Skip to main content
Log in

Estimating dynamic discrete choice models with aggregate data: Properties of the inclusive value approximation

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate the use of the inclusive value based approach for estimating dynamic discrete choice models of demand with aggregate data. The inclusive value sufficiency (IVS) approach approximates a multi-dimensional state space with a single “sufficient statistic” in order to mitigate the curse of dimensionality and tractability estimate model primitives. Although in widespread use, the conditions under which IVS is appropriate have not been examined. Theoretically, we show that the estimator is biased and inconsistent. We then use Monte Carlo simulations (of a simple model of dynamic durable goods adoption) to demonstrate the degree of bias associated with the inclusive value approximation estimator under an array of parameterizations and data generating processes. In our examination, we show that the estimator performs better when the discount factor is smaller and/or when the price sensitivity of the consumer is larger. Examining how the bias impacts economic quantities of interest, we find that the IVS method under estimates the true long-run own-price elasticities and over estimates the change in profits as prices change. Theses findings highlight the importance of correctly specifying how consumers form expectations. As a result, researchers should consider how to empirically support their assumption for the underlying consumer belief structure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The below assumes a constant flow of utility after the purchase of a product, but this can be generalized to the case were flow utilities are time-varying (e.g. in the presence of complementary products).

  2. This assumption is only for the sake of proving biasedness. However, note that if we were interested in proving unbiasedness, this argument would be problematic. We thank an anonymous reviewer for this point.

  3. Andrews and Armstrong (2017) illustrate that an IV estimator under certain conditions is an unbiased estimate of αp. Thus,\(\mathrm {E}[\hat {\alpha }^{p}]=\alpha ^{p}\).

  4. In our Monte Carlos simulations below we find that \(Cov\left (\text {Z},\boldsymbol {\eta (\delta _{t})}\right ){<}0\) leading to a negative bias associated with \(\hat {\alpha }_{IVS}^{p}\) given Cov(Z, p) > 0. Additionally, note in small samples \(\text {E}\left [\frac {Cov\left (\text {Z},\boldsymbol {\eta (\delta _{t})}\right )}{Cov(Z,p)}\right ]\neq \frac {\mathrm {E}[Cov\left (\text {Z},\boldsymbol {\eta (\delta _{t})}\right )]}{\mathrm {E}[Cov(Z,p)]}\). Thus, if the \(\mathrm {E}[Cov\left (\text {Z},\boldsymbol {\eta (\delta _{t})}\right )]=0\), the bias would still remain.

  5. In this case, we use the number of observations N = |JT.

  6. We thank the co-Editor for pushing us to clearly state under what conditions and assumptions these theoretical results hold.

  7. In implementing the price change, we use changes from a generated price and marginal cost trajectory, and retain the same error terms under the changed prices.

  8. We do generate data associated with J = 8 but we do not report these results given the computational time that is required to form elasticity estimates given the DGP. With 8 products we must determine new equilibrium beliefs for each measure of own-price elasticity for each NS simulation run. We have estimated the model using this data for both estimators and have found that the IVS parameter estimates exhibit more bias than the setting of J = 5 and in some cases J = 2. Thus, it appears the improvement of the IVS estimator is nonlinear and is eliminated when J is large (J = 8).

  9. In Appendix A, we present the results of our analysis of a short-term temporary price increase.

References

  • Aguirregabiria, V., & Mira, P. (2010). Dynamic discrete choice structural models: a survey. Journal of Econometrics, 156(1), 38–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, I., & Armstrong, T.B. (2017). Unbiased instrumental variables estimation under known first-stage sign. Quantitative Economics, 8(2), 479–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayer, P., McMillan, R., Murphy, A., Timmins, C. (2016). A dynamic model of demand for houses and neighborhoods. Econometrica, 84(3), 893–942.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp. 841–890.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carranza, J.E. (2010). Product innovation and adoption in market equilibrium: the case of digital cameras. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28(6), 604–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chou, C., Derdenger, T., Kumar, V. (2019). Linear estimation of aggregate dynamic discrete demand for durable goods: Overcoming the curse of dimensionality. Marketing Science.

  • Derdenger, T., & Kumar, V. (2013). The dynamic effects of bundling as a product strategy. Marketing Science, 32(6), 827–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubé, J-P, Hitsch, GJ, Jindal, P. (2014). The joint identification of utility and discount functions from stated choice data: An application to durable goods adoption. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 12(4), 331–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, B.R. (2009). A dynamic model of consumer replacement cycles in the PC processor industry. Marketing Science, 28(5), 846–867.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gowrisankaran, G., & Rysman, M. (2012). Dynamics of consumer demand for new durable goods. Journal of Political Economy, 120(6), 1173–1219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendel, I., & Nevo, A. (2006). Measuring the implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior. Econometrica, 74(6), 1637–1673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, C.-Y. (2015). Switching cost and deposit demand in China. International Economic Review, 56(3), 723–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski, C.F. (2004). Measuring expectations. Econometrica, 72(5), 1329–1376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D. (1974). The measurement of urban travel demand. Journal of public economics, 3(4), 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melnikov, O. (2013). Demand for differentiated durable products: the case of the us computer printer market. Economic Inquiry, 51(2), 1277–1298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nair, H. (2007). Intertemporal price discrimination with forward-looking consumers: Application to the us market for console video-games. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 5(3), 239–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schiraldi, P. (2011). Automobile replacement: a dynamic structural approach. The RAND journal of economics, 42(2), 266–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song, I., & Chintagunta, P.K. (2003). Micromodel of new product adoption with heterogeneous and forward-looking consumers: Application to the digital camera category. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 1(4), 371–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiergraeber, S. (2017). Network effects and switching costs in the us wireless industry. Memeo.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Timothy Derdenger.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Short term elasticity

In addition to estimates of a long run own-price elasticities and profits to inform the reader of the difference between the data generating process and the results of the estimation methodologies, we also present short-term elasticities. Specifically, this short-term own-price elasticity is the % change in total quantity for good j for the first τshort = 4 periods resulting from a 1% temporary decrease in the price of good j in period 1. We determine this measure for each good and average over the number of products as done above with the long-term elasticity measures.The profit measure is computed as the sum of discounted period profits and computed based on prices, marginal costs and sales in each period. We then determine the percent change in profit from a 1% temporary decrease in price in period 1, assuming an initial market size of 10,000,000 consumers and a discount factor of βj = 0.975 for the firm.

We present the results of a short-term temporary price change in Tables 5 and 6 for the setting of identical price transitions and heterogeneous transitions, respectively. When analyzes the results we find the results from the own-price elasticity differs from the long term elasticity above. Specifically, the tables below indicate that % change from the short-term own-price DGP elasticity becomes more negative as J increases whereas the long-term own-price elasticity improves as J increases. Moreover, it appears that with respect to both elasticity measures that the IVS is competitive with the full solution when J = 2 or J = 3.

Table 5 Short term elasticities: Identical transition
Table 6 Short term elasticities: Different transition

Appendix B: Computational details

We use the following computational algorithm to estimate the model parameters. We employ a GMM procedure using mathematical programming with equilibrium constraints (MPEC). Model parameters are \(\mathbf {\theta }=\left (\bar {\alpha }^{p},\alpha \right )\). Let W be the GMM weighting matrix. The constrained optimization formulation is

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \min_{\mathbf{\theta,\xi}}\left[\mathbf{\xi^{\prime}}\mathbf{Z}\mathbf{WZ}^{\prime}\mathbf{\xi}\right],\\ st: \hat{s}_{jt}(\xi,\theta)=S_{jt} \end{array} $$

with the market share equations imposed as constraints to the optimization problem.

2.1 Overall procedure

  1. 1.

    Given a guess of \(\mathbf {\theta }=\left (\bar {\alpha }^{p},\alpha \right )\) and ξjt determine the simulated market share for each product in each time period.

  2. 2.

    With the same guess of \(\mathbf {\theta }=\left (\bar {\alpha }^{p},\alpha \right )\) and ξjt compute the GMM objective function defined in the equation above.

  3. 3.

    Search over \(\mathbf {\theta }=\left (\bar {\alpha }^{p},\alpha \right )\) and ξjtto minimize the objective function given the constraint that the observed market share equals the simulated share.

2.2 Formation of the market share constraint

  1. 1.

    Given a guess of \(\mathbf {\theta }=\left (\bar {\alpha }^{p},\alpha \right )\) and ξjt formulate \(f_{k,t}\left ({x_{t}^{c}},\xi _{t}\right )\) for each product k, and for each period t.

  2. 2.

    Obtain \(\delta _{kt}^{h}\) for each product k and period t, using the following equation:

    $$ \delta_{kt}=\frac{F_{k,t}}{\left( 1-\beta\right)}+\bar{\alpha}^{p}p_{k,t}\qquad k\in\mathbf{J_{t}} $$
  3. 3.

    Compute the inclusive value for each consumer:

    $$ \delta_{t}=\log\left( \sum\limits_{k}\exp\left( \delta_{kt}\right)\right) $$
  4. 4.

    Obtain the coefficients through estimation of an AR(1) regression of δit:

    1. (a)

      estimate δt+ 1 = γ0 + γ1δt + ζt

    2. (b)

      given estimates of γ1 and the variance of ζt discretize (N = 30) formulate the transition matrix of δt using the Rouwenhorst method

  5. 5.

    Obtain consumer-specific expected value of not purchasing (and hence continuing):

    $$ EV\left( \delta\right)=\log\left( \exp\left( \delta\right)+\exp\left( \beta\mathbf{\ E}\left[EV(\delta^{\prime})|\delta\right]\right)\right) $$
    1. (a)

      Given the discretized values of δt and the corresponding transition matrix perform a value function iteration to determine \(EV\left (\delta \right )\)

    2. (b)

      Perfrom a linear interpolation of the expected value function back to the estimated values of δit

  6. 6.

    The model-predicted purchase probability or market share for each product k in each period t is then given as:

    $$ \hat{s}_{kt}=\frac{\exp\left( \delta_{t}\right)}{\left[\exp\left( EV\left( \delta_{t}\right)\right)\right]}\frac{\exp\left( \delta_{kt}\right)}{\exp\left( \delta_{t}\right)} $$
  7. 7.

    Determine the difference between the observed and simulated market shares at a given parameter set \(s_{k,t}-\hat {s}_{kt}\left (\delta _{t}\right )\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Derdenger, T., Kumar, V. Estimating dynamic discrete choice models with aggregate data: Properties of the inclusive value approximation. Quant Mark Econ 17, 359–384 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-019-09215-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-019-09215-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation