Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Import penetration and returns to tasks: recent evidence from the Peruvian labour market

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides original evidence on the impact of import penetration on wages of individuals performing manual/cognitive task-intensive jobs in the Peruvian labour market. Matching labour force surveys with task indicators from the us O*Net database and with information on industry- and occupation-specific import exposure, we build a continuous measure of manual intensity to uncover the heterogeneous effect of import penetration on workers’ wages. In order to tackle the endogeneity hampering the consistent estimation of our effects of interest, we combine an identification strategy based on heteroskedasticity with the traditional instrumental variable approach. We find that workers employed in highly cognitive/less manual-intensive jobs in the Peruvian manufacturing sectors are positively affected by industry-specific import penetration. This evidence is confirmed and magnified for the whole economy when the effects of occupation-specific import exposure are addressed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: WITS-COMTRADE 2003–2009. Authors’ own elaborations

Fig. 2

Source: epe 2004–2009, wits-comtrade, unido Industry database. Authors’ own elaborations

Fig. 3

Source: Authors’ own elaboration based on results of Table 5 and 6. The marginal effect in a is computed using the ols estimation results reported in Column [2] of Table 5, and confidence bands are based on cluster-robust standard errors. The marginal effect in b is computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [6] of Table 6, and confidence bands are based on cluster-bootstrapped standard errors

Fig. 4

Source: Authors’ own elaboration based on results of Table 7. The marginal effects in a are computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [1] of Table 7, and confidence bands are based on cluster-robust standard errors. The marginal effect in b is computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [2] of 7, and confidence bands are based on cluster-bootstrapped standard errors

Fig. 5

Source: Authors’ own elaboration based on results of Table 7. The marginal effect in a is computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [1] of Table 7, and confidence bands are based on cluster-robust standard errors. The marginal effect in b is computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [2] of 7, and confidence bands are based on cluster-bootstrapped standard errors

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On average the country annually grew by about 6.5% between 2002 and 2008 and, in the aftermath of the recent global crisis, it kept on growing at a similar pace (World Bank 2015).

  2. The weight of exports on GDP rose from 16% in 2001 to 24% in 2013 and Peru’s average MFN rate declined from 10.7% in 2004 to 3.4% in 2013 over the same period, one of the lowest in the continent. Consequently, imports rose from 18% to 26% of GDP over the same period (World Bank 2015).

  3. Namely, from the maximum peak of 18% in 2007 to 15% in 2013 (World Bank 2015).

  4. Muendler (2008) explores the evolution of employment in the aftermath of Brazil’s trade reforms and documents for Brazil a marked occupation downgrading and a simultaneous education upgrading within the traded sector of Brazil. Also, exporters experienced a severe employment downsizing. Currie and Harrison (1997) examined the employment effects of trade reforms in Morocco and similarly found that, although manufacturing employment was, on average, unaffected, exporters and highly exposed firms were characterised by significant employment losses.

  5. Our work is also near to that of Amiti and Davis (2011) who study the effect of trade liberalisation on manufacturing wages in Indonesia. Using data from 1991 to 2000, the authors test their model on the impact of final and intermediate input tariff cuts on workers’ wages and find that the effects are heterogeneous depending on how firms engage in the global economy. They, nonetheless, do not distinguish between skilled and low-skilled workers. For the same country Lee and Wie (2015b) show that the diffusion of foreign technologies through imports and foreign direct investment caused demand to shift towards more skilled labour and increased wage inequality.

  6. In order to assess whether dealing with the two approaches separately is a correct empirical strategy, we estimated the complete model for manufacturing workers only including both import penetration measures and both sets of fixed-effects. No relevant bias emerges from the estimation results. Also, we rerun the baseline ols industry and occupation-specific IP models with the inclusion of both occupation and industry fixed-effects to ascertain whether the omission of occupation (industry) fixed-effects in the industry (occupation)-level model could bias our estimates. As insights are substantially unchanged with respect to the empirical analysis below, and for the sake of brevity, we decided not to show this set of results, which are available upon request.

  7. Namely, \({ EXP}^{{ US}}_{jt}\) = (us exports of sector j going to non-lac)/(us production of sector j). Then \({ EXP}^{{ US}}_{kt}\) is computed according to Equation (10) in Sect. 4.

  8. Nevertheless, in the robustness checks we use alternative IVs to further control for the potential existence of common demand shocks.

  9. In a simple setting, workers can choose between two occupations, say white versus blue collar jobs, and are characterised by different skill endowments, motor and cognitive skills. Workers will self-select into the occupation returning the highest premium to the skill they are endowed with. For instance, cognitive-skilled workers choose to work as white collars if cognitive skills are more rewarded in white collar jobs.

  10. In the present setting we characterise occupations by a one-dimensional task measure and consider the sorting of workers into a continuum of occupations, which extends the traditional binary choice Roy model, as opposed to the general task approach in which occupations are described by a bundle of task measures.

  11. It can be argued that information about parents’ educational attainment and occupation could be used as sources of exogenous variation to identify the effects of the tasks performed on wages, similarly to the instrumental variable approach to the estimation of the Mincerian returns to education. However, the survey does not contain information on the family of origin and limiting the analysis to offsprings would considerably restrict the sample.

  12. Notwithstanding, we also provide evidence that our results are robust to the inclusion of a measure of technological change by exploiting a measure of computerisation for the us economy. Also, as the sector–occupation–year mean wage could be endogenous, in the robustness checks we will replace our dependent variable as the log ratio of individual wages over the average wage, therefore preserving a similar framework while treating mean wages as endogenous.

  13. Although the ENAHO survey has some information on individuals’ labour conditions, it has no information on their occupation of employment. The share of informal workers was only available at the 3-digit ISIC Rev. 3 sector level and has been kindly provided by Ana Cisneros Acevedo.

  14. Also, informal workers primarily work in agriculture, rather than in manufacturing and in non-urban areas (CEPLAN 2016). In the Lima metropolitan area—the geographical location of workers in our sample—informal workers account for 56% of total employment in our sample period (WIEGO 2010) compared to roughly 70% for non-agricultural employment in the rest of the country (ILO 2014).

  15. We provide results for the two-step estimator based on uncorrected cluster standard errors as a robustness check.

  16. Notice that under the null hypothesis of exogeneity, standard errors need not to be corrected for the presence of generated regressors. In this respect, the procedure of testing for exogeneity is similar to that described by Wooldridge (2010) when illustrating the Hausman test in the presence of heteroskedasticity.

  17. We collect data up to 2011. In 2010 classification of sectors of activity changed from isic Rev. 3 to isic Rev. 4 and, due to the lack of a proper fit between the two classifications, 2010 and 2011 are not considered in this work.

  18. From the initial sample we only retain workers working in the private sector and therefore drop those working in electricity, gas, steam and hot water supply; collection, purification and distribution of water; public administration and defence and compulsory social security.

  19. Our main results are robust to the inclusion of workers working in these sectors. Results are not shown for the sake of brevity, but they are available upon request.

  20. Actually, own calculations on wits-comtrade data reveal that capital goods and industrial supplies represent about 75% of non-fuel and non-primary imports. Furthermore, Fig. 7 in “Appendix A” shows that a large, although slightly declining, share of manufacturing imports originate from the eu and the usa At the same time, China is gaining increasing importance to the detriment of the Latin American neighbouring countries. In particular, Peru mostly imports capital goods and industrial supplies from the eu, usa and China. Purchases from the latter country, though, are also characterised by a non-negligible share of final goods (roughly 20%).

  21. The unido Industrial Statistic Database (indstat4) contains highly disaggregated data on the manufacturing sector. It provides, among other, information on output levels up to the 4-digit level of the isic Rev. 3. More information on how to access the database is available at the following link: http://www.unido.org/resources/statistics/statistical-databases.html.

  22. Although epe provides the 4-digit isic code of sectors where individuals are employed, trade flows from wits-comtrade are only available at the 3-digit level. For this reason, we attribute the same trade and output flows to individuals working in different 4-digit sectors who, nonetheless, belong to the same 3-digit sector. The slightly more aggregate sector detail has the advantage of producing sector cells with a not too small number of individuals.

  23. It was not possible to compute import penetration measures for the primary and service sectors. In both cases detailed information on sectors’ output to be included at the denominator of the formula was not available. Also, as far as service sectors are concerned, it is worth highlighting that most of these sectors are non-tradable and for those few tradable service sectors detailed information on imports is unavailable.

  24. See “Appendix A” for the details on o*net and for the occupation correspondence table.

  25. In this respect, Handel (2012) shows that uso*net indicators are highly correlated with occupation-level measures of job characteristics for a set of advanced economies from the European Social Survey and the International Social Survey Programme. Also, o*net-based cognitive and physical skill measures highly reflect the education level by occupation for countries in the European Labour Force Surveys, among which a few middle-income economies are present. We were prevented from running a similar comparison for Peru on the basis of our data, due to the lack of reliable information on years of schooling.

  26. Potential lack of comparability notwithstanding, our empirical setting accounts for the measurement error in MS, which is addressed via the kv-iv estimation approach.

  27. As an example, consider the o*net abilities “Manual dexterity” and “Fluency of Ideas”. Raw o*net scores for both items range from 1 to 5. In a sample of us workers we can normalise scores by dividing them for the maximum value. For “Bookbinders and related workers” (ISCO88 code \(=\) 7345) the raw score of “Manual dexterity” equals 3.44 which corresponds to 0.688 when rescaled, while the score for “Fluency of Ideas” is 2.185, corresponding to a rescaled value of 0.437. When normalising raw scores according to the distribution of workers across occupations in the Peruvian labour market “Manual dexterity” takes the value 0.395, meaning that almost 40% of the working population has an intensity of manual dexterity lower than that of bookbinders, which makes it a fairly manual-intensive job. At the same time, “Fluency of Ideas” takes the value 0.067 meaning that only 6.7% of the population has an intensity of fluency of ideas lower than that of bookbinders, which makes it a low cognitive-intensive occupation. By accounting for the peculiarity of the Peruvian labour market, this job requires more “Manual dexterity” than in the usa.

  28. More details on exact correlations between our task indicators and those used in the literature are available in “Appendix A”.

  29. In all the specifications presented in Table 5 and 6, individual-level controls are suppressed from the tables for the sake of brevity. Nonetheless, complete results for the baseline specifications and for first-stage estimation results are available in Tables 11, 12 and 13 in “Appendix B”.

  30. Calculations are as follows: from coefficients estimates in Column [2]: \((0.139-0.109*{ MS})*\Delta { IP}^{09/04}_{j}\) with \({ MS}=0.27\) for engineers and \(\Delta { IP}^{09/04}_{j}=0.12\).

  31. Calculations are as follows: from coefficient estimates in Column [6]: \((0.752-1.026*{ MS})*\Delta { IP}^{09/04}_{k}\) with \({ MS}=0.27\) and \(\Delta { IP}^{09/04}_{k}=-0.02\) for engineers and \({ MS}=0.85\) and \(\Delta { IP}^{09/04}_{k}=0.20\) for assemblers.

  32. If this were the case, however, this would imply that industry-/occupation-specific human capital is less relevant for highly cognitive-intensive activities. Ebenstein et al. (2014), instead, for routine workers in the usa switching out of manufacturing, interpret wage losses as stemming from the loss of industry and, especially, occupation-specific tenure.

  33. Biscourp and Kramarz (2007) on French firms document that imports of both intermediates and final goods are positively related to skill upgrading within firms and industries.

  34. More specifically, from WITS-COMTRADE we retrieved data on Peruvian import flows at 6-digit HS 2002 and jointly reclassified these product-level import flows according to the BEC and to the ISIC Rev. 3 classifications by means of readily available crosswalks from UNCTAD and RAMON websites. As a consequence, we were able to dissect, from the bulk of imports referable to an ISIC sector, import flows pertaining to each of the BEC categories. We classified as capital imports of capital goods (BEC one-digit code 4) and processed industrial supplies (BEC code 22). Remaining imports are mostly made up of final goods, as the incidence of primary goods is negligible or even non-existent in industrial sectors.

  35. http://faculty.som.yale.edu/peterschott/sub_international.htm.

  36. In this regard, we follow Autor et al. (2003), who build a measure of computerisation as the sum of capital stocks of private non-residential fixed assets by industry. In particular, they define the computer stock as the sum of stocks in mainframe computers, personal computers, packaged and custom software, printers, terminals, storage devices and other computers and peripheral equipment manufacturing. All stock variables are measured in constant 2009 dollars and classified according to the BEA industry classification which is directly comparable to the 1997 North American Industry Classification System (NAICS).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Autor D (2011) Skills, tasks and technologies: implications for employment and earnings. No. chap. 12 in Handbook of labour economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson GH, Price B (2016) Import competition and the great us employment sag of the 2000s. J Labor Econ 34(1):S141–S198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aedo C, Hentschel J, Moreno M, Luque J (2012) From occupations to embedded skills: a cross-country comparison. Technical report 6560, World Bank

  • Amiti M, Davis DR (2011) Trade, firms, and wages. Rev Econ Stud 79:1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amuedo-Dorantes C, de la Rica S (2011) Complements or substitutes? Task specialization by gender and nativity in Spain. Labour Econ 18(5):697–707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist JD, Evans WN (1998) Children and their parents’ labor supply: evidence from exogenous variation in family size. Am Econ Rev 88(3):450–477

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashournia D, Munch J, Nguyen D (2014) The impact of chinese import penetration on danish firms and workers. Technical report, IZA

  • Attanasio O, Goldberg KP, Pavcnik N (2004) Trade reforms and income inequality in Colombia. J Dev Econ 74:331–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor DH, Dorn D (2013) The growth of low-skill service jobs and the polarization of the US labor market. Am Econ Rev 103(5):1553–1597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor DH, Handel MJ (2013) Putting tasks to the test: human capital, job tasks, and wages. J Labor Econ 31(S1):S59–S96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor D, Levy F, Murname R (2003) The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Q J Econ 118(4):1279–1333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor DD, David H, Hanson GH (2013) The china syndrome: local labor market effects of import competition in the United States. Am Econ Rev 103(6):2121–2168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor DD, David H, Hanson GH (2014) Trade adjustment worker level evidence. Q J Econ 129(4):1790–1860

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacolod MP, Blum BS (2010) Two sides of the same coin: U.S. ”residual” inequality and the gender gap. J Hum Resour 45(1):197–242

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R (2006) Globalisation: the great unbundling(s). Working paper, Geneva Graduate Institute of International Studies

  • Balli HO, Sorensen BE (2013) Interaction effects in econometrics. Empir Econ 45:583–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgarten D, Geishecker I, Holger G (2013) Offshoring, tasks, and the skill-wage pattern. Eur Econ Rev 61(C):132–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biscourp P, Kramarz F (2007) Employment, skill structure and international trade: firm-level evidence for France. J Int Econ 72(1):22–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom N, Draca M, Van Reenen J (2015) Trade induced technical change? the impact of Chinese imports on innovation, it and productivity. Rev Econ Stud. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdv039

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas G (1987) Self-selection and the earnings of immigrants. Am Econ Rev 77(4):531–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronars SG, Grogger J (1994) The economic consequences of unwed motherhood: using twin births as a natural experiment. Am Econ Rev 84(5):1141–1156

    Google Scholar 

  • CEPLAN (2016) Economa informal en per: Situacin actual y perspectivas. Technical report, Centro Nacional de Planeamento Estrategico

  • Cisneros-Acevedo C (2016) Trade liberalisation effect in two margins of informality. The peruvian case. Working paper, mimeo University of Nottingham

  • Colantone I, Crinó R (2014) New imported inputs, new domestic products. J Int Econ 92(1):147–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Currie J, Harrison A (1997) Trade reform and labour market adjustment in Morocco. J Labor Econ 15(3):44–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dauth W, Findeisen S, Suedekum J (2014) The rise of the east and the far east: German labor markets and trade integration. J Eur Econ Assoc 12(6):1643–1675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis DR (1996) Trade liberalization and income distribution. Working paper 5693, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Duffy J, Papageorgiou C, Perez-Sebastian F (2004) Capital skill complementarity? Evidence from a panel of countries. Rev Econ Stat 86(1):327–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebenstein A, Harrison A, MacMillan M, Phillips S (2014) Estimating the impact of trade and offshoring on American workers using the current population surveys. Rev Econ Stat 96(4):581–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fajnzylber P, Fernandes A (2009) International economic activities and skilled labour demand: evidence from Brazil and China. Appl Econ 41(5):563–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farré L, Klein R, Vella F (2013) A parametric control function approach to estimating the returns to schooling in the absence of exclusion restrictions: an application to the NLSY. Empir Econ 44:111–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC (2004) Advanced international trade. Theory and evidence. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R, Hanson G (1996) Political economy of trade policy: essays in honor of Jagdish Bhagwati. Chap Foreign investment, outsourcing and relative wages. MIT Press, Boston, pp 89–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R, Hanson G (1997) Foreign direct investment and relative wages: evidende from Maxico’s maquiladoras. J Int Econ 42:371–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R, Hanson G (1999) The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. Q J Econ 114(3):907–940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R, Hanson G (2001) Global production sharing and rising inequality: a survey of trade and wages. NBER working papers 8372, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Galarza FB, Yamada G (2014) Labor market discrimination in Lima, Peru: evidence from a field experiment. World Dev 58:83–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallego FA (2012) Skill premium in Chile: studying skill upgrading in the south. World Dev 40(3):594–609

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg PK, Pavcnik N (2004) Trade, inequality, and poverty: what do we know? evidence from recent trade liberalization episodes in developing countries. NBER working papers 10593, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Goldberg PK, Pavcnik N (2007) Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries. J Econ Lit Am Econ Assoc 45(1):39–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goos M, Manning A (2007) Lousy and lovely jobs: the rising polarization of work in Britain. Rev Econ Stat 89(1):118–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1969) Capital-skill complementarity. Rev Econ Stat 51(4):465–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Rossi-Hansberg E (2006) Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring. NBER working paper 12721, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Handel MJ (2012) Trends in job skill demands in oecd countries. Technical report, The Review of Economics and Statistics

  • Hanson GH (2012) The rise of middle kingdoms: emerging economies in global trade. NBER working paper 17961, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Hanson G, Harrison A (1999) Trade liberalization and wage inequality in Mexico. Ind Labor Relat Rev 52(2):271–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47(1):153–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ, Hotz VJ (1989) Choosing among alternative nonexperimental methods for estimating the impact of social programs: the case of manpower training. J Am Stat Assoc 84(408):862–874

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D (2007) Transportation costs and international trade in the second era of globalization. J Econ Perspect 21(3):131–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D, Jrgensen R, Munch J, Xiang C (2014) The wage effects of offshoring: evidence from Danish matched worker-firm data. Am Econ Rev 104(6):1597–1629. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.6.1597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ILO (2011) Trade and employment from myths to facts. Technical report, International Labour Organization

  • ILO (2014) Trends in informal employment in Peru: 2004–2012. Technical report, International Labour Organization

  • Klein R, Vella F (2009) Estimating the return to endogenous schooling decisions via conditional second moments. J Hum Resour 44(4):1047–1065

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein R, Vella F (2010) Estimating a class of triangular simultaneous equations models without exclusion restrictions. J Econom 154(2):154–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korenman S, Neumark D (1990) Marriage, motherhood, and wages. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Lee JW, Wie D (2015a) Technological change, skill demand, and wage inequality: evidence from Indonesia. World Dev 67:238–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee JW, Wie D (2015b) Technological change, skill demand, and wage inequality: evidence from Indonesia. World Dev 67:238–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu R (2010) Import competition and firm refocusing. Can J Econ 43(2):440–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meschi E, Taymaz E, Vivarelli M (2011) Trade, technology and skills: evidence from Turkish microdata. Labour Econ 18(1):S60–S70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreno M, Nopo H, Saavedra J, Torero M (2012) Detecting gender and racial discrimination in hiring through monitoring intermediation services: the case of selected occupations in metropolitan Lima, Peru. World Dev 40(2):315–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muendler MA (2008) Trade and workforce changeover in Brazil. The analysis of firms and employees: quantitative and qualitative approaches, NBER Chapters. National Bureau of Economic Research Inc, pp 269–308

  • \(\tilde{{\rm N}}\)opo H (2008) Matching as a tool to decompose wage gaps. Rev Econ Stat 90(2):290–299

  • Pavcnik N (2003) What explains skill upgrading in less developed countries? J Dev Econ 71:311–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peri G, Sparber C (2009) Task specialization, immigration, and wages. Am Econ J Appl Econ 1(3):135–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides C (1997) Learning by trading and the returns to human capital in developing countries. World Bank Econ Rev 11(1):17–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raveh O, Reshef A (2016) Capital imports composition, complementarities, and the skill premium in developing countries. J Dev Econ 118:183–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy AD (1951) Some thoughts on the distribution of earnings. Oxf Econ Pap 3(2):135–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WIEGO (2010) Informal economy budget analysis in Peru and metropolitan lima. Technical report, Women in informal employment globalizing and organizing

  • Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. The MIT press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2013) World bank development report 2013. Technical report, World Bank

  • World Bank (2015) World bank development indicators. Online database, World Bank

  • WTO (2007) Trade policy review: Peru. Secretariat report. World Trade Organization

  • WTO (2013) Trade policy review: Peru. Secretariat report. World Trade Organization

  • Yi L, Ng T (2013) Import competition and skill content in U.S. manufacturing industries. Rev Econ Stat 95(4):1404–1417

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessia Lo Turco.

Additional information

We are grateful to Camila Cisneros-Acevedo for sharing Peruvian data on informal labour by sector. We are also grateful to participants at the \(8\mathrm{th}\) International Conference “Economics of Global Interactions: New Perspectives on Trade, Factor Mobility and Development” as well as to three anonymous referees for valuable comments and suggestions. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the affiliated institutions.

Appendices

A Additional material for the data section

1.1 A.1 Additional figures and tables

See Table 8, Figs. 6 and 7.

Table 8 Correlation coefficients between selected individual variables: EPE, 2004–2009.
Fig. 6
figure 6

Source: EY, 2014

Distribution of economic activities in Peru.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Source: WITS-COMTRADE 2003–2009. Authors’ own elaborations

Peruvian imports—shares by market of origin.

1.2 A.2 Description of task indicators

Matchingo*netand EPE We collected information on tasks from the o*net, the Occupational Information Network of the us Department of Labour, which includes, among other information, an abilities survey providing data on 52 abilities required for each o*net-soc2010 occupation. As occupations from the Peruvian Labour Force Surveys are classified according to cno-95 at the three-digit level, it was necessary to find a suitable crosswalk between cno-95 and o*net-soc2010. Using readily available crosswalks, we converted the o*net-soc2010 occupation coding to the isco-88 occupation coding. However, since there was no table of correspondence available, we built a table of correspondence between the cno-95 and the isco-88 based on the description of occupations provided in the two classification schemes (see Table 9 below). This procedure allowed the o*net survey to be linked to the isco-88 coding and then to the Peruvian labour force survey.

Table 9 Table of correspondence between CNO-95 and ISCO-88

Definition of manual and cognitive tasks and comparison with task indicators from extant literature The manual task indicator takes after Peri and Sparber (2009) and, although it only rests on the subset of o*net abilities labelled as “Physical” and “Psychomotor”, it well describes the physical conditions required by the work context. Our proxy turns to be highly correlated (0.92) with the average intensity of the subset of o*net items labelled as “Physical Work Conditions”. Therefore, our definition of manual is exhaustive in terms of the relevant physical and psychomotor abilities required to perform a job. To capture the cognitive nature of a job, instead, we follow Bacolod and Blum (2010) and select a subset of thirteen items from the o*net “Cognitive” abilities section and calculate their average. The resulting proxy fully reflects the information included in the whole section, as its correlation with the mean value of all cognitive abilities included in the section is 0.98. Also, our proxy is highly correlated (0.92) with the mean value of items in the “Mental Work Activities” section; therefore, it wholly captures the extent of mental activities required by a job. Moreover, we compare our task measures with existing ones in the related literature. In particular, we consider the split by Autor and Dorn (2013) who build abstract, non-routine cognitive, routine cognitive, non-routine manual and routine manual task measures. It is worth mentioning that the comparison between our task measures and theirs is not straightforward, due to the fact that the authors hinge on the dot, while we use the o*net database. However, we have built from the o*net database task measures analogous to theirs, and we show corresponding pairwise correlations between them in Table 10. As shown in the table, Manual captures information on Autor and Dorn ’s manual dimension of Non-routine and Routine. Cognitive, instead, is very close to the analytical and interpersonal dimension of Autor and Dorn ’s Abstract measure. Worthy of note is the correlation between our manual and cognitive task indicators which is equal to \(-\,0.52\). This suggests that the two measures give opposite, but not overlapping, indications on the nature of a job.

Table 10 Correlations between MS, manual, cognitive and other literature-based task measures.
Fig. 8
figure 8

Source: Authors’ own elaboration based on results of Table 5 and 6. The marginal effect in a is computed using the ols estimation results reported in Column [2] of Table 5, and confidence bands are based on cluster-robust standard errors. The marginal effect in b is computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [6] of 6, and confidence bands are based on cluster-bootstrapped standard errors

Marginal effects MS, a industry-specific and b occupation-specific baseline models, epe 2004–2009.

Marginal effects of MS Figure 8 shows the marginal effects of MS according to the percentiles of industry- and occupation-specific import penetration measures. In the sector-level model a positive effect of the manual intensity is only recorded on wages of workers employed in sectors that are only modestly exposed to import penetration, that is Peruvian’s comparative advantage sectors. As a matter of fact, in our data the average import exposure of the Food Sector is 8%, of the Textile sector is 15%, of the Apparel sector is 6%, while in comparative disadvantage sectors like Machinery and Transport Equipment the import exposure is about 48% and 43%, respectively. Turning to the effect of manual intensity on wages according to the percentiles of the occupation-specific import penetration measure, the effect is negative and declining as the import exposure of an occupation increases. As an example, manual intensity starts exerting a negative effect on wages for blacksmiths and metal workers whose import exposure is about 15% and 18%, respectively. Its effect worsens for chemical-processing plant operators whose import penetration measure is about 27% and reaches the lowest value for fibre preparers and shoe-makers whose import penetration measures are about 50% and 58%, respectively.

B Complete baseline estimation results

See Table 11, 12 and 13.

Table 11 Wage equation—industry-specific IP baseline model, epe 2004–2009
Table 12 Wage equation—occupation-specific IP baseline model, epe 2004–2009
Table 13 Wage equation—first-stage estimation results: manual intensity (MS) and import penetration (IP), epe 2004–2009

C Robustness checks

1.1 C.1 Instrumental variables

The first part of this exercise elaborates on the choice of our instrumental variable for the identification of import penetration effects. In particular, our concern is on the potentially improper control for common product demand shocks between Peru and the remaining low- and middle-income economies outside lac, which may threaten the exogeneity of \({ Exp}^{US}_{lt}\). Following Autor et al. (2013), we adopt a gravity-based approach where we instrument import penetration in Peru with the inferred relative change of us comparative advantage and market access vis-à-vis that of Peru. In particular, a standard gravity model of trade (Feenstra 2004) sees exports from country A to country B as dependent on the export capability—e.g. sectoral productivity—of country A and on transport costs between the two economies. Therefore, we estimated a gravity model by regressing the log difference of exports from the usa and Peru to the world on industry and partner country dummies and took the residual which should measure changes in the relative export performance of usa to Peru due to changes in the former’s comparative advantages and relative market access. The gravity equation we estimate is:

$$\begin{aligned} lnExp^{US}_{jkt}-lnExp^{Peru}_{jkt}= \alpha _{j} + \alpha _{k} +\epsilon _{jkt}, \end{aligned}$$
(13)

where \({ Exp}^{US}_{jkt}\) and \({ Exp}^{Peru}_{jkt}\) are us and Peruvian sector j exports to country k and \(\alpha _{j}\), respectively, and \(\alpha _{k}\) are sector and country fixed-effects, respectively. The latter are meant to purge from any possible demand conditions in the foreign country k, while sector fixed-effects are meant to capture initial us comparative advantages relative to Peru. As a consequence, relying on a standard theoretical derivation of the gravity model (Feenstra 2004), residuals from the above equation are expected to capture differential time-varying comparative advantage and trade costs of the usa relative to Peru for sector j. Then, we estimate gravity model 13 for us and Peru 3-digit ISIC exports to the world over the period 2004–2009 and take the mean change in the residuals for industry j across destination markets k between year t and t − 1. When the change in residual is multiplied by Peruvian imports from the world in industry j in the pre-sample year 2003, we obtain the change in Peruvian imports predicted by Peruvian major partner’s changing comparative advantage and falling trade costs. The results of the estimated kv-iv model with the gravity-based instrument are presented in Columns [1] and [4] of Table 14. Notice that, even though the gravity-based instrument does not exhibit strong explanatory power in predicting import penetration, our main findings hold for both the industry- and occupation-specific models.

Table 14 Wage equation—robustness to alternative iv, epe 2004–2009

In the same line, we further investigate this issue by adopting an alternative instrumental variable approach based on transport costs. We retrieve us import flows from Peter Schott’s web pageFootnote 35, and we calculate transport costs tc as the ratio of import charges—the costs of shipping a good from the source to the home market—over import value and we run the following regression:

$$\begin{aligned} tc_{us, g, k}= & {} \alpha + \beta _{1}\,\frac{import\ weight_{us,g,k}}{import\ value_{us, g,k}} + \beta _{2}\, distance_{us, k} \nonumber \\&+ \beta _{3}\, oil_{t} + \beta _{4} distance_{us, k}* oil_{t} \nonumber \\&+ \beta _{5} \frac{import\, weight_{us,g,k}}{import\, value_{us, g, k}}*distance_{us, k}* oil_{t} + \epsilon _{g,k,t} \end{aligned}$$
(14)

where \(import\, weight_{us, g, k}\) measures the weight of us imports of HS2002 6-digit good g from country k, \(distance_{us, k}\) measures geodesic distance between the usa and country k (available from CEPII), and \(oil_{t}\) measures oil price at time t. Once we estimate this model on us imports, we take \(\beta \) coefficient estimates and calculate the model predictions of transport costs on the bases of Peruvian right-hand side regressors based on Peruvian HS2002 6-digit import flows, quantities and source countries available from the CEPII BACI database. Then, we aggregate transport costs at the ISIC 3-digit level across goods and source countries weighting the latter by their share in the ISIC sector j in the pre-sample year 2003.

Corresponding results are presented in Columns [2] and [5] of Table 14. Notice that our main results still remain unaffected by the choice of an alternative instrumental variable, even though there is a statistically significant correlation between transport cost instrument and our sector-level import penetration measure.

These results provide two main takeaways. First, \({ Exp}^{US}_{lt}\) does not seem to carry residual correlation with common demand shocks between Peru and non-lac low- and middle-income countries, since the kv-iv strategy based on \({ Exp}^{US}_{lt}\) yields very similar results to those obtained with the gravity and transport costs-based instruments. Second, even though these instrumental variables may reveal to be rather weak, especially in predicting the occupation-level import penetration measure, the combination of the iv strategy with identification through heteroskedasticity provides stable and reliable results. This last finding is corroborated by the results in Columns [3] and [6] in Table 14, where we drop the instrumental variable and rely only on heteroskedasticity for identification.

1.2 C.2 Model misspecification

The second part of our robustness analysis looks into model misspecifications possibly arising from further uncontrolled heterogeneity in the sample and from the choice of the functional form of the wage regression equation.

With respect to the choice of our sample, we first look at the period between 2004 and 2008. Despite Peru’s exceptional growth during the whole period of analysis, the worldwide economic crisis has hit the country hard in 2009. We consider this feature in our baseline specification by including the interaction of sector or occupation fixed-effects with a dummy for 2009. Nevertheless, for robustness, we also limit our analysis to 2008 so that we eliminate any source of negative exogenous shock that may affect our findings. Results reported in Columns [1] and [5] of Table 15 confirm our main results.

Furthermore, we restrict our sample by considering only the first time each worker is interviewed. In this case our sample is a pure cross section consisting of individuals observed only once. As individuals appear up to four times in the 2004–2006 waves and up to two times in the 2007–2009 waves (see Sect. 4), we want to check that our inference is not inflated by repeated measurements and/or affected by a different survey design across the years. In Columns [2] and [6] of Table 15 we instead report the estimation results for the sample of cross sections. At least for the occupation-level import penetration measure, which is the specification that provides a significant effect of import penetration on wages according to the occupation manual intensity, the results confirm our main findings.

As for the choice of the functional form, we look into possible misspecification due to omitted quadratic terms. Balli and Sorensen (2013) argue that interaction terms are a partial specification of a multiple regression where explanatory variables represent the terms of a Taylor expansion approximating the functional relationship between the dependent and the independent variables. As such, the set of covariates should include at least quadratic terms. We show the result of this exercise in Columns [3] and [7] where we add the quadratic terms for IP and MS. We report only the results obtained by ols since managing endogeneity of the quadratic terms as well proved computationally very cumbersome in our context. We show that the statistical significance of our main variable of interest, i.e. the interaction term IP\(\times \)MS, is not the result of the omitted quadratic terms.

Last, we elaborate on our choice to deal with sample selection by means of a linear control function approach based on Heckman and Hotz (1989). The standard approach would be to embed Heckman ’s (1979) two-step strategy in the estimation framework laid out so far. The latter amounts to specifying an equation for the binary participation \(s_i\), for \(i=1, \ldots , n\) as

$$\begin{aligned} s_i = 1\left\{ w^*_i > 0 \right\} \qquad w^*_i = \varvec{S}_i' \varvec{\vartheta } + \zeta _i \quad \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where \(1\{ \cdot \}\) is an indicator function and \(s_i\) takes value 1 if worker i is employed and zero otherwise, \(w_i^*\) is worker i’s reservation wage, and \(\varvec{S}_i\) is a set of covariates including \(X_i\) and possibly exclusion restrictions. Under the assumption that \(\zeta _i \sim N(0,1)\), the error term \(\varepsilon _{ilt}\) in Eq. (1) is assumed to have expected value conditional on participation

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {E}\left( \varepsilon _{ilt}| s_i = 1 \right) = \lambda \left( \varvec{S}_i' \varvec{\vartheta } \right) \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where \(\lambda (\cdot )\) is the inverse Mills ratio \(\varphi (\cdot )/\Phi (\cdot )\), with \(\varphi (\cdot )\) and \(\Phi (\cdot )\) being the standard normal density and distribution function, respectively. Under Eq. (15) and (16) estimation then follows a standard two-step approach.

As argued in Sect. 3.2.2, this sort of strategy poses an additional problem in this context. Standard errors for the wage equation have to be clustered at either the sector or the occupation–year level to correct for the possible misleading inference arising from repeated measurements of MS and IP across workers. When we reject the null hypotheses of exogeneity of MS and IP, standard errors have to be cluster-bootstrapped. In this context, the two-step approach would require us to resample clusters of sectors or occupations for the non-employed, which are obviously undefined.

In order to overcome this issue, we decided to rely on the assumption that workers’ employment participation follows the mechanism of selection on observables, that is the dependence between earnings and participating in the labour market is approximated by a set of observable covariates describing the family composition (see Sect. 3.2.2), that we include in \(\varvec{X}_i\). This amounts to assuming that

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {E}\left( \varepsilon _{ilt}| s_i = 1 \right) = \mathrm {E}\left( \varepsilon _{ilt}| \varvec{X}_i \right) = \varvec{X}_i' \varvec{\beta } \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where we also specify the dependence between \(\varepsilon _i\) and \(\varvec{X}_i\) as linear. This approach was first put forward by Heckman and Hotz (1989) to deal with selection on observables. Notice that, in the context of our economic application, we must assume that neither \({ MS}_k\) nor \({ IP}_{lt}\), with \(l=j\) or \(l=k\), impact the participation decision.

Table 15 Wage equation—robustness to misspecification

In Columns [4] and [8] of Table 15, we compare our results with those based on Eq. (16). Worthy of note is that the results in the table are based on uncorrected standard errors. Our results are robust and prove that the coefficients of interest are not sensitive to our approach based on the linear control function estimator.

Table 16 Wage equation—robustness to omitted variables

1.3 C.3 Omitted variables

This section presents a sensitivity analysis of our main model to the potential omission of relevant confounding factors that might affect productivity levels and/or wages according to workers’ degree of manual intensity.

First, we account for the fact that the equivalent effects of import penetration and technological change (see Sect. 3.2.2) may vary with a job’s manual intensity. As technological improvements, in the form of more automated production processes, complement low manual-intensive workers but substitute high manual-intensive workers, our concern is that this unaccounted effect may influence our coefficient of main interest, \({ IP}_{lt}\times { MS}_k\), \(l=j,k\). To this purpose, we add to our main specification the interaction term Mean wages\( \times { MS}_k\) which should capture the heterogeneous effect of technology and informal labour on workers with different levels of manual intensity (see Columns [1] and [5] in Table 16).

As an alternative measure of technological progress, we add to our main set of covariates a measure of ict capital, at the sector or occupation level depending on the specification, to directly control for the evolution of technology in Peru. As previously stated, we unfortunately lack data on technology indicators for Peru and for this reason we decided to use information for the world technology leader, the usa. For this purpose, we retrieved industry-level data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (bea) of the us Department of Commerce on ict capital equipment stocks.Footnote 36 We take the 2003 pre-sample value of \(ICT_{{ Kap}}\) and multiply it by a trend to match to our data as a proxy of potential technological change in Peru. Taking the pre-sample value of \(ICT_{{ Kap}}\), with a time variation guaranteed by an exogenous trend, avoids potential further endogeneity issues. Also, we allow \(ICT_{{ Kap}}\) to have a different effect on wages according to the workers’ manual intensity by augmenting the model with the interaction term \(ICT_{{ Kap}}\times \)MS. Although the data are for the usa, the fact that ict technology has known a remarkably rapid diffusion across the world makes us confident that this variable is a fair proxy of the time evolution of technical progress in Peru. This robustness check is presented in Columns [2] and [6] of Table 16.

Furthermore, in order to account for potential wage changes induced by trade through channels other than import exposure, we add to our main set of covariates Exports calculated as the sector or occupation level, depending on the specification, change in Peru’s export share against the world as of 2003 and multiplied by a trend. As above, taking the pre-sample value of Exports, with a time variation guaranteed by an exogenous trend, avoids potential further endogeneity issues arising from the joint evolution of Exports and wages (Colantone and Crinó 2014). In our framework, Exports should capture any exogenous shock that may directly influence the competitiveness of the Peruvian economy and indirectly workers’ wages. We also add to our main set of covariates Exports and its interaction with \({ MS}_{k}\) to account for the possible moderating effect of the manual intensity on the impact of exports on wages. Columns [3] and [7] of Table 16 show that, even in this case, there are no significant changes to our main estimation results.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Source: Authors’ own elaboration based on results of Table 17. The marginal effect in a is computed using the ols estimation results reported in Column [1], and confidence bands are based on cluster-robust standard errors; The marginal effect in b is computed using the kv-iv estimation results reported in Column [5], and confidence bands are based on cluster-bootstrapped standard errors

Marginal effects IP, a industry-specific and b occupation-specific baseline models, epe 2004–2009.

Table 17 Wage equation—alternative specification based on relative wages

Finally, a further identification issue comes from the widespread use of informal labour in the Peruvian economy (see Sect. 3.2.2). Import competition may affect an individual’s probability of switching from a formal to an informal job. Although informality is a persistent feature of the Peruvian economy and sector dummies could be enough to control for this, the incidence of informality may still heterogeneously vary through time across sectors and this can affect the identification of our import competition measure. In this robustness check we account for the share of informal workers by sector and occupation from the ENAHO survey. Notice that this information is only available for the years 2007–2009. Looking at the results in Columns [4] and [8] in Table 16, our results are confirmed even in the presence of this control which only turns positive and significant in the occupation-specific specification. The positive association between informality and wages could stem from lower wage earners being more likely to be informal or, in the presence of market segmentation between formal and informal workers, from the lower availability of formal workers in a sector driving up formal wages.

1.4 C.4 Alternative specification based on relative wages

This section presents a final sensitivity check based on an alternative definition of our dependent variable. As previously discussed (see Sect. 3.2.2), sector- or occupation-level proxies for technological change are unavailable for Peru. Hence, we have included the average wage by industry, occupation and year as an explanatory variable in \(\varvec{X}_i\) in the wage equation. Since average wages are likely to be endogenous as well, the identification of import penetration effects is at risk if, beyond the inclusion of the baseline controls and industry-/occupation-specific fixed-effects, a residual correlation exists between mean wages and our IP variables. Therefore, in order to ascertain whether the potential endogeneity of mean wages affects our baseline evidence, we remove this variable from the set of regressors and redefine our dependent variable as the log ratio of individual wages over mean wages at the sector–occupation–year level. This allows us to retain the same framework while treating mean wages as endogenous. Corresponding results are shown in columns [1]–[2] and [4]–[5] of Table 17, and marginal effects are displayed in Fig. 9. Our baseline evidence is corroborated for both the sector- and occupation-specific models, thus confirming the high similarity of our baseline models with the empirical models for relative wages explored in this Appendix. Finally, in columns [3] and [6] of Table 17 we show that our findings are robust to the inclusion of the ict capital proxy used above in “Appendix C.3”.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Casabianca, E.J., Lo Turco, A. & Pigini, C. Import penetration and returns to tasks: recent evidence from the Peruvian labour market. Empir Econ 56, 551–617 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1412-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1412-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation