Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The effects of firms’ R&D and innovation activities on their survival: a competing risks analysis

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a data set of Norwegian firms, an examination is made of the relationship between firms’ R&D activities and their survival. A firm may exit the market through closure, or merger and acquisition (M&A). The analysis is based on a discrete time competing risks model with unobserved heterogeneity. We find that product-innovative firms have a higher probability of exit due to M&A, but only if they also introduce new products into their market. This highlights the importance of differentiating between different groups of product-innovative firms. None of the R&D and innovation activities considered has significant effects on the probability of firm closure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Audretsch (1991, 1995) and Audretsch and Mahmood (1994, 1995) have found that innovation activities are important determinants of firm survival, but these studies focus on innovation activities at the industrial level and not those within each firm.

  2. An introduction to the literature which focuses on the relationship between firm survival and innovation is given in Dalglish and Newton (2001).

  3. Fernandes and Paunov (2012, footnote 4) refer to the article by Mairesse and Mohnen (2010), which points out that ‘what exactly is defined as a new or improved product is not always clear anyway, certainly not to the respondents... The distinction between “new to the firm” and “new to the market” is also subject to a great deal of subjective judgement. To give a correct answer to this question presupposes a very good knowledge of one’s market’ (Mairesse and Mohnen 2010, p. 1137). Although the authors raise a valid concern, this is probably a widespread problem regarding subjective answers to survey questions on the relative performance of firms that the quality ‘can be very different depending on the judgment and knowledge of the respondents’ (Mairesse and Mohnen 2010, p. 1137).

  4. Jensen et al. (2008), Buddelmeyer et al. (2010), and Helmers and Rogers (2010) also use data for firms from different industrial sectors.

  5. See Lieberman and Montgomery (1988) and Kopel and Löffler (2008) for a discussion of first-mover advantages.

  6. For a discussion of cost competition, see Pries (2006).

  7. Mañez et al. (2009) find that large firms and/or firms operating in high-tech industries have significantly higher sunk R&D costs compared with small firms and/or firms in low- and medium-tech industries.

  8. Innovative firms may include firms that had innovation activities during the period 1999–2001 that did not result in a product or process innovation because the activities were abandoned before completion, or not completed by the end of 2001.

  9. Hazard models are also used in Jensen et al. (2008), Fontana and Nesta (2009), Buddelmeyer et al. (2010), Giovannetti et al. (2011), Fernandes and Paunov (2012), and Colombelli et al. (2013). Fontana and Nesta (2009, p. 296) emphasise that they apply a hazard model with two destinations, but treat the destinations as independent in their analysis.

  10. Buddelmeyer et al. (2010, p. 262) claim that Cefis and Marsili (2005) examine the effect in survival time due to ‘successful’ innovation.

  11. The share of R&D personnel among all employees is 4 % (0.126) for all manufacturing firms and 7 % (0.248) for manufacturing firms that are closed down, while from Table 1 we see that this share is 6 % (0.170) for all firms in our sample and 7 % (0.201) for all firms that are closed down (standard deviation in parenthesis). Thus, the ratio between the standard deviations is 197 % (=0.248/0.126) for manufacturing firms and 118 % (=0.201/0.170) for all firms.

  12. The Kendall’s rank correlation coefficients between the share of R&D personnel among all employees and total gross wages per employee are 15.6 % for the manufacturing sector and 14.6 % for all industrial sectors as a whole, while the Spearman’s rank correlation coefficients between the same variables are 20.4 % for the manufacturing sector and 19.0 % for all industrial sectors (all correlation coefficients are significant at the 1 % level).

  13. This result holds even at the 10 % level for manufacturing firms, but only at the 5 % level for all firms in our sample.

  14. Related to the ‘shadow of death’ phenomenon, Carreira and Teixeira (2011) explain that ‘the empirical literature... suggests that exiting firms do not face a ‘sudden death”. On the contrary, firms tend to reveal a steady decrease in their productivity level relative to survivors well before closure’ (p. 340).

  15. We have no obvious instruments for the R&D and innovation indicators either, although we are aware that some studies have used instruments for innovation (Lachenmaier and Woessmann 2006). Furthermore, although IV estimators are consistent given valid instruments, ‘IV estimators can be much less efficient than the OLS estimator and can have a finite-sample distribution that for usual finite-sample sizes differs greatly from the asymptotic distribution. These problems are greatly magnified if instruments are weakly correlated with the variables being instrumented’ (Cameron and Trivedi 2005, p. 103).

  16. From (R4) for the model in Table 4, we also find that manufacturing firms that are both product- and process-innovative have a relatively higher probability of exit due to M&A, but the result is only significant at the 10 % level.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Zilibotti F (2006) Distance to frontier, selection, and economic growth. J Eur Econ Assoc 4:37–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almus M (2004) The shadow of death—an empirical analysis of the pre-exit performance of new German firms. Small Bus Econ 23:189–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB (1991) New-firm survival and the technological regime. Rev Econ Stat 73:441–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB (1995) Innovation, growth and survival. Int J Ind Organ 13:441–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Mahmood T (1994) The rate of hazard confronting new firms and plants in U.S. manufacturing. Rev Ind Organ 9:41–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Mahmood T (1995) New firm survival: new results using a hazard function. Rev Econ Stat 77:97–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banbury CM, Mitchell W (1995) The effect of introducing important incremental innovations on market share and business survival. Strateg Manag J 16:161–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman E, Scarpetta S, Schivardi F (2005) Comparative analysis of firm demographics and survival: evidence from micro-level sources in OECD countries. Ind Corp Change 14:365–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (2002) The Free-market innovation machine: analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bellone F, Musso P, Quéré M, Nesta L (2006) Productivity and market selection of French manufacturing firms in the nineties. Revue de l’OFCE 97(bis):319–349

    Google Scholar 

  • Buddelmeyer H, Jensen PH, Webster E (2010) Innovation and the determinants of company survival. Oxf Econ Pap 62:261–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron AC, Trivedi PK (2005) Microeconometrics: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Carreira C, Teixeira P (2011) The shadow of death: analysing the pre-exit productivity of Portuguese manufacturing firms. Small Bus Econ 36:337–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis E, Marsili O (2005) A matter of life and death: innovation and firm survival. Ind Corp Change 14:1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis E, Marsili O (2006a) Innovation premium and the survival of entrepreneurial firms in the Netherlands. In: Santarelli E (ed) Entrepreneurship, growth, and innovation. The dynamics of firms and industries, Volume 12, Chapter 9. International Studies in Entrepreneurship. Springer, New York

  • Cefis E, Marsili O (2006b) Survivor: the role of innovation in firm’s survival. Res Policy 35:626–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis E, Marsili O (2012) Going, going, gone. Exit forms and the innovative capabilities of firms. Res Policy 41:795–807

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombelli A, Krafft J, Quatraro F (2013) Properties of knowledge base and firm survival: evidence from a sample of French manufacturing firms. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, available online 26 March 2013

  • Crepon B, Duguet E, Mairessec J (1998) Research, innovation and productivity: an econometric analysis at the firm level. Econ Innov New Technol 7:115–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dabla-Norris E, Kersting EK, Verdier G (2012) Firm productivity, innovation, and financial development. South Econ J 79:422–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalglish C, Newton C (2001) The relationship between firm survival and innovation: an introduction to the literature (review). Innovation: management. Policy Pract 4:209–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desmet K, Parente SL (2012) The evolution of markets and the revolution of industry: a unified theory of growth. J Econ Growth 17:205–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteve-Pérez S, Sanchis Llopis A, Sanchis Llopis JA (2010) A competing risks analysis of firms’ exit. Empir Econ 38:281–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandes AM, Paunov C (2012) The risks of innovation: are innovating firms less likely to die? Policy Research working paper 6103, The World Bank

  • Fontana R, Nesta L (2009) Product innovation and survival in a high-tech industry. Rev Ind Organ 34:287–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster L, Haltiwanger JC, Krizan CJ (2001) Aggregate productivity growth. Lessons from microeconomic evidence. In: Hulten CR, Dean ER, Harper MJ (eds) New developments in productivity analysis. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 303–372

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Giovannetti G, Ricchiuti G, Velucchi M (2011) Size, innovation and internationalization: a survival analysis of Italian firms. Appl Econ 43:1511–1520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z, Regev H (1995) Firm productivity in Israeli industry 1979–1988. J Econ 65:175–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hauknes J, Knell M (2009) Embodied knowledge and sectoral linkages: an input-output approach to the interaction of high- and low-tech industries. Res Policy 38:459–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ, Singer B (1984) A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52:271–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helmers C, Rogers M (2010) Innovation and the survival of new firms in the UK. Rev Ind Organ 36:227–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyman F (2007) Firm size or firm age? The effect on wages using matched employer–employee data. Labour 21:237–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopenhayn HA (1992) Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60:1127–1150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen PH, Webster E, Buddelmeyer H (2008) Innovation, technological conditions and new firm survival. Econ Rec 84:434–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW (1988) Productivity and postwar U.S. economic growth. J Econ Perspect 2:23–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B (1982) Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50:649–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelm M (1997) Schumpeter’s theory of economic evolution: a Darwinian interpretation. J Evol Econ 7:97–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (1996) Entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the product life. Am Econ Rev 86:562–583

    Google Scholar 

  • Kopel M, Löffler C (2008) Commitment, first-mover-, and second-mover advantage. J Econ 94:143–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lachenmaier S, Woessmann L (2006) Does innovation cause exports? Evidence from exogenous innovation impulses and obstacles using German micro data. Oxf Econ Pap 58:317–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman MB, Montgomery DB (1988) First-mover advantages. Strateg Manag J 9:41–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindsay BG (1983) The geometry of mixture likelihoods: a general theory. Ann Stat 11:86–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mairesse J, Mohnen P (2010) Using innovation surveys for econometric analysis. In: Halland BH, Rosenberg N (eds) Handbook of the economics of innovation, vol 2. Academic Press, Burlington, pp 1129–1156

    Google Scholar 

  • Mañez JA, Rochina-Barrachina ME, Sanchis-Llopis A, Sanchis JA (2009) The role of sunk costs in the decision to invest in R&D. J Ind Econ 57:712–735

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pries L (2006) Cost competition or innovation competition? Lessons from the case of the BMW plant location in Leipzig, Germany. Eur Rev Labour Res 12:11–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharif N, Huang C (2012) Innovation strategy, firm survival and relocation: the case of Hong Kong-owned manufacturing in Guangdong Province, China. Res Policy 41:69–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Norway (2004) Official statistics of Norway, D 304. Statistics Norway, Oslo-Kongsvinger

  • Van Beveren I (2012) Total factor productivity estimation: a practical review. J Econ Surv 26:98–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2013) Introductory econometrics: a modern approach, 5th edn. South-Western

  • Zhang T (2003) A Monte Carlo study on non-parametric estimation of duration models with unobserved heterogeneity. Memorandum, No. 25, Department of Economics, University of Oslo, Norway

Download references

Acknowledgments

Many thanks to Editor Bernd Fitzenberger and three anonymous referees for valuable comments on earlier drafts of this paper. The paper has also benefited from discussions with my colleagues Olav R. Spilling and Tore Sandven, and my former colleagues Aris Kaloudis and Øyvind Wiborg. Also, many thanks to my former colleague Rachel Sweetman and language consultant John G. Taylor for valuable contributions during proof editing. All remaining errors are my own responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pål Børing.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Børing, P. The effects of firms’ R&D and innovation activities on their survival: a competing risks analysis. Empir Econ 49, 1045–1069 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0901-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0901-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation