Skip to main content
Log in

Partial ownership of local firms and zoning of neighboring towns

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates zoning in two neighboring towns in which firms are owned by investors that reside in the two towns. We find that local regulators use zoning strategically depending on the weight of local profits in social welfare. When they are high enough, both towns are zoned. For intermediate values an asymmetric result emerges: Only one regulator resorts to zoning despite the symmetry in the percentage of ownership of the neighboring firms. For a low weight of local profits, towns may or may not be zoned. Zoning restrictions on the location of firms are tighter when local profits are more significant for social welfare.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. From the viewpoint of “fiscal zoning” local authorities may try to keep out relatively low-income residents, for example, by increasing the size of the minimum lot for building a single-family house or by reducing the number of apartments that can be built. A related branch of the literature on spatial models analyzes tax competition among perfectly competitive firms within local jurisdictions in metropolitan areas located on a line (see, for example, Braid 1993, 2000).

  2. The seminal work in analyzing the location of competing firms in linear cities is Hotelling (1929): Two firms simultaneously locate within a linear city and then simultaneously decide their prices. He assumes that consumers’ transportation costs are linear, which implies that there is no price equilibrium when firms locate close enough (see d’Aspremont et al. 1979). However, d’Aspremont et al. (1979) show that under quadratic transportation costs, the game has a price equilibrium for all locations of the firms.

  3. Bárcena-Ruiz and Casado-Izaga (2014) also analyze optimal zoning when two firms can price discriminate between consumers. Bárcena-Ruiz et al. (2014) study optimal zoning in a mixed duopoly framework. Matsumura and Matsushima (2012) show that restricting the locations of firms to the linear city reduces consumer welfare when firms sign strategic reward contracts with their managers. Hamoudi and Risueño (2012) study zoning in a circular city where firms and consumers are located on different sides. Suzuki (2013) analyzes the anticompetitive effect of land use regulations, since zoning may discourage entry.

  4. Examples of strategic behavior by local authorities can be found in the USA and in Europe (see Hanssen and Foslt 1998; Boarnet and Crane 1998; Heim 2012; Hrelja et al. 2012).

  5. Bárcena-Ruiz and Casado-Izaga (2017) point out that zoning costs are meaningful because “there are costs linked to studying regulation, to designing the maps that plot the different uses of different areas in the town, to uploading those maps and regulations to the Web site that offers the information; and there are costs for the staff who inform about and watch for non-fulfillment of the norms, to mention just a few.”

  6. Inoue et al. (2009) study the location of a public firm and a private firm in a city with two symmetric districts, each of which is run by a local government. However, they do not study zoning decisions.

  7. For example, Bárcena-Ruiz and Casado-Izaga (2016) show that the nationality of firms influences the design of the optimal zoning by a regulator in a duopoly model of spatial price discrimination. Matsushima and Matsumura (2006) analyze the spatial location of firms in a mixed oligopoly when there are foreign private firms, and Matsumura et al. (2009) investigate whether or not privatization is beneficial from the viewpoint of social welfare in a monopolistic competition model.

  8. Available at: http://www.bastianpr.com/wp-content/uploads/2014/07/Foreign-investment_-U.S.pdf.

  9. In Europe, French real estate investment trust Klépierre has recently acquired shopping malls in Spain and the Netherlands and owns shopping centers in 57 cities in 16 countries (http://www.klepierre.com/en/who-we-are/in-brief/).

  10. When the local firm belongs to local investors and a fixed cost of zoning exists, the model is the same as that analyzed by Bárcena-Ruiz and Casado-Izaga (2017) in the case of two towns of the same size.

  11. The second-order conditions of the problems that we analyze are always satisfied.

  12. The analysis that includes Eqs. (1)–(6) can be found in Anderson et al. (1992, Chapter 8, pp. 293–301).

  13. We have used Wolfram Mathematica for some of the calculations made in the paper. Detailed computations are available from the authors on request.

  14. For example, when \(\alpha =1\), we obtain that the optimal locations from a social welfare viewpoint are: \(x_{1}^{*}=5/16\); \(x_{2}^{*}=11/16\). For \(\alpha =3/4\): \(x_{1}^{*}=1/4\); \(x_{2}^{*}=3/4\). When \(\alpha =1/2\): \(x_{1}^{*}=1/8\); \(x_{2}^{*}=7/8\). Finally, when \(\alpha =1/4\) or 0: \(x_{1}^{*}=0\); \(x_{2}^{*}=1\), the same result is obtained by d’Aspremont et al. (1979) assuming a single linear city with \(\alpha =0\) and no zoning.

  15. This approach is valid as long as \(x_{2}=1\). When \(x_{2}\) depends on \(x_{1}\), this way of finding the solution is not valid as one has to proceed backwards.

  16. Comparing \(W_{1}^{ZN}\) and \(W_{2}^{ZN}\) for \(3/8<\alpha \le 0.4765\), we obtain that \(W_{1}^{ZN}\)\(<W_{2}^{ZN}\) because \(\delta >\gamma\).

  17. The situation is different if the metropolitan area extends over different countries. In that case, there is not a superior authority that can force local regulators to harmonize their rules across national borders.

