what they call the contribution of the outflow and the inflow rates to unemployment, respectively.

  6. In “Appendix B,” we implement the extensively used continuous time adjustment proposed by Shimer (2012) to correct for potential cyclical time aggregation bias.

  7. Typically, the elements of Eq. (1) are estimated from longitudinal household surveys. In what follows, we abstract the sampling error and attrition problems that affect the accuracy of the estimation of those elements.

  8. The equation system in (1) can then be represented in matrix notation as:

    \( \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {p_{et} } \\ {p_{ut} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\pi_{t} \left( {e,e} \right)} & {\pi_{t} \left( {u,e} \right)} \\ {\pi_{t} \left( {e,u} \right)} & {\pi_{t} \left( {u, u} \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {p_{et - 1} } \\ {p_{ut - 1} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {1 - s_{t} } & {f_{t} } \\ {s_{t} } & {1 - f_{t} } \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {p_{et - 1} } \\ {p_{ut - 1} } \\ \end{array} } \right], \)

    where \( f_{t} = \pi_{t} \left( {u,e} \right) \) and \( s_{t} = \pi_{t} \left( {e,u} \right). \).

  9. The \( \beta {\text{s}} \) can be computed from regressions of each time-varying component in (5) (i.e.,\( v0_{t + h} ,vs_{t + h} ,\; {\text{and}}\; vf_{t + h} \)) on the projected unemployment rate \( u_{t + h} \).

  10. This is shown in “Appendix A” using the matrix notation that will be introduced in the next subsection.

  11. For example, in the three-state model with \( \left( {i,j} \right) = \left( {2,3} \right),\psi_{t}^{2,3} \) is the following matrix:

    \( \psi \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {2,3} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right) = \psi_{t}^{2,3} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {1 - \bar{\pi }\left( {2,1} \right) - \bar{\pi }\left( {3,1} \right)} & {\bar{\pi }\left( {1,2} \right)} & {\bar{\pi }\left( {1,3} \right)} \\ {\bar{\pi }\left( {2,1} \right)} & {1 - \bar{\pi }\left( {1,2} \right) - \bar{\pi }\left( {3,2} \right)} & {\pi_{t} \left( {2,3} \right) } \\ {\bar{\pi }\left( {3,1} \right)} & {\bar{\pi }\left( {3,2} \right)} & {1 - \pi_{t} \left( {2,3} \right) - \bar{\pi }\left( {1,3} \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right] \).

  12. Like the two-state context, the \( \beta \)s can be obtained by regressing the time series of each time-varying component of Eq. (12) (i.e., \( u_{0t + h} \) and \( u_{ijt + h} , \forall i \ne j) \) on the projected unemployment rate \( u_{t + h}. \)

  13. The evidence on the presence of time aggregation bias in monthly gross flows in the USA is substantial (e.g., Elsby et al. (2009), Fujita and Ramey (2009), and Shimer (2012)). However, there is a debate on whether there is cyclical bias from time aggregation that affects unemployment decompositions considered here and in the related literature. Nekarda (2009) shows evidence that time aggregation in inflows and outflows from unemployment co-move positively with the US business cycle and that these time aggregation effects roughly offset each other, creating no substantial cyclical bias in gross flows. Gomes (2015) presents evidence for the USA that the time aggregation correction does not alter the results of the unemployment decomposition for monthly data. For UK data, Petrolongo and Pissarides (2008) do not find meaningful differences in estimates from the steady-state decomposition when flow rates are adjusted for time aggregation. Smith (2011) works with discrete monthly data for the UK and does not correct for time aggregation.

  14. Elsby et al (2013) proposes a method based on aggregate duration measures of unemployment to complement the measurement of outflows from unemployment for some countries. Their procedure, however, was developed only for a two-state labor market model.

  15. The six metropolitan areas are as follows: Porto Alegre, São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro, Belo Horizonte, Salvador and Recife. Around 40% of the Brazilian population live in those areas. As in the CPS, the PME follows a 4–8–4 rotation scheme so that households are surveyed for four consecutive months, leave the sample for eight months, and are interviewed again for four additional months. One difference between the two surveys is that the CPS’s interviews and reference week are fixed within the month, while the PME’s interviews and reference week are spread over the 4 weeks of the month. We implemented our decomposition method using the partitions of the sample according to the weeks of the interview within the month. Though transitions are still captured on a month-over-month basis, this partition allows checking whether changes that take place across the weeks could affect our results. Though we do not show the results, they are very similar to those presented in Sect. 4.

  16. It is important to bear in mind that we still have data on monthly transitions. One advantage of computing quarterly averages of monthly transitions is that it helps minimizing the influence of high-frequency fluctuations that likely reflect measurement error (Shimer, 2012).

  17. We have also considered alternative data treatments that (1) do not transform the monthly matrices into quarterly matrices, and (2) do not use the X13 and HP filters and instead run regressions that include variables for trend and monthly dummies for seasonality. Overall, the qualitative results were similar for both the short- and the long-run decompositions. The results are available from the authors upon request.

  18. To be more precise and complete, we present in “Appendix C” the correlations between the current and the projected unemployment rates for various time horizons, including the long-run one. The results confirm what is seen in Fig. 1a and b and shows that the correlations tend to diminish over the time horizons for both countries and are systematically higher for the USA.

  19. The results for Brazil are similar to those reported by Attuy (2012).

  20. Equation (11) helps to clarify this point by showing that h is used to project the transition matrix that represents month-over-month transitions in the labor market.

  21. This is done for each country and time horizon by dividing the contribution of the specific flow by the difference between the sum of the contributions of all components of the decomposition and the contribution of the initial state of the labor market.

  22. Our empirical results are for the three-state context but the extension to a greater number of states is straightforward.

  23. Figures analogous to 2 and 3 in the main text are available upon request and confirm the robustness of our results for any time horizon considered for the projected unemployment rate.

References

  • Ahn JH, Hamilton JD (2019) Heterogeneity and unemployment dynamics. J Bus Econ Stat. https://doi.org/10.1080/07350015.2018.1530116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attuy GM (2012) Ensaios sobre Macroeconomia e Mercado de Trabalho, PhD Thesis, Departamento de Economia, Universidade de São Paulo

  • Blanchard O, Diamond P (1990) The cyclical behavior of the gross flows of US workers. Brook Paper Econ Act 2:85–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darby M, Haltiwanger J, Plant M (1986) The ins and outs of unemployment: the ins win, NBER Working Paper 1997

  • Elsby M, Hobijn B, Sahin A (2008) Unemployment dynamics in the OECD, NBER Working Paper No. 14617

  • Elsby M, Michaels R, Solon G (2009) The ins and outs of cyclical unemployment. Am Econ J Macroecon 1:84–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsby M, Hobijn B, Sahin A (2013) Unemployment dynamics in the OECD. Rev Econ Stat 95:530–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita S, Ramey G (2009) The cyclicality of separation and job finding rate. Int Econ Rev 50:415–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomes P (2015) The importance of frequency in estimating labor market transition rates. IZA J Labor Econ. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40172-015-0021-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall R (2005) Job loss, job finding, and unemployment in the U.S. economy over the past fifty years. In: Gertler M, Rogoff K (eds), NBER macroeconomics annual. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 101–137

  • Hertweck MS, Sigrist O (2015) The ins and outs of german unemployment: a transatlantic perspective. Oxford Econ Papers 67:1078–1095

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nekarda C (2009) Understanding unemployment dynamics: the role of time aggregation, mimeo, Federal Reserve Board of Governors

  • Petrolongo B, Pissarides C (2008) The ins and outs of european unemployment. Am Econ Rev 98:256–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimer R (2007) Reassessing the ins and outs of unemployment, NBER Working Paper 13421

  • Shimer R (2012) Reassessing the ins and outs of unemployment. Rev Econ Dyn 15:127–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith J (2011) The ins and outs of UK unemployment. Econ J 121:402–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yashiv E (2007) US Labor market dynamics revisited. Scand J Econ 109:779–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Maira Albuquerque Penna Franca for preparing the Brazilian dataset used in the paper. We are grateful for comments from Gulherme Attuy, André Portela, Eduardo Zylberstajn and from seminars participants at the Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada, Insper, and the 37th Meeting the Brazilian Econometric Society on an earlier version of this paper. Two anonymous referees also made important contributions for this version of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlos Henrique Corseuil.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

All the authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: deriving the convergence to the steady state

For each period \( t \), let \( \pi_{t} \) be the transition matrix, \( p_{t} \) the state probability vector and \( p_{t}^{*} \) its correspondent steady-state vector.

Let the canonical decomposition of the transition matrix be expressed by \( \pi_{t} = \gamma_{t} \varLambda_{t} \gamma_{t}^{ - 1} \), where \( \gamma_{t} \) represents the eigenvectors and \( \varLambda_{t} \) the diagonal matrix of eigenvalues. As the sum of the columns of \( \pi_{t} \) is equal to 1, it has incomplete rank. In the case of a model with three states, \( \pi_{t} \) has rank equal to 2 and therefore \( \varLambda_{t} \) has two eigenvalues whose values are less than 1 and one eigenvalue equal to 1, where the corresponding eigenvector has all components with equal values. This has been confirmed in our empirical analysis for both the USA and Brazil.

Let \( \varLambda_{t} = \chi +\chi_{t} \), where \( \chi = diag\left( {0,0,1} \right) \) and \( \chi_{t} = diag\left( {\lambda_{t}^{1} ,\lambda_{t}^{2} ,0} \right) \), with \( \lambda_{t}^{1} < 1 \) and \( \lambda_{t}^{2} < 1 \). Denoting the state probability vector for the current period by \( p_{t} \), the projection of \( p \) for \( h \) periods ahead is given by the following:

$$ p_{t + h} = \pi_{t}^{h} p_{t} = \gamma_{t} \varLambda_{t}^{h} \gamma_{t}^{ - 1} p_{t} = \gamma_{t} \left( { \chi^{h} +\chi_{t}^{h} } \right)\gamma_{t}^{ - 1} p_{t} = \left( {A_{t} + A_{t + h} } \right)p_{t} , $$

where

  • \( A_{t} = \gamma_{t} \chi^{h} \gamma_{t}^{ - 1} = \left( {a_{t} a_{t} a_{t} } \right)\;{\text{and}}\;A_{t} p_{t} = \left( {a_{t} a_{t} a_{t} } \right)p_{t} = a_{t} , \) for any initial state \( p_{t} \) since the sum of the components of \( p_{t} \) is 1, and

  • \( A_{t + h} = (\gamma_{t} { \chi_{t}^{h}} \gamma_{t}^{ - 1} ) \) is a matrix that converges to the zero matrix as \( h \) grows to infinity. Thus, \( p_{t + h} = a_{t} + A_{t + h} p_{t} \) and \( \lim_{h \to \infty } p_{t + h} = a_{t} \), where \( a_{t} \) represents the steady-state vector of the state probability, i.e., \( a_{t} = p_{t}^{*} \).

Now, if \( p_{t + h} \) converges to \( p_{t}^{*} \), then any well-behaved function of \( p_{t + h} \), say \( g\left( {p_{t + h} } \right) \), should converge to \( g\left( {p_{t}^{*} } \right) \). In particular, the unemployment rate function \( u\left( {p_{t + h} } \right) = u\left( {\pi_{t}^{h} p_{t} } \right) \) should converge to \( u\left( {p_{t}^{*} } \right) = u\left( {F(\pi_{t} } \right)) \).

Following Shimer (2012), the steady-state unemployment rate \( u\left( {F(\pi_{t} )} \right) \) can be decomposed into a sum of terms, one of which can be represented by \( u(F\left( {\psi \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right)} \right) - u\left( {F\left( {\bar{\pi }} \right)} \right), \) where \( \left( {i,j} \right) \) corresponds to a transition between the state \( i \) to a state \( j \ne i \) and the matrix \( \psi \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right) \) is defined in Eq. (10) in the text. The contribution of the transition \( \left( {i,j} \right) \) to steady-state unemployment is given by

$$ \beta_{ij}^{*} = \frac{{\text{cov} \langle u(F\left( {\psi \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right)} \right), u\left( {F\left( {\pi_{t} } \right)} \right)\rangle}}{{\text{var} (u\left( {F\left( {\pi_{t} } \right)} \right)}} . $$
(15)

The prediction of the unemployment rate for \( h \) periods ahead can be written as Eq. (11) of the text:

$$ u_{t + h} \cong \kappa_{h} + \left[ {u\left( {\bar{\pi }^{h + 1} p_{t - 1} } \right) - \kappa_{h} } \right] + \mathop \sum \limits_{i \ne j} \{ u\left( {\psi^{h + 1} \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right)\bar{p}} \right) - \kappa_{h} \} = \kappa_{h} + u_{0t + h} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i \ne j} u_{ijt}^{h} ,\quad \forall h = 1,2, \ldots . $$

We have contributions from the following terms to the projected unemployment rate:

$$ {\text{Transition}}\;\left( {i,j} \right)\!:\beta_{ij}^{h} = \frac{{\text{cov} \langle u\left[ {\psi_{t}^{h + 1} \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right)\bar{p}} \right],u_{t + h} \rangle }}{{\text{var} \left( {u_{t + h} } \right)}}; $$
(16)
$$ {\text{Initial}}\;{\text{state}}\;{\text{of}}\;{\text{the}}\;{\text{labor}}\;{\text{market}}\!:\beta_{0}^{h} = \frac{{\text{cov} \langle u\left( {\bar{\pi }^{h + 1} p_{t - 1} } \right),u_{t + h} \rangle}}{{\text{var} \left( {u_{t + h} } \right)}}. $$
(17)

As \( \psi \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right) \) is a transition matrix, the previous convergence results also apply here, and thus \( u\left( {\psi^{h + 1} \left( {\pi_{t} \left( {i,j} \right);\bar{\pi }} \right)\bar{p}} \right) \) converges to \(u\left( {F\left( {\psi \left( {\pi _{t} \left( {i,j} \right); \bar{\pi}} \right)} \right)} \right) \). Hence, all the elements in (16) converge to their counterparts in (15) (i.e., \( \beta_{ij}^{h} \) converges to \( \beta_{ij}^{*} \), \( \forall i \ne j \)) when \( h \) grows to infinity.

As for \( \beta_{0}^{h} \), note that \( \bar{\pi }^{h + 1} p_{t - 1} = \left( {a + A^{h} } \right)p_{t - 1} = a + A^{h} p_{t - 1} \). As \( A^{h} p_{t - 1} \) converges to zero with \( h \), \( \beta_{0}^{h} = \frac{{\text{cov} \langle u\left( {a + A^{h} p_{t - 1} } \right),u_{t + h} \rangle}}{{\text{var} \left( {u_{t + h} } \right)}} \) also converges to zero.

Appendix B: continuous time correction for time aggregation

In this Appendix, we apply the widely used continuous time correction method put forward by Shimer (2012). For the three-state context, the method converts a discrete time Markovian transition matrix into its continuous time counterpart. The main conditions for the existence and uniqueness of this conversion are that the eigenvalues of the discrete time transition matrix are distinct, real and nonnegative. Fortunately, this is the case for both the US and Brazilian datasets we use. We implement this correction method using the decomposition methodology set out in Sect. 2.2 and the same empirical filters presented in Sect. 3 (i.e., seasonal adjustment, quarterly averages and HP filter). Results for the USA and Brazil are presented for the long-run unemployment rate in Table 3 and for the short-run rate in Table 4.

Table 3 Decomposition of the long-run unemployment rate in the three-state context based on Shimer (2012)’s time aggregation correction method
Table 4 Decomposition of the short-run unemployment rate in the three-state context based on Shimer (2012)’s time aggregation correction method

The comparison of Table 3 and Table 1 in the main text shows that most estimates for the importance of the corresponding flows are quite similar for the steady-state decomposition for the USA. These results are qualitatively similar to those obtained by Shimer (2012, Table 2), but the magnitudes of the contributions are somewhat different. For instance, taking his results for the 1987–2010 period, the relative importance of the ue transition rate (0.51) to the eu rate (0.17) is much higher than the ones we find here (0.35 and 0.26, respectively). Our results show a more balanced role played by the outflow and the inflow rates into unemployment, a pattern also observed in Gomes (2015). Notwithstanding the difference in methodology, sample periods and the usage of a two-state context, this balancing between the outflow and the inflow rates is more in line with the results from other papers in the literature (e.g., Elsby et al. 2009; Fujita and Ramey 2009).

As for Brazil, the main changes between Table 3 and Table 1 are for the iu and ui transitions (0.28 to 0.35 and 0.08 to 0.03, respectively) but these differences do not change the relative importance of the flow rates for explaining the cyclicality of the unemployment rate in that country.

The comparison of Table 4 and Table 2 also shows quite small differences in the estimates for the short-run decomposition for both countries. We conclude that our discrete time results are robust to the continuous time correction proposed by Shimer (2012).Footnote 23

Appendix C: correlation between the current and the projected unemployment rates

In Shimer (2012), the long-run (steady-state) unemployment rate is taken as a good proxy for the current rate in the USA. In our method, one can choose any projection horizon—including the long-run one—as a proxy for the current rate. In this Appendix, we measure the correlation between the projected unemployment rate for different time horizons (\( h \)) and the current unemployment rate for both the USA and Brazil. The figures are displayed in Table 5 for \( h = 1, \ldots ,24 \) months ahead of the current period as well as for the long-run case. The results for the USA show a high and stable correlation throughout the projection horizons, while for Brazil the correlation is high in the short run, declines within the first semester and flattens thereafter. As in Figs. 1a and 1b in the main text, these results confirm that the steady-state unemployment rate is only a good proxy for the current rate in the case of the USA and that shorter time horizons are preferable for Brazil.

Table 5 Correlation between current and projected unemployment rates by time horizon

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Moreira, A., Foguel, M.N. & Corseuil, C.H. The ins and outs of unemployment over different time horizons. Empir Econ 60, 2533–2556 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01845-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01845-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation