1 Introduction

Migration has become an increasingly politicized issue, in particular given the rise in unauthorized migration, igniting public and

policy interest in its impacts and sparking new debates on the relationship between migration and economic development. Not surprisingly, the focus of the academic literature on unauthorized migration has been on the impact of irregularity on the host country. However, little is known about the consequences of irregular migration on sending countries. Studying the impact of illegality on the origin country is particularly important since unauthorized migration is often temporary, and many irregular migrants return to their home country either because they are deported or because they planned on temporary migration all along.

Return migration is an important phenomenon in the broad picture of international mobility. Although statistics on return migration are not reliable, recent estimates are that roughly one-quarter of all migration events are returns (Azose and Raftery 2019). According to the OECD (2018), the five countries that experienced the largest outflows of foreign populations in 2016 were Germany (1.09 million), Korea (325,000), Spain (243,000), Japan (234,000), and the UK (195,000). At the same time, irregular migration has been on the rise. According to the European Commission, every year, between 400,000 and 500,000 foreign nationals are ordered to leave the European Union because they have either entered or stayed irregularly in the destination country.

Irregular migration is not only an issue for OECD countries, but is also a challenge for the Gulf states and middle-income countries like Malaysia and Thailand. For example, the United Nations Office for Drugs and Crime (UNODC) estimates that every year more than 660,000 people migrate irregularly to Thailand (Schloenhardt 2014). Another example is Mexico, known for being a major migrant-sending country to the USA, for its unauthorized emigration, and for its substantial return migration flows. According to the Mexican National Survey of Demographic Dynamics (ENADID), between 2009 and 2014, about half (48%) of the Mexican immigrant population in the USA was unauthorized, and one million Mexicans returned from the USA, leaving of their own accord (Gonzalez-Barrera 2015).Footnote 1 Many other developing countries are likewise experiencing high return migration rates, as well as an increase in unauthorized emigration.

This paper is the first to examine the impact of undocumented migration status on migrants upon return to their home country. It investigates an unexplored question, namely the impact of the legal status of migrants on their wages upon return. We study the impact of return migration on wages by disentangling the effects of overseas legal versus illegal status and ask whether undocumented temporary migration has any impact on human capital accumulation that persists after return. From a conceptual point of view, temporary migrants might acquire human capital and skills due to their work experience abroad and hence earn higher wages upon return compared to non-migrants. However, whether all migrants, documented or undocumented, would benefit from their migration experience upon return is not straightforward. On one hand, if illegal status hinders the human capital accumulation and the skill acquisition of undocumented migrants, the well-evidenced wage premium witnessed by migrants upon return might not apply and we might expect that only documented migrants would benefit from their migration experience. On the other hand, the origin country’s labor market might reward the migration experience regardless of the documented or undocumented nature of migration. If the latter scenario applies, through a signaling mechanism, all migrants would benefit from their experience overseas, regardless of the nature of migration and/or of the human capital and skills acquired abroad.

We contribute to the literature on undocumented migration, which is rather sparse given the lack of data. Hanson (2006) provides a survey of the determinants of illegal migration to the USA, focusing on the role of immigration policy and enforcement. Orrenius and Zavodny (2003) examine the impact of amnesty programs on undocumented immigration flows, while Orrenius and Zavodny (2005) study the effect of changes in border enforcement policies on the skill level of undocumented Mexican immigrants in the USA.

A few papers have examined the return intentions of undocumented migrants. For instance, Vinogradova (2016) provides theoretical explanations for the optimal timing of return of undocumented migrants, whereby the threat of deportation increases uncertainty with respect to the length of the stay abroad, which in turn reduces the desired migration duration and triggers voluntary return. In line with this theoretical argument, several papers find that a significant share of unauthorized migrants intend to immigrate only temporarily and to eventually return to their home country (Borjas et al. 1991). Reyes (2001) finds that undocumented Mexican immigrants are much more likely to return than documented ones. Coniglio et al. (2009) find that more than 70% of irregular immigrants to Italy planned to return home after an average intended stay of 6 years and that high-skilled clandestine migrants are more likely to return to the origin country compared with those with no or low skills. On the other hand, other studies have found lower return rates among undocumented immigrants due to stricter border enforcement (Kemnitz and Mayr 2012; Massey et al. 2016).

Focusing on the impact of illegality on the migrant, the literature has focused on a myriad of outcomes, including the labor market outcomes of undocumented migrants and their consumption behavior.Footnote 2 Under an Italian amnesty program, Devillanova et al. (2018) find that immigrants who are potentially eligible for legal status are more likely than ineligible undocumented immigrants to be employed. Using the 1990 Legalized Population Survey, Rivera-Batiz (1999) estimate a 52% wage penalty for Mexican undocumented immigrants in the USA, while Kossoudji and Cobb-Clark (2002) report a wage penalty that ranges between 14 and 24%. Phillips and Massey (1999) find that the Immigration Reform and Control Act in the USA, which made it illegal to hire unauthorized immigrants, is associated with a larger wage penalty for undocumented migrants as employers pass the costs of unauthorized hiring on to workers. Accounting for selection, Schluter and Wahba (2009) also find a significant effect of illegality on wages in the host country but mixed effects on remitting behavior. On the other hand, Dustmann et al. (2017) find that undocumented migrants consume about 40% less than documented migrants in Italy, partly due to their lower incomes relative to documented migrants.

The literature has put forward several explanations for the worse outcomes experienced by undocumented migrants compared with documented migrants. First, several studies show that undocumented migrants have weak bargaining power due to the lack of legal work options. Without viable outside options, undocumented migrants are confined into poor jobs (Gonzales 2011; Gleeson and Gonzales 2012). For instance, undocumented migrants are more likely to work in physically exhausting and dangerous jobs and receive no compensating differential, which is analogous to receiving lower wages than documented workers with similar education levels (Hall and Greenman 2015). Second, the occupational choices of undocumented migrants might be limited by fear of exposure to apprehension by immigration enforcement agencies, and relatedly, being undocumented may limit workers’ ability to maximize their potential, which may lead to lower productivity (Ortega and Hsin 2018). Third, several studies highlight the increased risk of depression and anxiety among undocumented migrants—due to the threat of deportation and poorer labor market conditions—which is also likely to negatively affect worker productivity (Abrego 2011; Gonzales 2011; Patler and Pirtle 2018).

There is also a well-established academic literature on the determinants and impacts of migration on countries of origin. Indeed, there is a growing body of evidence showing that temporary migration can be beneficial for migrants who accumulate savings and skills, which they use to better themselves upon return (see Wahba (2014) for a survey of this literature). On the impact of temporary migration experiences on return migrants’ wages, several papers find that there is a positive wage premium for return migrants associated with overseas work experience (Co et al. 2000; De Coulon and Piracha 2005). Ambrosini et al. (2015) find that for a source country, like Romania, relatively high rates of temporary migration have positive long-run effects on average skills and wages. Lacuesta (2010) finds an 11% wage gap between returning migrants and observationally equivalent non-migrants in Mexico, but argues that this premium is the result of pre-migration differences in ability and not the result of human capital gains derived from migration. Reinhold and Thom (2013) also find a wage premium for Mexican returnees who worked in the USA. The return to a year of occupation-specific migration experience is estimated to be as high as 9% for some occupations. De Vreyer et al. (2010) examine the labor market outcomes of returnees in seven capital cities in West Africa and find that experience abroad results in a substantial wage premium for migrants returning from an OECD country but not for other return migrants. Controlling for the emigration and return migration selections, Wahba (2015) finds that return migrants experience a wage premium of 16% relative to non-migrants. However, none of these studies has examined the differential effects of return migration on wages with respect to migrants’ legal status.

Our paper contributes to the literature in at least two ways. Firstly, while the literature on undocumented migration has focused on the impact of irregularity on destination countries, this paper is the first to investigate the impact of undocumented migration on migrants after they return to their origin country. This is particularly important since many unauthorized migrants return to their country of origin. Secondly, by disentangling the effects of migrants’ legal status, we contribute to the literature on the impacts of migration on origin countries, which has so far overlooked the question of undocumented migration.

We use data from the Egypt Labor Market Panel Survey (ELMPS 2012), which has several major advantages. First, Egypt provides a particularly suitable case study since it is a country with substantial return migration. According to the ELMPS data, in 2012, 9% of individuals between the ages of 15 and 59 were return migrants.Footnote 3 This figure is in line with the World Bank report by Brodmann et al. (2010), who document that Egyptian migrants constitute 85% of temporary workers in Arab countries, representing as much as 10% of the Egyptian labor force in recent years. Based on the Development Economics Group data from the World Bank, Brodmann et al. (2010) show that, in 2005, Egypt was among the top 10 emigration countries in the world. Second, our data provides unique information on migrants’ legal status while abroad, which allows us to distinguish between return migrants according to their type of international migration—documented versus undocumented. Return migrants were asked whether they had a visa or legal document to enter the destination country, as well as the type of document they had.

In this paper, illegal status/undocumented migration refers to unauthorized entry, stay, or employment in a country.Footnote 4 Generally speaking, misreporting information regarding migrants’ legal status is problematic. This is especially the case for studies that examine the impact of illegality from the perspective of the destination country, where migrants are asked—during ongoing migration spells—about their legal status. However, in our context, the issue of misreporting is much less of a concern since migrants have already returned to their origin country and there would be no repercussions at that stage.

Our empirical analysis relies on a Conditional Mixed Process (CMP) model, following Roodman (2011). The CMP model takes into account the triple selection into emigration, into illegality, and into return migration, and allows us to estimate the effect of overseas illegal status on wages after return. We find that undocumented migrants witness a wage penalty relative to documented migrants but also relative to non-migrants, while only documented migrants witness a wage premium relative to non-migrants. Our benchmark results show an estimated 19% wage penalty for illegal migrants relative to non-migrants, while documented migrants witness a wage premium of 28% relative to non-migrants. Therefore, the wage penalty for undocumented migrants relative to documented migrants is estimated to be around 47%. However, we do not find any effect of migrants’ legal status on occupations or on labor supply upon return to Egypt.

We investigate several underlying mechanisms that could be driving the undocumented migrants’ poorer labor market prospects upon return. We examine the effect of migrants’ undocumented status on various outcomes pertaining to the migration experience overseas. We find suggestive evidence of an overseas wage penalty associated with illegality, as our results show that undocumented migrants earn approximately half the wage of documented migrants while abroad. Moreover, our results suggest that undocumented migrants have significantly lower savings overseas, shorter migration duration, lower incidence of remitting, and lower ranked occupations overseas. Overall, these findings suggest that undocumented migrants’ lower earnings after return might be explained by a waste of human capital overseas. Indeed, we find evidence suggesting that the longer undocumented migrants stay abroad, the more their human capital is depleted, while the opposite is true for documented migrants. This is fully consistent with our descriptive analysis that shows that poor working conditions constitute the most important reason for return migration among undocumented migrants.

This paper sheds light on the potential costs and penalties of unauthorized overseas work and migration. Our results contest the positive wage premium evidenced in the existing literature, and suggest that the positive impact of temporary migration experience on wages upon return is conditional on the type of migration undertaken and that only documented migrants benefit from their migration experience in terms of higher wages upon return to their home country. Understanding the impacts of undocumented migration on the migrant and the origin country is indeed paramount as the results of this paper suggest that the impact of temporary migration might actually depend on the legal status of the migrants. Therefore, ignoring the legal status of migration and its impact is likely to lead to erroneous policies.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a brief description of Egyptian migration, while Section 3 presents the data. Section 4 describes our empirical model and identification strategy. Section 5 presents the results and tests for various underlying mechanisms. Section 6 provides robustness checks, while Section 7 concludes.

2 Background on Egyptian migration

Egypt is an ideal setting for our analysis given the importance of return migration. Egypt has been a main labor sending country since the 1970s. The largest boost to migration flows occurred after the 1973 War, when oil revenues quadrupled and Gulf countries started implementing major development programs. Ever since Egypt has experienced regular outflows of its workers. To a large extent, this was triggered by the labor shortages in the oil-producing Gulf countries and the increased demand for foreign labor. The majority of Egyptian migrants went to neighboring Arab states: to oil exporting Arab countries (the Gulf states, Libya, and Iraq) and to non-oil exporting Arab countries (Jordan and Lebanon) to replace nationals of those countries who migrated to the Gulf. A small proportion of Egyptian migration is permanent in nature and is destined to North America and Australia. More recently, after the 2011 Arab Spring and the economic slowdown that followed, Egyptian migration to Europe has increased (De Bel-Air 2016).

According to the Egyptian Ministry of Foreign Affairs, the number of Egyptians abroad was estimated to be 6.5 million at the beginning of 2011. Overall, Egyptian migration is temporary in nature and is male dominated, as Egyptians typically migrate to seek overseas employment. The Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries hire migrant labor under the sponsorship (kefala) system, where permanent residency and citizenship are precluded to foreign nationals. Many Egyptians are undocumented workers in the GCC countries, and in other Arab neighboring countries like Jordan, which constitute the main destinations for Egyptian migrants. Irregular migration in the GCC countries takes two forms: overstay and informal employment, defined as employment for purposes other than those for which entry was authorized (Awad and Aziz 2017). Finally, in the case of Jordan, Egyptians do not need an entry visa but are required to have a contract before working there.

3 The data

3.1 The ELMPS survey

For the empirical analysis, we use data from the Egypt Labor Market Panel Survey (ELMPS).Footnote 5 The ELMPS is a rich wide-ranging nationally representative survey carried out by the Economic Research Forum (ERF) in cooperation with Egypt’s Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics (CAPMAS) since 1998. In this paper, we focus particularly on the 2012 round (ELMPS 2012). As in a typical labor force survey, the ELMPS covers topics such as employment, unemployment, job dynamics, and earnings but also provides very rich information on education, migration, and socio-economic characteristics. In 2012, the ELMPS interviewed 12,060 households, which yields to a total sample size of 49,186 individuals. The ELMPS 2012 includes a refresher sample of 2,000 households that was selected from an additional 200 Primary Sampling Units (PSUs) randomly selected from a new master sample prepared by CAPMAS. By design, it oversampled areas with high migration rates, and is nationally representative once weights are applied (Assaad and Krafft 2013).Footnote 6

We rely on the return migration module that surveys all individuals aged between 15 and 59 years old. In 2012, about 10% of the households had a returnee. In the ELMPS, a returnee is defined as an individual who has worked abroad for more than 6 months, but was back in Egypt at the time of the survey. This module features return migrants’ characteristics, incidences of migration, reasons for migration, financial situation before migration, year and country of first migration episode, year of final return, earnings and savings abroad, and remittances, as well as documents obtained to travel and work abroad. In addition, the ELMPS 2012 collects rich retrospective information on previous employment characteristics and their location. At the same time, households are asked about current members of the household who were overseas at the time of the survey, and collects information on their overseas destination, overseas employment, migration duration, and frequency of contact/visits to the household back home.

3.2 Non-migrants versus return migrants

We focus on working-age men, aged 15 to 59 years old at the time of survey, as Egyptian migration is mostly male dominated. In Table 1, we report descriptive statistics on the sample of non-migrants (individuals who never migrated) and return migrants (individuals who migrated for work purposes and returned to Egypt). The two groups of individuals are significantly different along a set of individual, geographical, and job characteristics. Returnees are found to be significantly older compared to non-migrants, and also significantly more likely to be married. Returnees are also found to be more likely to have secondary education but less likely to have above secondary education compared to non-migrants. The incidence of rural residence is also significantly higher among return migrants compared to non-migrants.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics: Non-migrants and returnees who are wage earners

In terms of geographical locations, returnees are found to be less likely to live in Cairo, Alexandria, Canal cities, and urban Upper Egypt, and significantly more likely to live in rural Lower Egypt.Footnote 7 Returnees also have greater job tenure compared to non-migrants and we find that the incidence of having a work contract is also higher among return migrants. In terms of sectors of employment, returnees are significantly more likely to be employed in the public sector for their job in 2012 compared to non-migrants. In terms of economic activities, we find that non-migrants are significantly more likely to be employed in manufacturing, mining, and quarrying, and in wholesale and retail trade compared to return migrants.

3.3 Defining undocumented migration

In the ELMPS 2012, return migrants were asked whether they had a visa or official document to enter the destination country during the first migration episode, as well as the type of document they had.Footnote 8 Relying on this information, we are able to identify documented and undocumented migrants among the pool of return migrants. For most of the destination countries, Egyptian migrants are required to have a visa. For a few countries, like Sudan, Libya, Jordan, Lebanon, and Yemen, Egyptians are not required to have a visa or can ask for a visa on arrival.

We define undocumented migrants as those who entered the destination country without having a visa or official document, for countries that required an entry visa, or as those who did not have a work contract for their employment abroad, for countries that did not require an entry visa. This definition accounts for over-stayers in destination countries that have a visa waiver for Egyptians since an over-stayer who is working in these countries is likely to work as an undocumented worker, i.e., without a work contract. However, for countries that require an entry visa, an undocumented immigrant could have entered legally the destination country with a visa and over-stayed beyond the period for which admission was granted. Thus, to account for over-stayers in countries that require Egyptians to have a visa, we additionally consider as undocumented migrants those who entered the destination country with a work permit, a tourist visa, a visit visa or a temporary residence permit, and were working in the destination country without work contract.Footnote 9 Therefore, an undocumented migrant (1) is a migrant who did not have a visa or official document to enter the destination country if the country required an entry visa, (2) was working without a work contract for countries that had a visa waiver for Egyptians, or (3) had a work permit, a tourist visa, a visit visa, or a temporary residence permit but was working in the destination without any work contract (to potentially capture over-stayers).

3.4 Documented versus undocumented migrants

In our definition of undocumented migration, we focus on the first migration episode, since all the information provided in the dataset on the migrants’ legal status to enter the destination country is relative to the first migration.Footnote 10 In Table 2, we focus on the sample of returnees and compare returnees who had a legal migration status when they entered the destination country during their first migration episode to those who had an illegal migration. An important difference between documented and undocumented migrants is their level of educational attainment. Documented migrants are significantly more likely to have an above secondary education compared to undocumented migrants, while undocumented migrants are more likely to have no educational degree. In terms of geographical regions, documented migrants are more likely to live in Cairo and Upper Egypt, both urban and rural, whereas, undocumented migrants are more likely to live in rural Lower Egypt. As for their job in 2012 upon return, undocumented migrants have greater job tenure by approximately 2 years and are significantly less likely to have a work contract compared to documented migrants. Along the spectrum of sectors of employment and economic activities, both documented and undocumented migrants seem to be equally employed in the different economic sectors and activities.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics: Documented versus undocumented return migrants

In Table 13 in the Appendix, we examine additional differences between documented and undocumented migrants with respect to their migration spell abroad. Documented migrants are found to have significantly higher monthly earnings and savings while abroad. They are also more likely to remit and to send higher remittances compared to undocumented migrants. In addition, documented migrants are found to have longer migration spells relative to undocumented migrants, by 1 year on average. However, there is no significant difference in terms of number of migration episodes between the two groups—as they both seem on average to have one migration spell. In the 1980s, a significantly higher proportion of undocumented migrants migrated compared to documented migrants. By contrast, in the 1990s and in the 2000s, a higher proportion of documented migrants migrated for the first time compared to undocumented migrants. In terms of destination choice, undocumented migrants were significantly more likely to choose Libya and Iraq. However, documented migrants were found to be significantly more likely to migrate to Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, Kuwait, and other destination countries.Footnote 11

Looking at the average hourly wages in 2012 for non-migrants, returnees, documented and undocumented migrants in Table 3, we find that the average hourly wage for returnees is higher than non-migrants.Footnote 12 We also find that documented migrants have higher hourly wages compared to undocumented migrants upon return. In the second column, we report the difference in hourly wages between each group and non-migrants. Indeed, we find that the difference in hourly wages between documented migrants and non-migrants is the largest, while we find that the difference in hourly wages between undocumented migrants and non-migrants is the smallest.

Table 3 Average hourly wages for non-migrants, returnees by legal status

4 Empirical strategy

4.1 The empirical model and identification

We estimate the effect of the legal status of migrants on their wages upon return by using a relatively new estimation technique—a Conditional Mixed Process (CMP) estimator—following Roodman (2011). The CMP model jointly estimates two or more equations with correlations in the error processes, while the dependent variables may or may not be correlated within this system of equations. The modeling framework of CMP is essentially similar to fitting a Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) model. However, the standard SUR consistently estimates models with continuous dependent variables using OLS and requires the error term in each equation to have a zero conditional mean. The latter assumption in SUR rules out simultaneity or the presence of endogenous variables. The CMP model, on the other hand, estimates mixed processes, i.e., it does not require classical continuous dependent variables. It offers a broad spectrum to estimate different types of dependent variables including binary, categorical, or censored outcomes.

As opposed to SUR, the CMP modeling framework can fit instrumental variables system to deal with endogeneity or simultaneity, and is therefore appropriate to estimate multi-equation models in which endogenous variables appear on the right-hand side of other equations. Moreover, the CMP model is conditional on the data as it allows the different equations in the model to vary by observations. This means that equations can be estimated on different samples which may or may not overlap. For structural models in which the data-generating process is fully modeled, CMP is full information maximum likelihood estimator (FIML), while CMP is limited information maximum likelihood (LIML) for models in which some equations are structural and other equations are reduced forms, as in 2SLS, to provide instruments for identification of the parameters in the structural equations.

We estimate the effect of migrants’ legal status on their wages upon return by taking into account the selection into migration, the selection into legal status, and the selection into return. Our structural equation—in which we estimate the effect of illegality on wages—is therefore augmented with reduced form equations to account for these various layers of selection.

In our structural equation, Wi denotes the logarithm of hourly wages in 2012 upon return to Egypt. We fit two distinct equations. In equation 1a, we estimate the effect of illegality conditional on being a return migrant on wages upon return, where Mi denotes the probability of migration. Our sample therefore consists of return migrants and we compare migrants with illegal status to those with legal status. In equation (1b), we estimate instead the effect of illegality and legality, unconditional on return migration. Thus, our sample consists of return migrants and non-migrants, which allows us to compare migrants with illegal status to those with legal status relative to non-migrants.

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} W_{i}= \delta_{0}+ \delta_{1~} (Illegal_{i} \vert M_{i}=1) + \delta_{2}~X_{i} + \delta_{3}~Z_{i} +v_{i} \end{array} $$
(1a)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} W_{i}= \delta_{0}+ \delta_{1~}Illegal_{i}+ \delta_{2~}Legal_{i}+ \delta_{3}~X_{i} + \delta_{4}~Z_{\text{i}}+v_{i} \end{array} $$
(1b)

Our regressions control for the vector (Xi) for individual characteristics, which includes individual’s age and its squared term, a dummy variable for rural residence, highest level of educational attainment dummies (no educational degree, primary or preparatory education, and secondary education), and parental controls (a dummy for having an illiterate father or mother, a dummy for having a wage-worker father, and a dummy for having a wage-worker mother). In equations (1a) and (1b), we also include labor market controls (Zi) such as a dummy for public sector employment, job tenure in years, and its squared term.

To deal with the triple selection into emigration, illegality, and return decisions, we model three interrelated decisions through reduced form equations: (1) the probability of emigration, (2) the probability of undocumented migration, and (3) the probability of return migration. Our total sample consists of 14,897 observations: 12,804 individuals are non-migrants, 1,346 are return migrants (out of whom 481 had an undocumented migration), and 747 individuals are current migrants.Footnote 13

First, we denote the probability of temporary migration as Mi. An individual decides to migrate when the unobservable latent variable M capturing the individual gains from migration is positive, while an individual decides to stay if the gains from migration are negative. For identification of equation (2), we use the inflation adjusted oil prices (Oilt) for each individual at the age of 25, the average age of migration. To obtain an exogenous source of variation in the probability of migration, we follow the same identification strategy proposed by Wahba and Zenou (2012), Wahba (2015), and Elmallakh and Wahba (2021b). The rationale behind using historic oil prices as a predictor of the migration probability is that other Arab countries constitute the most important destination for Egyptian migrants, where oil prices played a crucial role in driving the demand for foreign labor both directly in the Gulf countries or indirectly, in other non-oil-producing Arab countries.Footnote 14 When estimating equation (2), the sample includes return migrants, current migrants, and non-migrants.Footnote 15

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} M_{i}= \alpha_{0}+ \alpha_{1}~X_{i}+ \alpha_{2}~Oil_{t}+ \varepsilon_{i} ~~~~~~~~ M_{i}= \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \text{1 if }M^{\ast}>0\\ \text{0 if }M^{\ast} \leq 0 \end{array}\right. \end{array} $$
(2)

Second, we denote the probability of undocumented migration by Ii. This is only observed for the subsample of migrants. Therefore, the sample used to estimate equation (3) only includes return and current migrants. A migrant decides to undertake an illegal migration if the value of the unobservable latent variable I is positive and it captures the perceived gains from undocumented migration. By contrast, a migrant decides to undertake a legal migration if the value of the latent variable I is negative. In equation (3), we use the diplomatic exchange (Dipc,t) between Egypt and the countries of destination of Egyptian migrants at the time of migration for identification. The diplomatic exchange variable is both country and year specific, and is derived from the Correlates of War Diplomatic exchange dataset.Footnote 16 Our diplomatic exchange variable captures diplomatic representation at the level of Chargé d’Affaires, minister, and ambassador between Egypt and all members of the Correlates of War interstate system, every 5 years for our period of analysis.Footnote 17 The identifying assumption is that exogenous shocks to the bilateral diplomatic relations between Egypt and the countries of destination of Egyptian migrants constitute a strong predictor of undocumented migration.

$$ (I_{i} \vert M_{i}=1) = \beta_{0}+ \beta_{1}~X_{i}+ \beta_{2}~Dip_{c,t}+ \omega_{i} ~~~~~~~~~ I_{i}= \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \text{1 if }I^{\ast}>0\\ \text{0 if }I^{\ast} \leq 0 \end{array}\right. $$
(3)

Third, we also account for return migration; i.e., not every migrant returns to Egypt within our window of observation. The probability of return migration is denoted by Ri. This is only observed for the subsample of migrants (current and return migrants). A migrant decides to return to Egypt if the value of the unobservable latent variable R is positive and it captures the gains from return migration. By contrast, a migrant decides to stay abroad if the value of the latent variable R is negative. For identification of equation (4), we use the number of active armed conflicts (Conflictc,t) in the countries of destination of Egyptian migrants at the time of migration (for current migrants) and at the time of return migration (for return migrants). We rely on this instrument for the identification of the return migration equation since most Egyptians migrate to other Arab countries and since, in recent years, many of these countries experienced a series of conflicts. To name just a few, these conflicts include the Iran-Iraq war between 1980 and 1988, the 1986 South Yemen civil war, the Gulf war in 1990 and 1991, and the Iraq war in 2003 following the US invasion. The identifying assumption is that conflict occurrence in these countries constitutes a strong predictor of return migration. The number of active armed conflicts is both country and year specific and comes from the Monadic Conflict Onset and Incidence dataset of the Uppsala Conflict Data Project (UCDP).Footnote 18

$$ R_{i}= \gamma_{0}+ \gamma_{1}~X_{i}+ \gamma_{2}~Conflict_{c,t}+ \tau_{i}~ ~~~~~~~~ R_{i}= \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \text{1 if }R^{\ast}>0\\ \text{0 if }R^{\ast} \leq 0 \end{array}\right. $$
(4)

When estimating the reduced form equation (2), equation (3), and equation (4), our regressions include the same vector of individual controls (Xi). In these equations, Xi additionally includes decades of migration dummies. In our CMP model, the error terms v, ε, ω, and τ are allowed to be correlated through a multidimensional distribution.

4.2 Discussion on the exclusion restrictions

In this section, we discuss issues pertaining to the validity of our empirical model presented in Section 4.1. First, in Section 4.2.1, we discuss the exclusion restriction of oil prices and present evidence supporting the orthogonality of oil prices to both illegality and return decisions. Second, in Section 4.2.2, we discuss the evolution of Egypt’s diplomatic relations with other Arab countries and provide evidence that migration is not influenced by the bilateral relationship of countries. Third, in Section 4.2.3, we discuss concerns related to the exclusion restriction of conflict occurrence and how we address them empirically.

4.2.1 The exclusion restriction of oil prices

The exclusion restriction of oil prices is that oil prices affect wages in Egypt only through temporary migration decision. Since Egypt is a non-dependent oil economy, the exclusion restriction holds if oil prices at the age of 25 are not correlated with employment and wages in Egypt. To provide support to our identifying assumption, in Fig. 1 in panel a, we present oil prices against key aggregate economic indicators in Egypt including GDP annual growth rate, male labor force participation rate, male employment in agriculture (% of total male employment), male employment in industry (% of total male employment), and male employment in services (% of total male employment).Footnote 19 The top panel in Fig. 1 provides support to our exclusion restriction since key economic and labor market indicators in Egypt are unaffected by oil prices’ fluctuations.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Oil prices, aggregate indicators, and migration flows. Oil prices are inflation adjusted and expressed in $ per barrel. In panel a, labor force participation rate, employment in agriculture, industry, and services are from the International Labor Organization, Key indicators of the Labor Market Database. GDP growth rates are from the World Bank National accounts data files. Panel b presents a scatter plot of the inflation adjusted oil prices (horizontal X-axis) and the share of migrants per year (vertical Y-axis). The share of migrants is derived from the ELMPS 2012 using information on current and return migration and the year of migration and is computed as the number of migrants in a specific year divided by the number total migrants. The dashed line represents a fitted regression line

In Fig. 1 in panel b, we present a scatter plot featuring the evolution of the inflation adjusted oil prices and migration patterns from the 1960s to 2010. The share of migrants is derived from the ELMPS (2012), using information on both current and return migrants, and on the year of migration. The fitted regression line shows a positive correlation between oil prices and the share of migrants. While panel a provides support to the exclusion restriction of oil prices, panel b shows that oil prices constitute indeed a strong predictor of migration decisions.

A potential threat to identification would be the non-orthogonality of oil prices (1) to legal status of migrants, or (2) to return decisions. We discuss these two issues and present evidence supporting the orthogonality of oil prices to these two decisions. In Fig. 2 in panel a, we present the yearly evolution of oil prices and the percent of undocumented migrants derived from the ELMPS.Footnote 20 If oil price shocks directly affect the probability of illegal migration, this would suggest that when oil prices are high, Egyptian migrants might be more frequently willing to emigrate irregularly since it would be more profitable. Panel a in Fig. 2 shows that the two series—oil prices and the share of undocumented migrants—do not follow the same trend. Indeed, this figure shows several episodes of spikes in oil prices, during which irregular migration remained low. Conversely, irregular migration was particularly high in the late 1960s and early 1970s—a period with relatively low oil prices. We further corroborate this evidence in panel b, where we present a scatter plot on the relationship between oil prices and the share of undocumented migrants from the 1960s to 2010. Panel b in Fig. 2 additionally confirms the orthogonality of oil prices with respect to irregular migration flows. Indeed, there does not seem to be any correlation between oil prices and illegality. We find a correlation coefficient of 0.042 with an associated P-value of 0.787.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Oil prices and illegal migration flows. Oil prices are inflation adjusted and expressed in $ per barrel. The percent of undocumented migrants is derived from the ELMPS 2012, using information on current and return migrants, and the year of migration and is computed as the number of undocumented migrants in a specific year to the total number of migrants in the same year. Panel a presents the yearly evolution of oil prices and the percent of undocumented migrants. Panel b presents a scatter plot of the inflation adjusted oil prices (horizontal X-axis) and the percent of undocumented migrants per year (vertical Y-axis). The dashed line represents a fitted regression line

For the validity of the identification strategy, we additionally discuss the issue of non-orthogonality of oil prices to return migration decisions. A potential concern would be if individuals who migrate with high oil price may also be more likely to return when oil prices go down. In Fig. 3 in panel a, we present the evolution of oil prices against the evolution of both the share of return migrants and the share of migrants from the late 1960s to 2012. While we find that the share of migrants closely mimics oil price fluctuations, we do not find a clear association between oil price shocks and the share of return migrants. While return migration seems to have peaked in the late 1980s following the drop in oil prices, it likewise peaked again in the late 2000s even though oil registered particularly high price levels. The direction of the association between oil prices and return migration is therefore not a priori clear. In panel b, we further present a scatter plot on the relationship between oil prices and the share of return migrants. The fitted regression line shows that oil prices are indeed uncorrelated with return migration flows. We find a correlation coefficient of 0.118 with a P-value 0.476. The evidence provided in Fig. 2 and Fig. 3 therefore shows that oil prices are indeed orthogonal to both illegality and return decisions.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Oil prices and return migration flows. Oil prices are inflation adjusted and expressed in $ per barrel. The percent of return migrants is derived from the ELMPS 2012, using information on return migration and the year of final return. The percent of return migrants is computed as the share of return migrants in a specific year to the total number of return migrants. In panel a, the percent of migrants is derived from the ELMPS 2012, using information on the year of first migration among return migrants. Panel b presents a scatter plot of the inflation adjusted oil prices (horizontal X-axis) and the share of return migrants per year (vertical Y-axis). The dashed line represents a fitted regression line

4.2.2 The exclusion restriction of diplomatic exchange

Before discussing the exclusion restriction of our diplomatic exchange variable, we also highlight the evolution of Egypt’s diplomatic relations and the variability of diplomatic representation for the validity of our identification strategy.

In Table 14 in the Appendix, we report the share of countries with diplomatic representation in Egypt by year.Footnote 21 Indeed, our diplomatic representation variable shows significant variability over time. The first important decrease in diplomatic representation between Egypt and migrants’ destination countries—predominantly other Arab countries—is observed in the 1960s. Nasser, the Egyptian president at the time who was elected in 1956, was becoming increasingly popular in the Arab world as the leader for pan-Arabism which culminated in the United Arab Republic with Syria in the late 1950s and early 1960s. As Nasser’s ideology gained support in various Arab countries, disagreements emerged between Egypt and Arab monarchies, importantly, Saudi Arabia, for which pan-Arabism posed a real threat to its stability. While Egypt’s pan-Arab ideology resonated with a number of Arab countries, it also led to conflicting dynamics with the monarchies (Mann 2012). These dynamics explain the observed decrease in diplomatic representation in the 1960s and early 1970s.

The second sharp decrease in diplomatic representation is observed in the 1980s. This episode coincides with Egypt’s signing of the Camp David Agreement with Israel in 1978, followed by the conclusion of the peace treaty between the two countries in 1979. Following these events, the perception of the Arab world towards Egypt changed in particular, since for decades Egypt was presumed to stand for Arab interests. In November 1978, in a summit meeting held in Baghdad, a consensus among Arab countries was reached to impose economic and political sanctions on Egypt (Lavy 1984; Sullivan 1999). Egypt was subsequently suspended from the Arab League from 1979 until 1989. Evidently, this political and economic embargo negatively affected the bilateral relations between Egypt and other Arab countries, as reflected in the sharp drop in diplomatic representation in the 1980s. As shown in the descriptive statistics in Table 13 in the Appendix, these events coincide with greater undocumented migration in the 1980s.

A potential concern would be if migration is influenced by the bilateral relationship of countries, i.e., if individuals consider the bilateral diplomatic relations between Egypt and alternative countries of destination when taking their migration decisions. To dispel this concern, in Fig. 4 in the Appendix, we present the share of migrants who migrated to countries without diplomatic representation and to countries with diplomatic representation in Egypt by year of migration.Footnote 22 Figure 4 shows that migrants do not consistently consider diplomatic representation when undertaking their migration decisions. For instance, in the years between 1968 and 1980, all migrants went to countries with no diplomatic representation in Egypt. On the other hand, in every single year between 1981 and 1990, migrants predominantly chose to migrate to countries without diplomatic representation in Egypt. Between 1992 and 1995, the majority of migrants chose destinations with diplomatic representation, while a non-negligible share of migrants still migrated to countries with no diplomatic representation. On the other hand, from 1996 onwards, migration was destined to countries with diplomatic exchange but it is important to note that this is a period with little variability in diplomatic representation, as shown in Table 14 in the Appendix.

Overall, these patterns do not show a clear-cut relationship between diplomatic representation and migration, whereby individuals decide to migrate mostly to countries with diplomatic representation. In fact, Fig. 4 suggests that diplomatic representation does not predict migration decisions. Elmallakh and Wahba (2021a) further investigate the relationship between diplomatic exchange and migration flows. They present a scatter plot on the relationship between diplomatic representation and the share of migrants. Even though the scatter plot is derived from data of limited sample size, the analysis confirms that migration is not directly influenced by diplomatic exchange, in line with Fig. 4.

4.2.3 The exclusion restriction of conflicts

In this section, we discuss two concerns related to the exclusion restriction of conflicts in the return migration equation and how we address them empirically in Section 6. The first one is that our instrument would only predict forced return migration due to armed conflicts and not planned return migration. To address this challenge, in Section 6, we also control for labor market outcomes at destination to account for planned return migration. We augment our return migration equation (4) with the unemployment rate at destination at the time of return migration (for return migrants) and at the time of the survey in 2012 (for current migrants). This allows us to account for both forced return migration and planned return.

While conflict occurrence in host countries constitutes a strong predictor of return migration, an empirical concern would be if conflicts might have consequences on the Egyptian economy through, for instance, changes in trade flows, foreign direct investments, or remittances. To address this concern, we additionally rely on data from the World Bank Development Indicators in order to control for FDI (% of GDP), remittances (% of GDP), and the exports and imports of goods and services (% of GDP) in Egypt in equation (4). We show in Section 6 that our results are robust to these two checks, which provides support to the exclusion restriction of conflict occurrence.

5 Empirical findings

5.1 Does the legal status of migrants matter upon return?

5.1.1 Hourly wages upon return

In Table 4, we depart from simple OLS regressions to estimate the effect of return migration on wages in 2012 upon return. We are interested in examining whether the legal status of migrants has a differential effect on their wage premium upon return. In column (1), we focus on the full sample of non-migrants and returnees. In column (2), we focus on the subsample of documented migrants compared to non-migrants, and in column (3), we compare undocumented migrants to non-migrants. Without accounting for any of the selection issues presented earlier, Table 4 shows that controlling for individual and job characteristics, return migration is associated with a significant wage premium. However, when we disentangle the effects by legal status, the results show that this positive association between return migration and wages holds only for documented migrants.

Table 4 Estimating the effect of return migration on hourly wages

Accounting for the triple selection into migration, illegality, and return using a conditional mixed process model, in Table 5, we estimate equation (1a) on the effect of illegality on hourly wages upon return, conditional on return migration. We start by presenting the results from the reduced form equations and then discuss the results from our primary structural equation (1a). First, we find that oil prices are a strong predictor of the probability of migration. In column (1), we find that a one dollar increase in oil prices leads to an increase in the probability of migration by 1.3 percentage points. Diplomatic exchange also plays a crucial role in explaining the legal migrant status. In column (2), we find strong suggestive evidence that negative shocks to the bilateral relations between Egypt and the countries of destination of Egyptian migrants, at the time of migration, drive illegal migration to the destination countries. Indeed, we find that the lack of diplomatic representation of countries of destination in Egypt leads to an increase in the probability of illegal migration by 23 percentage points. As for identification of the return migration, in column (3), we find that an additional active armed conflict that occurs in the destination country at the time of return migration (for return migrants) or at the time of migration (for current migrants) increases the probability of return migration by 5 percentage points. Correcting for this triple selection into migration, illegality, and return, in column (4), we find that undocumented migrants witness a wage penalty compared to legal migrants upon return to Egypt.

Table 5 Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on hourly wages after return, conditional on return migration

To assess how undocumented migrants fare with respect to non-migrants in terms of wages upon return, in Table 6, we estimate equation (1b) unconditional on return migration. Therefore, in column (4), our sample includes non-migrants in addition to return migrants (documented and undocumented). Indeed, we find that undocumented migrants witness a wage penalty relative to non-migrants, while only documented migrants witness a wage premium. To compute the wage penalty associated with undocumented migration, we rely on the predicted logarithm of hourly wages for non-migrants, illegal, and legal migrants in the last row of Table 6. The difference in logarithms approximate the percentage change in hourly wages. We find that undocumented migration yields to a 19% wage penalty with respect to non-migrants. On the other hand, we find that documented migration leads to a positive wage premium of 28%. The estimates therefore suggest that the wage penalty of undocumented migrants relative to documented migrants is estimated to be around 47%.Footnote 23

Table 6 Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on hourly wages after return, unconditional on return migration

5.1.2 Occupations, labor supply, and monthly wages upon return

While we are primarily interested in the impact of illegality on hourly wages upon return, in this section, we expand our analysis to other outcomes such as occupations, labor supply, and monthly wages upon return. In Tables 7 and 8, we examine the effect of migrants’ legal status on occupations and labor supply upon return, respectively. We estimate equation (1b), unconditional on return migration. In Table 7, our dependent variable is occupational ranking. Occupations are split into 9 distinct categories according to the ISCO-88 one digit classification. They are ranked from 1 to 9 according to the amount of human capital needed to be employed in each occupation following Sicherman and Galor (1990) and Carletto and Kilic (2011). According to this ranking, our dependent variable takes the value 1 for the lowest-ranked occupation and 9 for the highest-ranked occupation.Footnote 24 In Table 8, our independent variable of interest is the number of hours of work/week. Accounting for the triple selection into emigration, legal status, and return, Table 7 shows that migrants’ legal status does not have any significant effect on occupations upon return. Even though illegal migrants seem to have lower ranked occupations compared to non-migrants upon return, the results show that the effect is not statistically significant. Table 8 reports the results on labor supply. Likewise, the results in Table 8 show that migrants’ legal status does not have any significant effect on labor supply. Indeed, we find that undocumented migrants have lower labor supply compared to non-migrants, while documented migrants seem to work more than non-migrants. However, these effects are not statistically significant.

Table 7 Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on occupations after return, unconditional on return migration
Table 8 Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on labor supply, unconditional on return migration

Finally, in Table 9, we examine the effect of migrants’ legal status on monthly wages upon return. We estimate equation (1b), unconditional on return migration. Our main outcome of interest is the logarithm of monthly wages upon return to Egypt. We account for the various layers of selection in columns (1) to (3), and in column (4), we report the results from our structural equation. The results in Table 9 confirm that undocumented migrants witness a wage penalty with respect to both documented migrants and non-migrants. In terms of monthly wages, we find that undocumented migrants witness a wages penalty of 28% compared to non-migrants, while documented migrants witness a wage premium of 29% relative to non-migrants. In terms of monthly wages, the estimated penalty for undocumented migrants is larger in magnitude compared to the estimates presented in Section 5.1.1 in terms of hourly wages. On the other hand, the wage premium of documented migrants remains of the same magnitude.

Table 9 Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on monthly wages after return, unconditional on return migration

5.2 Underlying mechanisms: does the legal status of migrants matter while abroad?

The results in Section 5.1 suggest that undocumented migrants fare worse upon return to Egypt compared to documented migrants but also compared to non-migrants. While documented migrants benefit from their migration experience abroad and witness a positive wage premium compared to non-migrants, undocumented migrants witness a wage penalty associated with their experience overseas. In this section, we investigate several underlying mechanisms.

In the ELMPS, individuals are asked about the reasons for return. Interestingly, we find that the primary motives for return migration differ between return migrants who had a documented migration versus those who had an undocumented migration. For example, while the most important cause of return migration is the end of the work contract for documented migrants (26%), the primary reason for return for undocumented migrants is poor working conditions (30%).Footnote 25 In line with

Gonzales (2011), Gleeson and Gonzales (2012), and Hall and Greenman (2015), this might suggest that undocumented migrants are employed in poorer jobs, which might make them less likely to benefit from their migration experience overseas compared to documented migrants. In this section, we explore the effect of migrants’ illegal status on various outcomes during their migration spells abroad including: monthly wages, monthly savings, migration duration, occupations, and the probability of remitting.

In Table 10, we test for potential underlying mechanisms that could be driving our results. We rely on our benchmark CMP model to account for the triple selection into emigration, legal status, and into return. We report the results on the various selection equations in columns (1) to (3), while columns (4a) to (4e) report the results from our structural equation on various outcomes pertaining to the migration experience overseas. We estimate equation (1a), conditional on return migration. Therefore, the sample used in the estimation of our structural equations includes only return migrants (both documented and undocumented). We estimate separate models for each of the outcomes presented in columns (4a) to (4e), where we account, in each, for the various layers of selection. The first three columns: the probability of emigration, the probability of illegality, and the probability of return migration are therefore the same across models.

Table 10 The effect of return migrants’ legal status on various outcomes overseas

In line with the descriptive statistics presented in Table 13 in the Appendix, the results in Table 10 suggest that the illegal status of migrants negatively affects their monthly wages and savings, while abroad. Accounting for the triple selection into migration, illegality, and return, the results in Table 10 suggest that illegal migrants overseas earn half the wage of documented migrants. Likewise, we find that the undocumented migration status is associated with significantly lower monthly savings overseas. We also find that illegality reduces migration duration, by approximately 2 years. As we show at the bottom of Table 10, the predicted migration duration for undocumented migrants is 3 years, while the predicted duration for documented migrants is approximately 5 years.

In column (4d), we report the results on occupational ranking overseas. Our results show that migrants’ illegal status is associated with a significant decline in occupational ranking. This suggests that undocumented migrants hold lower ranked occupations, while overseas, compared to documented migrants. In terms of occupational ranking, undocumented migrants seem to be employed in occupations that are on average 1 point lower, on the occupational ladder, compared to documented migrants. Finally, in column (4e), we further examine the impact of illegality on the probability of sending remittances. Controlling for wages overseas and based on the predicted probabilities of remitting in the last row of Table 10, the results show that illegality leads to a 46% reduction in the probability of sending remittances.

Overall, these results suggest that the underlying mechanism for the wage penalty experienced by undocumented migrants is driven by bad overseas jobs, i.e., human capital waste story. Indeed, we find that undocumented migrants primarily return to Egypt due to poor working conditions in the destination. We further showed in this section that migrants’ illegal status is associated with lower ranked occupations overseas. These lower ranked jobs are also associated with lower earnings, lower savings, and lower incidence to send remittances. While documented migrants enhance their human capital overseas, which leads to remuneration gains upon return, our findings suggest that the migration experience of an undocumented migrant depletes their human capital, leading to wage losses upon return.

5.3 Discussion on other selection issues

Our benchmark results deal with three layers of selection, namely, the selection into emigration, the selection into the legal status, and the selection into return migration. Nonetheless, other selectivity or endogeneity issues might still be a source of concern. For instance, it seems reasonable to expect that (observable and unobservable) individual characteristics affect the choice of destination, or that emigrants choose between different destination countries, taking into account changes in the relative payoffs from moving to one country versus another. This might be problematic if the differential returns that we estimate are due to the different groups of countries that documented and undocumented migrants decide to choose as their destinations.

While our model does not explicitly deal with multiple destination choices, we address this concern by comparing Egyptian workers who migrated to the same country of destination, as either documented or undocumented migrants, to identify the causal impact of legal status on wages back home. In Table 11, we restrict our analysis to returnees from Iraq, the most important country of return migration when estimating equation (1b). In this equation, our analysis is restricted to returnees from Iraq, while returnees from all other countries are excluded from the sample. Comparing documented and undocumented Egyptian migrants who went to the same country of destination, Iraq, the results in Table 11 consistently point out to a wage penalty associated with undocumented migration, and to a wage premium witnessed by documented migrants.

Table 11 Robustness checks, restricting the analysis to Iraq. Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on hourly wages after return, unconditional on return migration

Furthermore, the data shows that both documented and undocumented migrants choose the same pool of destination countries, at the exception of western countries where we only observe documented migrants. To make sure that our results are therefore not driven by these differential destination choices, in Table 15 in the Appendix, we also exclude return migrants from all Western countries.Footnote 26 Our results also hold after excluding this subset of destination countries. These two tests therefore confirm that our findings are not driven by differential destination choices made by documented and undocumented migrants.

Another potential concern is the endogeneity of the migration duration. This would be problematic if the wage penalty of undocumented return migrants is due to their shorter migration duration compared to documented migrants. While we cannot control for migration duration in our model since it is an endogenous variable and would be considered as a bad control, we address this challenge empirically by focusing on documented and undocumented migrants with similar migration duration. We estimate the impact of illegal status on migrants’ wages upon return relying on three separate models in Table 12. First, we estimate the model by focusing on migrants who belong to the lowest 33rd percentile of the distribution of migration duration (those who have 2 years of migration or less) and we report the corresponding results in column (4a). Second, we estimate the model by considering returnees who belong to the middle 33rd percentile of the distribution with 3 to 5 years of migration and we report results in column (4b). Finally, we focus on returnees who belong to the highest 33rd percentile of migration duration with 6 years of migration or more in column (4c). The first three estimated equations: the probability of emigration, the probability of illegality, and the probability of return migration are the same across the three models. Interestingly, we find that the results are mostly driven by returnees who belong to the upper end of the migration duration distribution—those with 3 years of migration duration or more. Moreover, it is interesting to note that the wage gap between documented and undocumented return migrants grows bigger the longer the migrants stay abroad. Indeed, the predicted probabilities reported at the bottom of Table 12 show that documented migrants’ predicted hourly wage upon return appreciates with the length of stay abroad, while undocumented migrants’ predicted hourly wage depreciates the longer the migrant’s migration spell. These dynamics address the concern that undocumented migrants are faring worse due to the shorter migration spells as these results, in fact, show the opposite dynamic; the longer undocumented migrants stay abroad, the more their human capital is depleted. These dynamics are also fully consistent with the theoretical argument of human capital waste for undocumented migrants and on the other hand, with greater human capital accumulation for documented migrants.

Table 12 Heterogeneous effects by migration duration. Estimating the effect of migrants’ legal status on hourly wages after return, conditional on return migration

6 Robustness checks

6.1 Alternative definitions

Throughout the paper, we define undocumented migrants as those who (1) did not have a visa or official document to enter the destination country if the country required an entry visa, (2) were working without a work contract for countries that had a visa waiver for Egyptians, or (3) had a work permit, a tourist visa, a visit visa, or a temporary residence permit but were working in the destination without any work contract to capture over-stayers. In this section, we rely on an alternative definition of undocumented migration. We simply define undocumented migrants as those who either entered the destination country without a visa or an official document for countries that required an entry visa or those who did not have a work contract for their employment abroad in countries that did not require an entry visa for Egyptians. Elmallakh and Wahba (2021a) show that the results are consistently robust to using this alternative definition of undocumented migration.

We also checked the robustness of our results with respect to the definition of diplomatic representation for the identification of the illegality equation. In our benchmark model, we use the diplomatic representation of each country of destination of the migrants in Egypt. To check the robustness of our results, we also use two alternative definitions. The first one captures instead the diplomatic representation of Egypt in each country of destination of migrants at the time of migration. It is a dummy variable equal to one if Egypt is diplomatically represented in the country of destination at the time of migration and zero, otherwise. The second definition captures the diplomatic representation in both Egypt and the country of destination of the migrants at the time of migration. In this case, the dummy variable takes the value one if there is diplomatic representation in both Egypt and the country of destination of the migrant at the time of migration and zero, otherwise. Elmallakh and Wahba (2021a) show that the results are also robust to these additional checks and remain stable in magnitude.

6.2 Alternative specifications

In this section, we check the robustness of our results to alternative specifications of our benchmark model. In the model we present in Section 4.1, there are three selection processes, namely migration, legal status of migrants, and return migration. Our benchmark model implicitly assumes that the legal status of migrants does not have an impact on return migration. However, it might be possible that the return migration decision and migrants’ legal status are closely linked.

Elmallakh and Wahba (2021a) also check the robustness of the results to incorporating the legal status into the return migration equation (4)—which models the return migration decision—therefore includes a dummy variable for illegal migration. We find a negative coefficient of illegality in the return migration equation, although it is not statistically significant. This suggests that there is no significant association between illegality and return decisions. As for the results from our structural equation, we consistently show that undocumented migration is associated with a wage penalty, while documented migrants witness a significant wage premium upon return. The magnitude of the estimated wage penalty and premium are 17% and 27%, respectively. Our benchmark results reported in Table 6 were associated with an estimated wage penalty of 19% and a wage premium of 28%. These effects are therefore very comparable in terms of magnitude.

As presented in Section 4.2, we also check the validity of the exclusion restriction of conflict occurrence. Since our instrument could only be predicting forced return migration due to armed conflicts and not planned return migration, we also control for unemployment rate in the destination country in the return migration equation. The unemployment rate is both country and year specific. For return migrants, the unemployment rate is matched with the year of return migration, while we matched the unemployment rate at the time of the survey in 2012 for current migrants.

We report our results in Table 16 in the Appendix. We deal with the selection into emigration, legal status, and into return in columns (1) to (3). For the identification of the return migration equation, column (3) includes both the number of active armed conflicts and the unemployment rate in the destination. We find that both variables are positively associated with return migration. While an additional armed conflict in the destination country increases the probability of return migration by 2.8 percentage points, we find that a 1% increase in unemployment rate at destination is associated with 0.7% increase in the return probability. The results from our structural equation are reported in column (4) and are consistently robust to controlling for unemployment rates at destination in the return migration equation.

A related issue is that conflicts might have consequences on the Egyptian economy through, for instance, changes in trade flows, foreign direct investments, or remittances. In Table 17 in the Appendix, we check the robustness of our results to controlling for the following variables in Egypt in the return migration equation: FDI (% of GDP), remittances (% of GDP), and the exports and imports of goods and services (% of GDP).Footnote 27 Our results from the structural equation in column (4) are also consistently robust to controlling for these variables.

6.3 Using 2018 data

In this paper, we rely on data from the ELMPS 2012. Indeed, the 2012 survey is advantageous as it oversampled areas with high migration rates. As we discussed in Section 3.1, the most recent ELMPS data was conducted in 2018 and instead oversampled rural communities in Egypt. Nonetheless, in this section, we replicate our analysis using the most recent publicly available survey as a robustness check.

We examine the effect of migrants’ legal status on hourly wages in 2018, unconditional on return migration, by estimating equation (1b). In Table 18 in the Appendix, we report our results unconditional on return migration. We account for the various selection processes in columns (1) to (3) following the same identification strategy presented in Section 4.1. In line with our benchmark results presented in Section 5.1.1, we find that only documented migrants witness a wage premium relative to non-migrants, while undocumented migrants witness a wage penalty.

Elmallakh and Wahba (2021a) also check the robustness of the results to using pooled cross-sectional data from the 2012 and 2018 ELMPS. The model additionally includes a year fixed effect for the 2018 survey. Our results consistently show that undocumented migration is associated with a wage penalty, while migrants’ legal status leads to a positive wage premium upon return.

Relying on the 2018 data, we also analyze the dynamics of the effects. We ask whether the effect of legal status remains constant over time after return or varies. Accounting for the triple selection in columns (1) to (3), column (4) reports the results from the structural equation. To capture the dynamics of the effects, instead of focusing on the full 2018 sample as in Table 18, we restrict our analysis, in Table 19, to individuals who were interviewed in both ELMPS 2012 and 2018. We therefore track the same individuals included in our benchmark analysis in the 2018 survey. Our results consistently point to a wage penalty for undocumented migrants of 54% and to a wage premium for documented migrants of 16%. Comparing the magnitude of these effects with those from our benchmark model in Section 5.1.1, we find that undocumented migrants’ wage penalty grew larger over time. Moreover, while documented migrants still witness a significant wage premium upon return, our results show that legal migrants’ wage premium was actually larger in 2012 (28%). The evidence therefore suggests that the wage gap between non-migrants and undocumented migrants grew larger over time, while the wage gap between documented migrants and non-migrants narrowed down.

6.4 Other robustness checks

As we discussed earlier in the paper, the incidence of multiple migration episodes is very low in Egypt. In our dataset, approximately 95% of return migrants had one or two migration episodes and less than 5% had more than two migration episodes. Elmallakh and Wahba (2021a) also exclude individuals who had more than two migration episodes and show that the results are also robust to this check.

Finally, we check whether the differential results that we observed are due to differences in the reasons of return between documented and undocumented migrants. In Table 20 in the Appendix, we estimate two distinct models. Columns (1), (2), and (3) are the same across the two models, while in the first model, we focus on voluntary return migration (column 4a), and in the second model, we focus on involuntary return migration (column 4b). Voluntary reasons are the following: individuals return to get married, to set up business at home country, to take over family business or farm, due to poor working conditions, to care for family, to study, or due to an appointment. On the other hand, involuntary reasons include contract ended, sudden termination by employer, retirement, health problems, the war in Iraq or Kuwait, accident or illness, death, or compulsory military service. The estimates in columns (4a) and (4b) allow us to compare documented and undocumented migrants who returned due to voluntary or involuntary reasons, respectively.

Interestingly, we find that voluntary returns are associated with a wage penalty for undocumented migrants and a wage premium for documented migrants. On the other hand, we find that undocumented migrants who returned involuntary do not witness a wage penalty, while documented migrants still witness a wage premium. Indeed, we find that undocumented migrants who returned involuntary have lower migration duration (average migration duration is 3.6 years with a standard deviation of 3.7), while undocumented migrants who returned voluntary have on average 5.8 years of migration duration with a standard deviation of 6.6. In line with our results in Table 12, these differential effects might be associated with the length of the migration spell abroad. These results confirm once again that the longer undocumented migrants stay abroad, the more their human capital is depleted.

7 Concluding remarks

This paper examines the impact of the legal status of temporary overseas migration on migrants’ wages upon return to the home country. Using unique data from Egypt, we distinguish between return migrants according to their type of international migration—documented versus undocumented—and examine the impact of temporary migration on wages upon return. Relying on a conditional mixed process model, which takes into account the triple selection into emigration, illegality, and return migration, we examine the effect of illegality on wages upon return.

Our findings show that controlling for the various layers of selection, return migrants who had an illegal status while abroad have significantly lower earnings upon return compared to both documented return migrants and non-migrants. This suggests that undocumented migrants do not gain from their overseas migration experience in terms of skill acquisition the way documented migrants do. Our results show that the longer undocumented migrants stay abroad, the more their human capital is depleted, while the opposite is true for documented migrants. Indeed, we find evidence that undocumented migrants experience a waste of human capital overseas, as they have lower earnings and end up in lower ranked occupations while abroad, which might explain their lower earnings upon return.

Our results are the first to show the negative impact associated with illegality on the migrants, even after they return to their country of origin. These findings have important policy implications, as they suggest that there is a need to raise awareness among potential migrants about the negative consequences of illegal migration experiences. Furthermore, countries of origin should maximize the benefits of migration by supporting legal migration and curbing illegal migration.