References

  • Anderson SP, de Palma A, Thisse J-F (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. M.I.T. Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2005a) Economic integration and privatization under diseconomies of scale. Eur J Polit Econ 21:247–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2005b) International trade and strategic privatization. Rev Dev Econ 9:502–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Casado-Izaga FJ (2014) Zoning under spatial price discrimination. Econ Inq 52:659–665

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Casado-Izaga FJ (2016) Foreign-owned firms and zoning under spatial price discrimination. Lett Spat Resour Sci 9:145–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Casado-Izaga FJ (2017) Zoning a cross-border city. J Reg Sci 57:173–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Casado-Izaga FJ (2018) Zoning a metropolitan area. Pap Reg Sci 97:S123–S137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Casado-Izaga FJ, Hamoudi H (2014) Optimal zoning of a mixed duopoly. Ann Reg Sci 52:141–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Casado-Izaga FJ, Hamoudi H, Rodríguez I (2016) Optimal zoning in the unconstrained Hotelling game. Pap Reg Sci 95:427–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boarnet MG, Crane R (1998) Public finance and transit-orientated planning: new evidence from Southern California. J Plan Educ Res 17:206–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braid RM (1993) Spatial competition between jurisdictions which tax perfectly competitive retail (or production) centers. J Urban Econ 34:75–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braid RM (2000) A spatial model of tax competition with multiple tax instruments. J Urban Econ 47:88–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cato S, Matsumura T (2017) Optimal production tax and privatization policies under an endogenous market structure. MPRA Paper No. 82893, posted 23 November 2017 16:17 UTC. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/82893/. Accessed 28 Jun 2018

  • Chen CS, Lai FC (2008) Location choice and optimal zoning under Cournot competition. Reg Sci Urban Econ 38:119–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo S (2012) On optimal zoning in a linear town with Cournot competitors. Lett Spat Resour Sci 5:113–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G, Jeanne O (1994) Oligopole mixte dans un marche commun. Ann d’Econ Stat 33:73–90

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1979) On Hotelling’s stability in competition. Econometrica 47:1145–1150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell K, Pal D (1996) A mixed oligopoly in the presence of foreign private firms. Can J Econ 29:737–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamoudi H, Risueño M (2012) The effects of zoning in spatial competition. J Reg Sci 52:361–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanssen JU, Foslt O (1998) Shopping malls-location and use. A study of ski and vinterbro shopping malls focusing on the users and their transport. TØI report 394/1998. https://www.toi.no/getfile.php/Publikasjoner/T%C3%98I%20rapporter/1998/394-1998/sum-394-98.pdf

  • Heim CE (2012) Border wars: tax revenues, annexation, and urban growth in Phoenix. Int J Urban Reg Res 36:831–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henninger G (2015) How municipal finance creates regional shopping centers. http://www.fromsuburbia.com/2015/01/how-municipal-finance-creates-regional-shopping-centers/

  • Heywood JS, Ye G (2009) Mixed oligopoly and spatial price discrimination with foreign firms. Reg Sci Urban Econ 39:592–601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hrelja R, Karolina I, Richardson T (2012) IKEA and small city development in Sweden: planning myths, realities, and unsustainable mobilities. Int Plan Stud 17:125–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inoue T, Kamijo Y, Tomaru Y (2009) Interregional mixed duopoly. Reg Sci Urban Econ 39:233–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai FC, Tsai JF (2004) Duopoly locations and optimal zoning in a small open city. J Urban Econ 55:614–626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin MH, Matsumura T (2012) Presence of foreign investors in privatized firms and privatization policy. J Econ 107:71–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Löfgren O (2008) Regionauts: the transformation of cross-border regions in Scandinavia. Eur Urban Reg Stud 15:195–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorentzon S (2011) Shopping along the border between Norway and Sweden as engine of regional development. Occasional Papers 2011:4. http://www.ipd.gu.se/digitalAssets/1349/1349301_occ-p-20114.pdf

  • Matsumura T, Matsushima N (2012) Locating outside a linear city can benefit consumers. J Reg Sci 52:420–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Matsushima N, Ishibashi I (2009) Privatization and entries of foreign enterprises in a differentiated industry. J Econ 98:203–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima N, Matsumura T (2006) Mixed oligopoly, foreign firms and location choice. Reg Sci Urban Econ 36:753–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal D, White MD (1998) Mixed oligopoly, privatization, and strategic trade policy. South Econ J 65:264–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salcedo R (2003) When the global meets the local at the mall. Am Behav Sci 46:1084–1103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spierings B, van der Velde M (2013) Cross-border differences and unfamiliarity: shopping mobility in the Dutch-German Rhine-Waal Euroregion. Eur Plan Stud 21:5–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan P, Bonn MA, Bhardwaj V, DuPont A (2012) Mexican national cross-border shopping: exploration of retail tourism. J Retail Consum Serv 19:596–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzuki J (2013) Land use regulations as a barrier to entry: evidence from the Texas lodging industry. Int Econ Rev 54:495–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timothy DJ, Butler RW (2005) Cross-border shopping: Canada and the United States. In: Ganster P, Lorey DE (eds) Borders and border politics in globalizing world. S.R. Books, Boulder, pp 285–300

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank two referees for helpful comments. Financial support from Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnología (ECO2015-66803-P) and the University of the Basque Country UPV/EHU (GIU17/051) is gratefully acknowledged

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Juan Carlos Bárcena-Ruiz.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bárcena-Ruiz, J.C., Casado-Izaga, F.J. Partial ownership of local firms and zoning of neighboring towns. Ann Reg Sci 65, 27–43 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-019-00972-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-019-00972-5

JEL Classification

Navigation