Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Nurses and physicians: a longitudinal analysis of mobility between jobs and labor supply

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We estimate a dynamic discrete choice model of registered nurses’ labor supply. A distinguished feature of our model is that the random terms in the utility functions are correlated over time and jobs (habit or job persistence). Past options and not only the past optimal choices matter for the current choices. Given observed incentives and institutional constraints on offered hours, we find that nurses are mobile when they are young (less mobility than among physicians), but there is also a weak tendency of higher mobility again when they are approaching retirement age. Wage increases have a modest impact on labor supply. The overall elasticity for nurses is close to zero. These low elasticities shadow for stronger responses, shifting labor away from part-time jobs in the public and private sector toward full-time jobs in the private sector. A change in taxation away from the progressive tax system toward a flat tax of 28 % gives registered nurses a very modest incentive to shift their job to private hospitals. For physicians, the impact is stronger.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Table 14 in “Appendix 2”.

  2. A 10 % increase in the wage level for all nurses is estimated to yield a 3.3 % increase in the unconditional expectation of hours supplied in the population of nurses. Labor supply is aggregated across individuals and job types, and then the elasticities are calculated for this aggregate sum with respect to the wage rate in all job types. This aggregate elasticity is equivalent to taking the elasticity of the labor supply for every individual, and then calculating the weighted sum using the predicted choice probabilities of hours worked for each individual as weights.

  3. Implying that hours of work are zeros.

  4. The classification of sectors is based on the standard used by Statistics Norway, which is based on the Statistical Classification of Economic Activities (NACE) used in the European Community. The sector “Other sectors” consists of all types of jobs that do not fall in under either hospital or healthcare services. It thereby includes nurses doing a wide variety of works outside the traditional healthcare sectors, such as administrative work in government and in the private sector or working in non-health sectors.

  5. The PAI register consists of data on workers in public enterprises, including physicians and nurses working in hospitals and health care.

References

  • Aaberge R, Dagsvik JK, Strøm S (1995) Labor supply responses and welfare effects of tax reforms. Scand J Econ 97:635–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreassen L, Di Tommaso ML, Strøm S (2013) Do medical doctors respond to economic incentives? J Health Econ 32:392–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Askildsen J, Baltagi B, Holmås T (2003) Will increased wages reduce shortages of nurses? A panel data analysis of nurses’ labor supply. Health Econ 12:705–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy J, Kalb G (2005) Discrete hours labour supply modelling: specification estimation and simulation. J Econ Surv 19:697–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dagsvik JK (2002) Discrete choice in continuos time: implications of an intertemporal version of the IIA property. Econometrica 70:817–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dagsvik JK, Strøm S (2006) Sectoral labor supply, choice restrictions and functional form. J Appl Econ 21(6):803–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dagsvik JK, Jia Z (2015) Labor supply as a choice among latent jobs: unobserved heterogeneity and identification. J Appl Econ (Article first published online: 6 Jan 2015)

  • Deaton A (1992) Understanding consumption. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tommaso ML, Strøm S, Sæther EM (2009) Nurses wanted. Is the job too harsh or is the wage too low? J Health Econ 28:748–757

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dynan KE (2000) Habit formation in consumer preferences: evidence from panel data. Am Econ Rev 90:391–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorman WM (1967) Tastes, habits and choices. Int Econ Rev 8:218–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanel B, Kalb G, Scott A (2014) Nurses’ labour supply elasticities: the importance of accounting for extensive margins. J Health Econ 33:94–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005) Tackling nurse shortages in OECD countries. OECD health working paper no. 19. http://www.oecd.org/health/health-systems/34571365.pdf

  • OECD (2013) Ageing and employment policies: Norway 2013: working better with age. OECD Publishing. doi:10.1787/9789264201484-en

  • Pollak RA (1970) Habit formation and dynamic demand functions. J Polit Econ 78:745–763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shields MA (2004) Addressing nurse shortages: what can policy makers learn from the econometric evidence of nurse labor supply. Econ J 114:F464–F498

    Google Scholar 

  • Train KE (2003) Discrete choice methods with simulations. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Steinar Strøm.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Tax functions

See Tables 6, 7 and 8.

Table 6 Tax function, 1997
Table 7 Tax function, 1998
Table 8 Tax function, 1999

Appendix 2: Data

In this appendix, the data and estimates for physicians are copied from Andreassen et al. (2013) (Tables 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15).

Table 9 Sample selection
Table 10 Number of married physicians and married nurses in the different sectors
Table 11 Average weekly hours across sectors
Table 12 Distribution between short part-time and long part-time among married nurses
Table 13 Mean of the explanatory variables for married physicians and married registered nurses
Table 14 Mean consumption for married physicians and married nurses by sector
Table 15 Mean leisure for married physicians and married nurses by sector

Appendix 3: Observed transition rates for nurses, transition rates for physicians are given in Andreassen et al. (2013)

See Tables 16, 17, 18 and 19.

Table 16 Transitions of married nurses from 1997 to 1998
Table 17 Transitions of married nurses from 1998 to 1999
Table 18 Transitions of married nurses from 1997 to 1998
Table 19 Transitions of married nurses from 1998 to 1999

Appendix 4: Wage equations and selection effects for nurses, for physicians see Andreassen et al. (2013)

We estimate wage equations for all individuals for the 3 years 1997, 1998 and 1999. The wage equations for physicians are documented in Andreassen et al. (2013). The wage equations for nurses are documented below. We take sample selection into account by including the predicted choice probabilities as explanatory variables in the wage equations. These probabilities were the predictions resulting from a simple multinomial logit estimation of sector choice. We show the mean of the explanatory variables used in the estimation of the choice probabilities in Table 20. The estimates of the choice probabilities are given in Table 21, and the resulting average predicted probabilities are given in Tables 22, along with the means of the other variables used in the wage equations. The logit estimations were done on all nurses in a given year, while the wage equations were estimated on all working nurses with observations of wage income (Table 23). The estimates of the wage equations are given in Table 24. The wage equations for all nine work sectors have been estimated simultaneously using maximum likelihood, allowing for correlation between the different wages. The parameters \({\sigma }_1\) to \({\sigma }_9\) are the variance parameters mentioned in the main paper, and the parameters \({\kappa }_1\) to \({\kappa }_9\) are the parameters allowing for correlation between sectors. As shown in tables, these correlation factors are not found to be significant, indicating that there is not much residual correlation between the different wages after correcting for the other explanatory variables. In general, being a woman reduces wages, while wages increase with age. Table 25 shows the mean and predicted hourly wages for nurses and derived from predictions using the estimated wage equations reported above. Table 26 shows the predicted wages for physicians based on the wage equations documented in Andreassen et al. (2013). The wages for doctors are higher and vary more than the wages of nurses.

Table 20 Mean of the explanatory variables for the logit estimation
Table 21 Logit estimates of choice of sector and hours (job type)
Table 22 Sample selection for logit estimation and estimation of wage equations
Table 23 Mean of the explanatory variables for the wage equations
Table 24 Estimated coefficients of the wage equations for nurses 1997–1999
Table 25 Mean and median predicted hourly wages for nurses
Table 26 Mean and median predicted hourly wages for physicians

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Andreassen, L., Di Tommaso, M.L. & Strøm, S. Nurses and physicians: a longitudinal analysis of mobility between jobs and labor supply. Empir Econ 52, 1235–1269 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1116-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1116-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation