Skip to main content
Log in

Human capital and fertility in Chinese clans before modern growth

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the effect of changes in the return to human capital on the fertility–education relationship. The setting is in Anhui Province, China in the thirteenth to twentieth centuries. Over this period, key changes occurred in the civil service examination system, providing a means to test whether incentives for acquiring education influenced fertility decisions. I form an intergenerationally linked dataset from over 43,000 individuals from all social strata to examine the evidence for a child quantity–quality tradeoff. First, as the civil service examination system became more predictable and less discretionary starting in the seventeenth century, raising the return to human capital, I find evidence that households with a lower number of children had a higher chance that one of their sons would participate in the state examinations. This finding is robust to accounting for differences in resources, health, parental human capital, and demographic characteristics. Importantly, the finding is not limited to a small subset of rich households but present in the sample as a whole. Second, the negative relationship between fertility and education disappeared as the lower chance to become an official during the nineteenth century implied a decline in the return to human capital. Taken together, my findings support the hypothesis that fertility choices respond to changes in the return to human capital.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. World Bank (2014).

  2. Starting with the work of Becker (1960, 1981) economists have pursued the idea that fertility is based on rational choice. On its broader importance for economic development, see Galor (2011).

  3. As summarized in Esherick and Rankin (1990): “There is a strong tendency for this literature to view state-elite competition as a zero-sum game. The autocratic state seeks full fiscal and coercive power over rural society, while local elites—sometimes representing community interests, sometimes pursuing their own gain—seek to check the state’s intrusion...most of this literature sees order as the product of state control. When elites organize it is a symptom of crisis, conflict, or the disintegration of established order.” See also Hsiao (1960) and Wakeman (1975). Fear of regional clans and military leaders was also the motivation of Sung emperors, who promulgated the civil service examinations in 960; on this point, see Elman (1991).

  4. Although this suggests a greater degree of cooperation and integration between the center and local actors, Beattie’s (1979) study of Tongcheng county shows that families also used income from land holdings, coupled with civil service, in order to maintain status. In other regions, merchants entered elite status and civil service through activities in trade or patronage of the literati lifestyle. See also Naquin and Rawski (1987) for other detailed accounts of local society.

  5. The previous literature on Chinese historical demographics is too large to cite completely. A partial list might include Coale (1985), Lavely and Wong (1998), Lavely (2007) and Wolf (2001). Also see discussions in Zhao (2002) and Lee and Wang (2001).

  6. For example, after Newcomen and Watt pioneered the steam engine in eighteenth century Britain, by the 1830s the first railway lines were being constructed in Germany as well as the United States. Between 1825–1850, markets in Europe were much more integrated than they were just 50 years earlier, suggesting that the roots of modernization had taken hold (Shiue and Keller 2007). Printing and the Enlightenment also played a role in the timing of growth in Europe (Mokyr 2012).

  7. Also see Lehr (2009) on the interaction of productivity and demand for human capital.

  8. Fernihough (2011) shows that school enrollment declines with sibship size in early twentieth century Ireland; Klemp and Weisdorf (2012) document that marital fecundity, instrumented by time-until-first-child, is associated with lower literacy of the offspring in reconstitution data for eighteenth and nineteenth century England; Basso (2012) examines the effect of child education on parents’ fertility across early twentieth century Spanish provinces; Murphy (2015) shows that family size is negatively correlated with measures of education across late-nineteenth century French regions; and Diebolt et al. (2015) explore the role of gender in the negative fertility–education relationship in mid-nineteenth century France. Finally, Jun and Lee (2014) examine the relationship between fertility and human capital in South Korea between 1970 and 2010.

  9. For further discussions on social mobility in China during the late imperial era, see Greenhalgh (1988) and Shiue (2017). The use of a civil service examination for government service was also used in Western countries, but only much later. England adopted a government service examination in 1870, and the US in 1883 (Miyazaki 1976, 124).

  10. The first Ming national exam was given in 1371, wherein 119 degrees were given. The second exam was given only 14 years later, with 485 degrees awarded (Elman 2000, p. 68; Ho 1962, p. 186).

  11. It is estimated that the actual number of these degrees increased by 20-fold nationally from the late 1500s–1600 (Ho 1962, p. 182).

  12. By about 1650, the only types of hereditary privileges and automatic status that remained belonged to the imperial lineage where the throne was passed from the emperor to one of his sons and the families of the Eight-Banner system. Whereas provinces had regional provincial quotas, the Banner families had a generous “Banner” quota. The latter was an exclusive hereditary institution that dominated military and command functions, and men born into Banner families held a caste-like elite position. Elliot (2001) estimates the total Banner population in the early eighteenth century was 3% of the population of China, mostly in Beijing and Manchuria.

  13. Upwards of 4000 persons appeared for provincial exams at the capital (Twitchett and Mote 1998, p. 36).

  14. For example, in the first metropolitan exam of the Qing dynasty in 1646, the regent asked how the government could bring Manchu and Han officials and people together for a common purpose. This was an important question for the Qing Manchu government that sought to rule over a Han Chinese population. See Twitchett and Mote (1998), Chap. 7, p. 361.

  15. In 1661, maximal quotas for the numbers of eligible candidates per year were 20 for a large prefectural city, 15 for a large and “cultured” county, and 4–5 for a small and “backward” county. Daqinghuidian shili (1899 edition) Chap. 370.

  16. “In all likelihood the fluctuations in the total cumulative number of sheng-yuan in an average lifetime during the first centuries of the Qing period were not very great...All in all, the Qing state succeeded in the main in keeping a stable sheng-yuan quota system.” (Ho 1962, p. 197).

  17. I analyze degree purchase as an alternative strategy below.

  18. Although the imperial government issued decrees that schools be set up in prefectures and counties, in practice, teachers and schools were largely funded through private initiatives organized at the local level. For instance in the year 1078, it was decreed that provinces and prefectures should appoint full-time school teachers, but only 53 counties out of 1000 counties did so (Ho 1962, p. 170). At the start of the Ming (1368–1644) another decree to establish schools was issued, with more compliance (ibid, p. 179).

  19. For basic literacy, parents of even moderate means could pool together tuition fees to hire a local schoolmaster to teach village youngsters basic literacy in return for room and board, meals, and a small allowance (Ebrey 1993, p. 72); other types of support might be had from the lineage (common descent group, or clan). It is estimated that around 30–45% of males and 2% of females were literate in the late Qing (Rawski 1979, p. 23). Over 3 or 4 years, children could learn approximately 1000 characters, which would have been sufficient for reading everyday text and writing business contracts (Leung 1994, p. 393; Ebrey 1993, p. 348).

  20. Specialized schools, and officially subsidized schools, such as the schools specializing in military education or medicine, or national schools that were open to students preparing for state exams, could also be found. Private institutions also flourished—academies such as those established by salt merchants of Guangzhou, for example, were probably among the best schools in the empire (Elman 2002, pp. 403–406).

  21. All three levels of degree holders are included in my empirical analysis.

  22. In comparison, a manual laborer made about 50 taels per year (see Keller et al. 2017).

  23. For example, the official salary of a first-ranked official such as a Grand Secretary was only 180 taels per year (Chang 1962, Tables 1, 16).

  24. The introduction of the printing press might have affected the costs of human capital acquisition (Becker and Woessmann 2009), in addition to diffusing knowledge relevant to merchants (Dittmar 2011). In China, the introduction of movable type printing facilities in the early sixteenth century had arguably limited effects. Ho notes that printed books were still too expensive relative to the means of the large majority of the population, to the point that the introduction of printing in fact increased the hold of high-status families on passing the higher state examinations (Ho 1962, pp. 214–215).

  25. A range of estimates is shown in Ho (1959, pp. 263–264); Perkins (1969, Table 4a), Durand (1977), McEvedy and Jones (1978), and Cao (2000).

  26. One might think that the return to office might rise with the increase to population size, although as discussed above there is little evidence for this. For evidence that competition was intensifying over the Qing across all regions of China, see Chang (1955), Ho (1962), and Elman (2000, Table 3.4, p. 662).

  27. Based on data in Ho (1962, p. 201); my analysis includes both academies set up officially and privately. I take 9.8 million to be Guangdong’s average population for the 1662–1795 period, and 28.2 million for the 1796–1908 period, using Ho’s population estimates (Ho 1962, p. 223).

  28. \(\updelta \) could also be stochastic due to idiosyncratic factors across individuals or over time.

  29. Genealogies are family histories; their main purpose was to keep a record of the rituals and the achievements of the family; see Liu (1978, 1980) and Telford (1986) as well as the discussion below.

  30. The Tongcheng genealogies are not unique in the length of the period covered; Fei and Liu (1982), for example, examine lineages over the period of 1400–1900.

  31. See Shiue (2016) for additional information.

  32. Life table and related demographic approaches were originally developed under the auspices of the United Nations. For applications to lineage populations, see Liu (1980), Harrell (1985) and Telford (1990) extends their approach in a number of ways.

  33. Co-residence beyond the nuclear household was common practice during the Ming–Qing era. Tax census data for the late eighteenth century suggests the average size of the household was between 5 and 8 persons, where typically grandparents shared a household with their sons and grandchildren (Wang 1974).

  34. In Sect. 5.2.1 below I examine different levels of human capital separately. The classification of education levels is based on Chang (1962), Ho (1962), and Telford (1995).

  35. In particular, degree purchases are examined in Sect. 5.2.1 below.

  36. That is, this data may not be well suited for analyzing child mortality. Furthermore, each of these men is linked to his father and grandfather to examine the intergenerational transmission of human capital.

  37. I observe about 3600 men who were alive in the year 1790 in my sample. These men had more than 4200 wives, and the data records more than 7500 sons and 4100 daughters, for a total of just under 20,000 persons. Gazetteers were local histories about a certain place. Three county-level gazetteers about Tongcheng cover the period under analysis: Tongcheng xian zhi (1490), Tongcheng xian zhi (1696), Tongcheng xuxiu xian zhi (1827).

  38. I define the variable Brothers as the number of brothers from the same father, but results are similar when I include half-brothers and adopted brothers in the analysis.

  39. Fertility figures should be viewed as lifetime (completed) fertility data.

  40. Studies of fertility in China at times apply a scaling factor to account for any under-recorded births (male and especially female). This would not affect the fertility–education relationship I focus on.

  41. There are 8291 married men during the Qing in the sample. To convert this into a population figure, I assume that 20% of all men did not marry, and that the Qing population was composed of below-age-of-marriage men/women to one-third each. This gives a scaling factor of 3.75: 14 jin-shi/\((8291 \times 3.75) = 0.045\%\).

  42. Note that since optimal child quantity and quality are simultaneously determined, \(\beta _1\) gives the conditional correlation implied by the model, not the causal effect of child quantity on child quality.

  43. Extending this analysis below I allow for more general patterns over time as well as trends that vary across lineages (Table 11), without changing the main results.

  44. The figures differ slightly because I bootstrap standard errors in Table 11 for robustness, while standard errors in Table 5 are analytical.

  45. In unreported analysis I have also examined the role of lineage differences for these results by dropping one lineage at a time, finding that the results are robust.

  46. I take as Late Qing observations all men with birth year of 1800 or later; this includes a few that were born after the fall of the Qing in 1911. These cases do not drive the result.

References

  • Basso, A. (2012). Fertility transition and the quantity–quality trade-off: Historical evidence from Spain. Mimeo.

  • Beattie, H. (1979). Land and lineage in China: A study of T’ung-ch’eng County, Anhwei, in the Ming and Ch’ing dynasties. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1960). An economic analysis of fertility. In A. J. Coale (Ed.), Demographic and economic change in developed countries. Princeton University Press: Princeton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1981). A treatise on the family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., Cinnirella, F., & Woessmann, L. (2010). The trade-off between fertility and education: Evidence from before the demographic transition. Journal of Economic Growth, 15(3), 177–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., Cinnirella, F., & Woessmann, L. (2012). The effect of investment in children’s education on fertility in 1816 Prussia. Cliometrica, 6(1), 29–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was weber wrong? A human capital theory of protestant economic history. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(2), 531–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, S. E., Devereaux, P. J., & Salvanes, K. G. (2005). The more the merrier? The effect of family size and birth order on children’s education. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 669–700.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bleakley, H., & Lange, F. (2009). Chronic disease burden and the interaction of education, fertility, and growth. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(1), 52–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, S. (2000). Zhongguo Renko Shi Mingqing Shiqi (China’s Population History in the Ming-Qing Period). Shanghai: Fudan University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, C. (1955). The Chinese gentry: Studies on their role in nineteenth century chinese society. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, C. (1962). The income of the Chinese gentry. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coale, A. J. (1985). Fertility in rural China: A reconfirmation of the barclay reassessment. In S. Hanley & A. P. Wolf (Eds.), Family and population in east Asian history. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cong, X. (2007). Teachers’ schools and the making of the modern Chinese nation-state, 1897–1937. Vancouver: UBC Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts, N. (1995). Exogenous or endogenous growth? The industrial revolution reconsidered. Journal of Economic History, 55(4), 745–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeLong, J. B., Goldin, C., & Katz, L. F. (2003). Sustaining US economic growth. In H. Aaron, J. M. Lindsay, & P. S. Niyola (Eds.), Agenda for the nation, 17–60 (p. 2003). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt, C., Mishra, T., & Perrin, F. (2015). Did gender-bias matter in the quantity–quality trade-off in 19th century france? Lund papers in economic history no. 141.

  • Dittmar, J. (2011). Information technology and technological change: The impact of the printing press. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(3), 1133–1172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M. (2004). Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 347–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durand, J. D. (1977). Historical estimates of world population: An evaluation. Population and Development Review, 3(3), 253–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A., & Crimmins, E. M. (1985). The fertility revolution: A supply–demand analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebrey, P. B. (1993). Chinese civilization: A sourcebook (2nd ed.). Mumbai: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliot, M. (2001). The manchu way: The eight banners and ethnic identity in late imperial China. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elman, B. (1991). Political, social, and cultural reproduction via civil service examinations in late imperial China. Journal of Asian Studies, 50(1), 7–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elman, B. (1994). Changes in civil service examinations from the ming to the Ch’ing Dynasties. In B. Elman & A. Woodside (Eds.), Education and society in late imperial China (pp. 1600–1900). Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elman, B. (2000). A cultural history of civil examinations in late imperial China. Los Angeles: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elman, B. (2002). The social roles of literati in early to Mid-Ch’ing. In Willard J. Peterson (Ed.), Part one: The Ch’ing Empire to 1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esherick, J. W., & Rankin, M. B. (Eds.). (1990). Chinese local elites and patterns of dominance. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fei, J. C. H., & Liu, T. (1982). The growth and decline of China family clans. Journal of Interdisciplinary History, XII:3((Winter)), 375–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernihough, A. (2011). Human capital and the quantity–quality trade-off during the demographic transition: New evidence from Ireland. Working papers 201113, School of Economics, University College Dublin.

  • Galor, O. (2011). Unified growth theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 469–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Mountford, A. (2008). Trading population for productivity: Theory and evidence. Review of Economic Studies, 75(4), 1143–1179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. (2000). Population, technology and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review, 90, 806–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenhalgh, S. (1988). Fertility as mobility: Sinic transitions. Population and Development Review, 14(4), 629–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guinnane, T. (2011). The historical fertility transition: A guide for economists. Journal of Economic Literature, 49(3), 589–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrell, S. (1985). The rich get children: Segmentation, stratification, and population in three chekiang lineages. In S. Hanley & A. P. Wolf (Eds.), Family and population in east Asian history (pp. 1550–1850). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrell, S. (1987). On the holes in Chinese genealogies. Late Imperial China, 8(2), 53–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, P. (1959). Studies on the population of China, 1368–1953. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, P. (1962). The ladder of success in imperial China: Aspects of social mobility (1368–1911). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao, K. (1960). Rural China: Imperial control in the nineteenth century. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jun, B., & Lee, J. (2014). The tradeoff between fertility and education: Evidence from the Korean development path. No. 92-2014, FZID discussion papers, University of Hohenheim.

  • Keller, W., Santiago, J. A., & Shiue, C. H. (2017). China’s domestic trade during the Treaty Port Era. Explorations in Economic History, 63, 26–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemp, M., & Weisdorf, J. (2012). Fecundity, fertility and family reconstitution data: The child quantity–quality trade-off revisited. Working paper.

  • Lavely, W. (2007). Sex, breastfeeding, and marital fertility in pre-transition China. Population and Development Review, 33(2), 289–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavely, W., & Wong, R. B. (1998). Revising the Malthusian narrative: The comparative study of population dynamics in late imperial China. The Journal of Asian Studies, 57(3), 714–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R. (2003). The demographic transition: Three centuries of fundamental change. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(4), 167–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., & Wang, F. (2001). One quarter of humanity, Malthusian mythology and Chinese realities, 1700–2000. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehr, C. S. (2009). Evidence on the demographic transition. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(4), 871–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung, A. K. C. (1994). Elementary education in the lower yangtze region in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. In A. Woodside & B. A. Elman (Eds.), Education and society in late imperial China. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, T. (1978). Chinese genealogies as a source for the study of historical demography. In Studies and essays in commemoration of the golden jubilee of Academia Sinica. Taipei: Academia Sinica.

  • Liu, T. (1980). The demographic dynamics of some clans in the lower Yangtze area, c. 1400–1900. In paper presented at the international conference on sinology. Taipei.

  • Livi Bacci, M. (1986). Social-group forerunners of fertility control in Europe. In A. J. Coale & S. C. Watkins (Eds.), The decline of fertility in Europe (pp. 182–200). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McEvedy, C., & Jones, R. (1978). Atlas of world population history. Harmondsworth, Middlesex: Penguin Books Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, I. (1976). China’s examination hell: The civil service examinations of imperial China, trans. Conrad Schirokauer. New York: Weatherhill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moav, O. (2005). Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Economic Journal, 115, 88–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2012). The enlightened economy: An economic history of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, T. E. (2015). Old habits die hard (sometimes). Journal of Economic Growth, 20(2), 177–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naquin, S., & Rawski, E. S. (1987). Chinese society in the eighteenth century. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perkins, D. H. (1969). Agricultural development in China, 1368–1968. Chicago, IL: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pomeranz, K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawski, E. S. (1979). Education and popular literacy in Ch’ing China. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiue, C. H. (2002). Transport costs and the geography of arbitrage in eighteenth century China. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1406–1419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiue, C. H. (2016). A culture of kinship: Chinese genealogies as a source for research in demographic economics. Journal of Demographic Economics, 82(4), 459–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiue, C. H. (2017). Social mobility in the long-run: An analysis with five linked generations, 1300–1900. Mimeo.

  • Shiue, C. H., & Keller, W. (2007). Markets in China and Europe on the eve of the industrial revolution. American Economic Review, 97(4), 1189–1216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shryock, H. S., & Siegel, J. S. (1973). The methods and materials of demography. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Telford, T. A. (1986). A survey of social demographic data in Chinese genealogies. Late Imperial China, 7, 118–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Telford, T. A. (1990). Patching the holes in Chinese genealogies. Late Imperial China, 11(2), 116–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Telford, T. A. (1995). Fertility and population growth in the lineages of tongcheng county. In S. Harrell (Ed.), Chinese historical microdemography (pp. 1520–1661). Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teng, S. (1967). Zhongguo kaoshi zhidu shi [A history of the Chinese examination institution]. Taibei: Taiwan xuesheng shuju.

    Google Scholar 

  • Twitchett, D., & Mote, F. W. (Eds.). (1998). The Cambridge history of China, (Vol. 8). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogl, T. S. (2016). Differential fertility, human capital, and development. Review of Economic Studies, 83, 463–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakeman, F. E. (1975). The fall of imperial China. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Y. (1974). Land taxation in Imperial China, 1750–1911. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolf, A. P. (2001). Is there evidence of birth control in late imperial China? Population and Development Review, 27, 133–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2007). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2014). Annual report overview. http://www.worldbank.org/en/about/annual-report/overview#HumanDevelopment.

  • Yuchtman, N. (2017). Teaching to the tests: An economic analysis of traditional and modern education in late imperial and republican China. Explorations in Economic History, 63(C), 70–90.

  • Zhao, Z. (1994). Demographic conditions and multi-generation households in Chinese history. Results from genealogical research and microsimulation. Population Studies, 48, 413–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, Z. (2002). Fertility control in China’s past. Population and Development Review, 28(4), 751–757.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Primary Sources Cited

  • Daqinghuidian shili (1899 edition) Ch. 370.

  • Tongcheng xian zhi (1490). Tongcheng local gazetteer of 1490.

  • Tongcheng xian zhi (1696). Tongcheng local gazetteer of 1696.

  • Tongcheng xuxiu xian zhi (1827). Tongcheng local gazetteer of 1827.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carol H. Shiue.

Additional information

Thanks to the editor, four referees, Sascha Becker, Steve Broadberry, Raquel Fernandez, Avner Greif, Bishnupriya Gupta, Murat Iyigun, Wolfgang Keller, Omer Moav, Tom Rawski, Ted Telford, Michèle Tertilt, and Nathan Sussman, as well as audiences at University of California-Davis, Fudan University, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Mannheim, University of Montreal, McGill, Northwestern, Oxford, Warwick, the Asian Historical Economics Conference, the NBER Development of the American Economy, the NBER Economic Fluctuations and Growth, and the Stanford SITE Conference for useful comments. T. Telford provided data used in this paper. Generous support from the Russell Sage Foundation and the National Institute of Child Health and Human Development (R03 HD042731-01) is gratefully acknowledged. The paper was partly written while the author was National Fellow at the Hoover Institution, whose hospitality is gratefully acknowledged.

Electronic supplementary material

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 910111213 and 14 and Fig. 4.

Table 9 Summary statistics by lineage
Table 10 Quantity–quality relationship in early Qing 1644–1800—Probit results
Table 11 Quantity–quality relationship in early Qing—robustness
Table 12 Fertility and human capital versus other investments
Table 13 Quantity–quality relationship in early versus late Qing—Probit results
Table 14 Quantity–quality relationship in late Qing—robustness
Fig. 4
figure 4

Quantity–quality relationship in early versus late Qing: nearest-neighbor matching for alternative time breakpoints

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Shiue, C.H. Human capital and fertility in Chinese clans before modern growth. J Econ Growth 22, 351–396 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-017-9148-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-017-9148-9

Keywords

Navigation