Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Consequences of war: Japan’s demographic transition and the marriage market

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study explores the effects of imbalances in the sex ratio on both the quantity and the quality of children, with a focus on changes in intra-household bargaining power. We first present a theoretical model of intra-household bargaining in the presence of conflicting family goals within a couple, and show that male scarcity (a decrease in the male-to-female sex ratio) induces an increase in the number of children and a decrease in the quality of children. Second, using the impact of World War II on the sex ratio as a quasi-natural experiment, we establish empirically that the decrease in the male-to-female sex ratio in World War II contributed to a smaller decline in fertility and child mortality rates in postwar Japan. In particular, the fertility rate would have fallen by an additional 12% and the child mortality rate by an additional 13% between 1948 and 1970 absent the decrease in the sex ratio.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Since the seminal works by Becker, numerous studies have documented the role of the quantity-quality trade-off with regard to children (see Becker and Lewis 1973; Becker and Barro 1988; Barro and Becker 1989; Becker et al. 1990. The underlying mechanism of Becker’s theory, the shift toward quality, is led by preference, i.e., the higher elasticity of child quality with respect to income. On the contrary, the unified growth theory, in the vein of Galor and Weil (2000) and Galor and Moav (2002), explains this shift as the change in the relative net returns between child quality and quantity triggered by an event such as the Industrial Revolution, which drastically improves the returns from education. Recent studies using historical events, focusing on the quality-quantity trade-off of children, support the quality and quantity trade-off, thereby, favoring the latter explanation (Galor 2012; Fernihough 2017; Shiue 2017; Klemp and Weisdorf 2018). These findings on the interrelation between economic growth and family planning by households suggest that a shift toward quality can benefit the overall economy. Departing from these existing studies, we adopt a non-unitary model to attempt to explain the negative relation between the quantity and quality of children from the perspective of the sex ratio and intra-household bargaining over family planning. For excellent surveys, see Doepke (2015) and Fernihough (2017).

  2. See Testa (2006) and Westoff (2010).

  3. Women’s liberation can also alter the power balance within a marriage by affecting the outside options of the current marital relationship (Doepke and Tertilt 2009; Fernandez 2014).

  4. In developing countries, the marriage systems may be based on a polygamous marriage market, in which case there are adjustments to the prices of brides and grooms and to the quantity of each (Becker 2014; Grossbard 1980, 2014).

  5. Although the higher quantity and the lower quality of children generally lead to an economic slowdown, the manpower of the baby boomer generation is considered to have underpinned the rapid economic growth in Japan.

  6. The details of the trends in birth control during the pre-war period are described in Online Appendix A.1 of Ogasawara and Komura (2021).

  7. The annual data of Japanese TFR is stably and continuously available from 1947. The TFR was 4.54 in that year, the highest in the postwar period, 3.65 in 1950, 2.37 in 1955, and 2.00 in 1960.

  8. The sex ratio decreased sharply after 1937, when the wartime regime began to draft men into the army, and dropped to 0.95 in 1940, just before the start of the Pacific War, reaching less than 0.8 by the end of the war in 1945. The sex ratio recovered dramatically by 0.13, from 0.79 in 1945 to 0.92 in 1947. This considerable change within a relatively short time was undoubtedly caused by repatriated soldiers (Online Appendix B of Ogasawara and Komura (2021) for further details). Importantly, most of the repatriation had finished by 1947, after which the sex ratio barely increased.

  9. Today, apart from different historical and cultural backgrounds and meanings of out-of-wedlock children, the ratio of children born out of wedlock is quite low in Japan, at 2.3%, while the average ratio of OECD countries was 39.9% in 2014.

  10. Becker (1974) shows that the demand for wives is higher under polygyny than under monogamy, and that for a given supply of women, their market value and access to marital income will increase. Thus, he claims that laws against polygyny reduce the “demand” for women, and thus, reduce their share of total household output, while increasing that for men.

  11. This assumption corresponds to the interpretation in Nash bargaining that the reservation utility of marriage (i.e., the single state) is lower than the utility levels achieved by any bargaining outcomes under marriage.

  12. The assumption that only women take responsibility for childcare is justified if the time spent by mothers and fathers are perfect substitutes, and if the women’s wage rates are lower than their husbands.

  13. Chiappori et al. (2002) show other elements of legislation systems. Legislation systems can lead to a favorable position for one party, depending on whether they are utilitarian or egalitarian systems (Chiappori et al. 2002; Cigno 2012; Doepke and Tertilt 2009; Fernandez2014). If the latter is employed by the state, the party in the economically unfavorable position can secure a certain level of income, even after a divorce (breakdown of the marriage).

  14. The identification strategy used in this study is similar to that employed by Abramitzky et al. (2011). To study the impact of male scarcity on marital assortative matching and other marriage market outcomes, they utilized the geographical variation of the military mortality rate across départments during World War I in France.

  15. This means that our main variable could also capture the changes in the sex ratio due to air attacks on the Japanese archipelago during the war. Potential issues with our main variable relate to rumors about areas exposed to atomic bombs and physical disruptions due to the attacks. These might correlate with the changes in the sex ratio during the period just before and after the war. Although we do not report the full results, we have confirmed that our main results remain largely unchanged if we include the interaction term between the air attack death rate and the postwar dummy (Online Appendix B of Ogasawara and Komura (2021)).

  16. For the general fertility rate, we use the number of women ages 15–44 rather than the number of married women. This is because the proportion of illegitimate births to total births is relatively small in Japan, as bigamy is prohibited by law. In fact, the average proportion of illegitimate births (i.e., the proportion per 1000 live births) between 1948 and 1970 was only 1.5% (Cabinet Bureau of Statistics, various years).

  17. For further details on these Japanese physical examinations, see Ogasawara (2017) and Schneider and Ogasawara (2018). Here, we use the height at age 6 rather than at later ages to capture the instantaneous effects of changes in the marriage market on child height.

  18. As the precise number of females ages 15–44 is recorded in the census years (1925, 1930, 1935, 1950, 1955, 1960, 1965, 1970), we linearly interoperated the number of females ages 15–44 in the non-census years. This is because we are interested in the varying effects of the change in the sex ratio in the marriage market on the general fertility rate, as expressed in Eq. 2. However, we have confirmed that this interpolation does not matter; we obtain virtually the same baseline estimate (i.e., 220 per mille) using the census years (note that in column (1) of Table 2, the estimate is 214 per mille). In Online Appendix D.2 of Ogasawara and Komura (2021), we have confirmed that our main results are also similar to those obtained using the crude birth rate. However, we do not prefer using the crude birth rate as our main outcome variable because it is more likely to be influenced by the male casualties in the war. Similarly, we do not use the marital fertility rate (defined as the number of live births per 1000 married women) as our main outcome variable, because this is more likely to be influenced by the existence of women of non-childbearing age.

  19. From 1925 to 1970, excluding the wartime period (1937–1945) and the period immediately after the war (1945–1947). We confirm the stationarity in our panel dataset. For all outcome variables used in our analysis, several tests reject the null of unit-root non-stationarity (Online Appendix D.1 of Ogasawara and Komura (2021)). Note that we do not use the regression difference-in-differences models using the continuous shock variable. This is because although the approach requires the continuous measure of both sex ratio and outcome variables over time, both data are discontinuous at the wartime period, and thus, the dramatic changes in the sex ratio could not be captured continuously. Moreover, panel data on the continuous measure of the sex ratio are unavailable throughout the sampled period.

  20. This variable takes the value “one” for 1950–1970 and “zero” otherwise.

  21. We specify the model similar to Naidu and Yuchtman (2013), who use the interaction term between the cross-sectional treatment variation and the post-event dummy as a key variable of interest.

  22. We assign the value zero to negative values in the calculation of the counterfactual child mortality rate.

  23. Note that if we choose an alternative baseline year, the point estimates change in all models.

  24. Although we focus on the effect of the shock in the marriage market on demographic trends in monogamy systems, Neelakantan and Tertilt (2008) comprehensively consider the interdependence among the marriage market system, the spousal age gap of couples, and population growth, treating all of them as endogenous variables. According to their study, the narrowed spousal age gap is likely to coexist with the monogamy system.

References

  • Abramitzky R, Delavande A, Vasconcelos L (2011) Marrying up: The role of sex ratio in assortative matching. Amer Econ J Appl Econ 3(3):124–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Autor DH, Lyle D (2004) Women, war, and wages: The effect of female labor supply on the wage structure at midcentury. J Polit Econ 112(3):497–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amuedo-Dorantes C, Grossbard S (2007) Cohort-level sex ratio effects on women’s labor force participation. Rev Econ Househ 5(3):249–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist J (2002) How do sex ratios affect marriage and labor markets? Evidence from America’s second generation. Q J Econ 117(3):997–1038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps PF, Rees R (1988) Taxation and the household. J Public Econ 35:355–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Becker GS (1989) Fertility choice in a model of economic growth. Econometrica 57:481–501

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1973) A theory of marriage: Part I. J Polit Econ 81 (4):813–846

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1974) A theory of marriage: Part II. J Polit Econ 82 (2):511–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1981) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Barro RJ (1988) A reformulation of the economic theory of fertility. Q J Econ 103(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Lewis HG (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 81:S279–S288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM, Tamura R (1990) Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. J Polit Econ 98(5):S12–S37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom T (1994) On the economics of polygyny. Department of Economics, UCSB

    Google Scholar 

  • Bethmann D, Kvasnicka M (2013) World War II, missing men and out of wedlock childbearing. Econ J 123(567):162–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F, Browning M, Chiappori P (1993) Intra household allocation of consumption: A model and some evidence from French data. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique 29:137–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainerd E (2007) Uncounted costs of World War II: The effects of changing sex ratios on marriage and fertility of Russian women. National Council for Eurasian and East European Research

  • Bureau of Statistics Office of the Prime Minister (1959) Showasanjyunen Kokuseichosa hokoku, daisankan [1955 population census of Japan, vol.3] Tokyo

  • Chiappori PA (1988) Rational household labor supply. Econometrica 56:63–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA (1992) Collective labor supply and welfare. J Polit Econ 100:437–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Fortin B, Lacroix G (2002) Marriage market, divorce legislation, and household labor supply. J Polit Econ 110(1):37–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A (1998) Fertility decisions when infant survival is endogenous. J Popul Econ 11(1):21–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A (2012) Marriage as a commitment device. Rev Econ Househ 10(2):193–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clio-Infra (2018) https://www.clio-infra.eu/Indicators/IncomeInequality.html#datasets (Accessed 16 Jul 2018)

  • Department of Health Statistics Ministry of Welfare (2021) Jinkodotai tokei [The vital statistics, 1946 editions]. Tokyo, 1949a–1949a

  • Department of Statistics and Investigation Welfare Ministry’s Secretariat (1949) Jinkodotai tokei [The vital statistics, 1947 editions]. Tokyo, 1949a–1949a

  • Devision of Health and Welfare Statistics Health and Welfare Ministry’s Secretariat (1962-1963) Jinkodotai tokei [The vital statistics, 1960-1961 editions]. Tokyo, 1962a–1963a

  • Devision of Health and Welfare Statistics Welfare Ministry’s Secretariat (1950-1961) Jinkodotai tokei [The vital statistics, 1948-1959 editions]. Tokyo, 1950a–1961a

  • Doepke M (2015) Gary Becker on the quantity and quality of children. J Demograp Econ 81(1):59–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke M, Hazan M, Maoz YD (2015) The baby boom and World War II: A macroeconomic analysis. Rev Econ Stud 82(3):1031–1073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke M, Kindermann F (2014) Intrahousehold decision making and fertility. IZA DP No. 8726

  • Doepke M, Tertilt M (2009) Women’s liberation: What’s in it for men?. Q J Econ 124(4):1541–1591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duflo E (2003) Grandmothers and granddaughters: Old-age pensions and intrahousehold allocation in South Africa. World Bank Econ Rev 17 (1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eswaran M, Kotwal A (2004) A theory of gender differences in parental altruism. Canadian J Econ/Revue canadienne déconomique 37(4):918–950

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farré L., Vella F (2013) The intergenerational transmission of gender role attitudes and its implications for female labour force participation. Economica 80(318):219–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez R (2007) Women, work, and culture. J Eur Econ Assoc 5(2-3):305–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández R (2013) Cultural change as learning: The evolution of female labor force participation over a century. Am Econ Rev 103(1):472–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez R (2014) Women’s rights and development. J Econ Growth 19(1):37–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez R, Fogli A (2009) Culture: an empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility. Amer Econ J Macroecon 1(1):146–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernihough A (2017) Human capital and the quantity-quality trade-off during the demographic transition. J Econ Growth 22(1):35–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fogli A, Veldkamp L (2011) Nature or nurture? Learning and the geography of female labor force participation. Econometrica 79(4):1103–1138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2012) The demographic transition: Causes and consequences. Cliometrica 6(1):1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Q J Econ 117(4):1133–1191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90 (4):806–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gay V (2018) The legacy of the missing men: World war i and female labor in France over a century (Doctoral dissertation The University of Chicago)

  • Goldin CD (1991) The role of World War II in the rise of women’s employment. Am Econ Rev 81(4):741–756

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin C, Olivetti C (2013) Shocking labor supply: A reassessment of the role of World War II on women’s labor supply. Am Econ Rev 103(3):257–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard A (1980) The economics of polygamy. Res Popul Econ 2:321–350

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard S (2014) Sex ratios, polygyny, and the value of women in marriage: A Beckerian approach. J Demograph Econ 81(01):13–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi F, Prescott EC (2008) The depressing effect of agricultural institutions on the prewar Japanese economy. J Polit Econ 116(4):573–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyigun M, Walsh R (2007) Endogenous gender power, household labor supply and the demographic transition. J Develop Econ 82(1):138–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Japanese Ministry of Health Labour and Welfare (2006) Kousei roudou hakusho chiiki to tomoni sasaeru korekarano shakai hosho [White paper in Japanese Ministry of Health Labor and Welfare future social security to support with community] Tokyo

  • Johnston DW, Schurer S, Shields MA (2013) Maternal gender role attitudes, human capital investment, and labour supply of sons and daughters. Oxf Econ Pap 66(3):631–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kawaguchi E (2003) Sensou Miboujin (War widows:Between the victem and the fault), Tokyo: Domesu Shuppan

  • Kawaguchi D, Miyazaki J (2009) Working mothers and sons’ preferences regarding female labor supply: Direct evidence from stated preferences. J Popul Econ 22(1):115–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitagawa K (2000) Sengo no Shuppatsu: Bunkaundou, Seinendan, Sensou Miboujin (The post-war departure: Cultural movement, young organization, and war widows) Tokyo: Aoki Shoten

  • Klemp M, Weisdorf J (2018) Fecundity, fertility and the formation of human capital. Econ J 129(618):925–960

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Komura M (2013) Fertility and endogenous gender bargaining power. J Popul Econ 26(3):943–961

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurushima N, Nagano H, Osa S (2015) Jenda karamita nihonshi (A gendered history of Japan), Tokyo: Ōtsukishoten

  • Lundberg SJ, Pollak RA, Wales TJ (1997) Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from the United Kingdom child benefit. J Hum Resour 32(3):463–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maitra P (2004) Parental bargaining, health inputs and child mortality in India. J Health Econ 23(2):259–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naidu S, Yuchtman N (2013) Coercive contract enforcement: Law and the labor market in nineteenth century industrial Britain. Am Econ Rev 103(1):107–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neal D (2004) The relationship between marriage market prospects and never-married motherhood. J Hum Resour 39(4):938–957

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neelakantan U, Tertilt M (2008) A note on marriage market clearing. Econ Lett 101(2):103–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogasawara K (2017) Persistence of pandemic influenza on the development of children: Evidence from industrializing Japan. Soc Sci Med 181:43–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogasawara K, Komura M (2021) Consequences of War: Japan’s Demographic Transition and the Marriage Market. GLO Discussion Paper Series 750, Global Labor Organization (GLO)

  • Ogino M (2008) Kazokukeikaku heno michi (The Road to ‘Family Planning’), Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten

  • Phipps SA, Burton PS (1998) What’s mine is yours? The influence of male and female incomes on patterns of household expenditure. Economica 65:599–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport B, Sofer C, Solaz A (2011) Household production in a collective model: Some new results. J Popul Econ 24(1):23–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasul I (2008) Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence from Malaysia. J Dev Econ 86(2):215–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees R, Riezman R (2012) Globalization, gender, and growth. Rev Income Wealth 58:107–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider EB, Ogasawara K (2018) Disease and child growth in industrialising japan: Critical windows and the growth pattern, 1917-39. Explor Econ Hist 69:64–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TP (1990) Testing the neoclassical model of family labor supply and fertility. J Hum Resour 25:599–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiue CH (2017) Human capital and fertility in Chinese clans before modern growth. J Econ Growth 22(4):351–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet (1929) Taishokyunen Kokuseichosa hokoku, dainikan [1920 population census of Japan, vol.2] Tokyo

  • Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet (1924-1932) Nihonteikoku jinkodotai tokei [The vital statistics of the empire of Japan, 1922-1931 editions]. Tokyo, 1924a–1932a

  • Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet (1932-1943) Nihon jinkodotai tokei [The vital statistics of Japan, 1932-1943 editions]. Tokyo, 1934a–1945a

  • Statistics and Information Department Minister’s Secretariat Ministry of Health and Welfare (1999) Jinkodotaitokei hyakunen no doko [Trends in vital statistics of Japan for 100 years]. Health, Labour, and Welfare Statistics Association Tokyo

  • Strauss J, Thomas D (1998) Health, nutrition, and economic development. J Econ Lit 36(2):766–817

    Google Scholar 

  • Testa M (2006) Childbearing preferences and family issues in Europe. Special Eurobarometer 253:65. European Commission, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas D (1990) Intra-household resource allocation: An inferential approach. J Hum Resour 25:635–664

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas D (1994) Like father, like son; like mother, like daughter: Parental resources and child height. J Hum Resour 29:950–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe T (2014a) Who became the solders? Part 1: Inequality in pre-war Showa period military service cohorts. Kanseigakuindaigaku Shakaibakubu Kiyo 119:1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe T (2014b) Who became the solders? Part 2: Inequalities in educational background and occupation in pre-war Showa period military service. Kanseigakuindaigaku Shakaibakubu Kiyo 119:19–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Westoff CF (2010) Desired number of children: 2000-2008. DHS Comparative Reports 25, Calverton: ICF Macro

  • Willis RJ (1999) A theory of out-of-wedlock childbearing. J Polit Econ 107(S6):S33–S64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yugami K (2003) Nihon no Shotoku Kakusa wo Doumiruka: Kakusa Kakudai no Youin wo Saguru (How can we see the income gap issue in Japan?: Questioning the factors of the widen income gap) JIL Labor Policy Report 3

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor, Oded Galor, Madeline Zavodny, and two referees of this journal for their detailed and constructive comments. We are also grateful to Dirk Bethmann, Sonia Bhalotra, Alessandro Cigno, Neil Cummins, Taiyo Fukai, Daiji Kawaguchi, Yukitoshi Matsushita, Kentro Nakajima, Ryoji Ohdoi, Hikaru Ogawa, Kenta Tanaka, Kensuke Teshima, Masaru Sasaki, Masayuki Yagasaki, Shintaro Yamaguchi, and all the participants of the Kansai Seminar for Studies on Labor, Tokyo Labor Economics Workshop, Society of Economics of the Household, Western Economic Association International, Japanese-American-German Frontiers of Science Symposium 2017, 7th Kyoto Summer Workshop, Asian and Australasian Society of Labour Economics, and seminars held at Nagoya University, Kyoto University, Daitobunka University, and Chukyo University. All errors are our own.

Funding

This study is supported by JSPS KAKENHI (Grant Numbers 15K17074, 16K17153, and 18K01661). Support from the Tokyo Institute of Technology for Ogasawara’s visit to the London School of Economics also helped this study. Komura is received support from the project “Building of Consortia for the Development of Human Resources in Science and Technology.” She also received support from Murata Overseas Scholarship Foundation for her visit to the University of Florence. All errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mizuki Komura.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Oded Galor

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ogasawara, K., Komura, M. Consequences of war: Japan’s demographic transition and the marriage market. J Popul Econ 35, 1037–1069 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-021-00826-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-021-00826-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation