Advertisement

Journal of Population Economics

, Volume 22, Issue 1, pp 131–144 | Cite as

Welfare effects of illegal immigration

  • Theodore Palivos
Original Paper

Abstract

This paper analyzes the welfare effect of illegal immigration on the host country within a dynamic general equilibrium framework and shows that it is positive for two reasons. First, immigrants are paid less than their marginal product, and second, after an increase in immigration, domestic households find it optimal to increase their holdings of capital. It is also shown that dynamic inefficiency may arise, despite the fact that the model is of the Ramsey type. Nevertheless, the introduction of a minimum wage, which leads to job competition between domestic unskilled workers and immigrants reverses all of the above results.

Keywords

Economic growth Illegal immigration 

JEL Classification

F2 O4 

Notes

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Hung-Ju Chen, Bharat Hazari, Chong Yip, seminar participants at the Chinese University of Hong Kong, the Kyung Hee University and the University of Cyprus, and especially two anonymous referees for valuable comments and suggestions on an earlier version of the paper. I would also like to thank the Research Committee of the University of Macedonia for financial support.

References

  1. Amuedo-Dorantes C, Pozo S (2006) Remittances as insurance: evidence from Mexican immigrants. J Popul Econ 19(2):227–254CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Amuedo-Dorantes C, Bansak C, Pozo S (2005) On the remitting patterns of immigrants: evidence from mexican survey data. Econ Rev Fed Reserve Atlanta 90(1):37–58Google Scholar
  3. Chen HJ (2006) International migration and economic growth: a source country perspective. J Popul Econ 19(4):725–748CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Epstein GS, Heizler (Cohen) O (2007) Illegal immigration, enforcement and minimum wage. IZA Discussion Paper, No. 2830Google Scholar
  5. Ethier WJ (1986) Illegal immigration. Am Econ Rev 76(2):258–262Google Scholar
  6. Hazari BR, Sgro PM (2003) The simple analytics of optimal growth with illegal migrants. J Econ Dyn Control 28(1):141–151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Kemnitz A, Wigger BU (2000) Growth and social security: the role of human capital. Eur J Polit Econ 16(4):673–683CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Markova E, Reilly B (2007) Bulgarian migrant remittances and legal status: some micro-level evidence from madrid. S-East Eur J Econom 5(1):55–69Google Scholar
  9. Martin P, Miller M (2000) Employer sanctions: French, German and US experiences. International Migration Papers, No. 36Google Scholar
  10. Meier V, Wenig A (1997) Welfare implications of international labor migration. Z Wirtsch-Sozialwiss 117(4):505–524Google Scholar
  11. Moy HM, Yip CK (2006) The simple analytics of optimal growth with illegal migrants: a clarification. J Econ Dyn Control 30(12):2469–2475CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Ortega J (2000) Pareto-improving immigration in an economy with equilibrium unemployment. Econ J 110(460):92–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Rivera-Batiz FL (1999) Undocumented workers in the labor market: an analysis of the earnings of legal and illegal Mexican immigrants in the United States. J Popul Econ 12(1):91–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. United Nations (2004) World economic and social survey 2004. United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, E/2004/75/Rev.1/Add.1.Google Scholar
  15. US Accountability Office (2005) Immigration enforcement: preliminary observations on employment verification and worksite enforcement efforts, JuneGoogle Scholar
  16. Woodland AD, Yoshida C (2006) Risk preferences, immigration policy and illegal immigration. J Dev Econ 81(2):500–513CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of MacedoniaSalonicaGreece

Personalised recommendations