1 Introduction

Some neighborhoods in the USA were hit hard, but unevenly, by foreclosures in the aftermath of the 2008 housing market crash.Footnote 1 The prevailing view has been that the uneven distribution of foreclosures is largely responsible for the uneven price effects observed across neighborhoods, as greater concentrations of foreclosures increase marginal price effects of additional foreclosures. But this perspective ignores the possibility that foreclosure price effects on surrounding properties may depend not only on the localized concentration of foreclosures, but also on the physical and structural characteristics of neighborhoods. The nature of the built environment may matter; the age and uniformity of the neighborhood and the physical proximity to neglected or vacant foreclosed properties are determined by structural density and street configuration. The questions addressed here are straightforward: Does the surrounding built environment influence foreclosure price effects? And, if so, to what extent?

Most reviews of empirical studies on foreclosure effects suggest that neighboring property prices tend to be anywhere between one to two percent lower in neighborhoods with foreclosures.Footnote 2 The literature recognizes two mechanisms driving neighboring property prices lower. One is the negative foreclosure externality arising from poorly maintained or vacant foreclosed property.Footnote 3 The second is the supply effect arising from the fact that foreclosures increase the supply of housing for sale (Anenberg and Kung 2014; Hartley 2014; Mian et al. 2015; Gerardi et al. 2015).Footnote 4 Both mechanisms lead to lower neighborhood property values, the source of distress to residents and local governments.

The prevailing focus on foreclosure externality and supply effects on prices of surrounding houses overlooks a possibly mediating influence within the neighborhood. For instance, supply of new construction provides positive physical externalities to the neighborhood (Ioannides 2002; Rosenthal 2008; Helms 2012; Zahirovic-Herbert and Gibler 2014; Coulson et al. 2019; Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022). Buyers may interpret new construction as a signal of improved neighborhood quality, or the arrival of more affluent residents (Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022). In any case, new construction, whether rebuilding teardowns or new infill development, occurs unevenly in the interior of the urban area.Footnote 5 We empirically control for differences in the supply of new construction as a source of systematic variation in observed foreclosure price effects across neighborhoods.

It is worth emphasizing at this point that the foreclosure externality argument itself also suggests possible variation in foreclosure effects across neighborhoods. The negative externality arises because foreclosures induce vacancy and underinvestment in maintenance, creating negative physical externalities that reduce neighborhood attractiveness (Harding et al. 2009, 2012; Daneshvary and Clauretie 2012) as well as external social costs in the form of reduced social interaction and community involvement (Harding et al. 2009) or increased crime (Immergluck and Smith 2006). Foreclosures may be the source of negative shopping externalities as well; potential buyers may interpret the presence of foreclosures as a signal of a greater risk of neighborhood instability or secular decline, which prompts them to focus their search efforts elsewhere. All of these factors reduce property values of surrounding non-distressed property. Not all neighborhoods, however, are equally vulnerable to these risks (Anenberg and Kung 2014; Ihlanfeldt and Mayock 2016). This study focuses on how foreclosure price effects vary by neighborhood configuration. To do so, we use geocoded administrative data to allow more explicit models of how foreclosure effects vary across neighborhoods.

This paper makes two contributions to the empirical housing market literature. First, we propose a simple framework for sorting neighborhood property price effects into foreclosure externality, new construction externality, and supply or pecuniary externality effects. Most previous work struggles with how to empirically separate these externality and supply effects and so tends to avoid distinguishing them explicitly. Studies that do distinguish externality and supply effects use supply measures that count numbers of foreclosures at greater distance (Harding et al. 2009), nearby foreclosures of different property types (Hartley 2014; Fisher et al. 2015), or precise timing of distressed and non-distressed properties listings (Anenberg and Kung 2014). It seems appropriate to identify supply effects using measures of competing or substitute properties that are on the market at the same time as the subject property. To that end, we incorporate measures of both foreclosed and similar open market (non-foreclosed) properties for sale in the surrounding neighborhood at the same time as the subject property.

Second, we examine whether foreclosure price effects vary with neighborhood configuration. Foreclosure effects may vary across neighborhoods due to differences in underlying economic vitality (Rosenthal 2008), housing market segmentation (Gerardi et al. 2015; Cheung et al. 2014; Zhang and Leonard 2014) as well as the neighborhood structure (Schuetz et al. 2008). Ellen and O'Regan (2010) argue that neighborhood configuration matters for market outcomes in general. Applying that notion to this case, a foreclosure may be more visible or physically closer to more surrounding properties in some neighborhoods than in other neighborhoods, and as a result, generate stronger price responses. To take these neighborhood differences into account, we also investigate foreclosure effects across built environments in terms of their urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, development period, vacancy rate, and whether the subdivision is gated or non-gated.

The geographic concentration of foreclosures in certain neighborhoods suggests that, for some neighborhood configurations, the foreclosure effect might be nonlinear in the number of foreclosures (e.g., in the case of rather uniform neighborhoods with many similar properties). If so, even a few neighboring foreclosures relative to non-distressed sales will have significant value effects on surrounding non-distressed transactions. Hanson et al. (2012) show that households tend to spatially sort by credit quality, creating conditions ripe for geographic concentration of foreclosures. The question remains whether the resultant concentrations of foreclosures in certain neighborhoods lead to increasing marginal price effects, exhibiting deeper and more enduring neighborhood price effects than would otherwise be expected if foreclosures were instead more evenly distributed across the market area. Schuetz et al. (2008) and Harding et al. (2009) both find no evidence of nonlinear foreclosure effects. In contrast with the samples used in those studies, our sample covers a period of intense foreclosure activity in one of the most active foreclosure markets in the US, which allows us to probe more deeply into how an unprecedented level of foreclosures affects property prices.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the empirical framework to sort out the channels through which foreclosures may influence surrounding property values. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 reports the empirical results. We first report on foreclosure spillover effects and then consider whether these spillover effects vary with neighborhood configuration. Section 5 concludes.

2 Empirical framework

The empirical framework maps local foreclosures, open market sales and new construction onto neighboring house prices. In estimating these local effects we face the following challenge. Neighborhood effects such as foreclosure externalities (Campbell et al. 2011; Towe and Lawley 2013), crime risk (Linden and Rockoff 2008) or externalities associated with new construction (Ioannides 2002; Helms 2012) may be associated with endogenous social effects (Manski 1993; Rossi-Hansberg et al. 2010; Ross 2011; Ioannides 2011). These social effects arise when a household’s foreclosure or new construction decision spillover to neighbors. Ideally, one would like to control for these effects using instrumental variables that are correlated with the local measure but not with price.Footnote 6 We take the alternative approach used by Linden and Rockoff (2008) and Campbell et al. (2011), which relies on the impact of extremely local neighborhood measures and very small time windows, and compares the relevant coefficients pertaining to neighborhood measures before and after each property sale to control for the state of the local economy in the micro-neighborhood.

We estimate separate localized externality effects of foreclosures, supply or pecuniary externality effects, and new housing constructionFootnote 7 on other non-distressed property sales. We control for neighborhood market externalities by including number of foreclosures, number of open market sales and, number of newly constructed houses that are on the market at the same time as the subject property.

The model we estimate specifies the log of price of house transaction i in neighborhood r and year t as a linear function of property characteristics and neighborhood market conditions:

$$\begin{aligned} {\text{ln}}P_{irt} =\; & \beta_{X} X_{it} + \beta_{{{\text{FS}}}}^{{{\text{before}}}} {\text{FS}}_{it}^{{{\text{before}}}} + \beta_{{{\text{FS}}}}^{{{\text{after}}}} {\text{FS}}_{it}^{{{\text{after}}}} + \beta_{{{\text{MS}}}}^{{{\text{before}}}} {\text{MS}}_{it}^{{{\text{before}}}} + \beta_{{{\text{MS}}}}^{{{\text{after}}}} {\text{MS}}_{it}^{{{\text{after}}}} \\ & + \beta_{{{\text{NC}}}}^{{{\text{before}}}} {\text{NC}}_{it}^{{{\text{before}}}} + \beta_{{{\text{NC}}}}^{{{\text{after}}}} {\text{NC}}_{it}^{{{\text{after}}}} + \mu_{t} + \eta_{r} + \varepsilon_{irt} ,\\ \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where Pirt is the selling price; Xit the vector of house characteristics; FSit the number of nearby foreclosures, MSit the number of nearby open market sales, and NCit is the number of nearby newly constructed houses, all within distance d and within timeframe τ before or after the subject property transaction. Equation (1) also includes location and (interaction) time fixed effects to reduce unobserved heterogeneity and omitted variable bias.Footnote 8 Further, \({\varepsilon }_{irt}\) is the error term clustered at the location fixed effects-level. Davis (2004) argues that using location fixed effects and clustered errors together also serves as nonparametric spatial correlation control.

Cast this way, the FS, MS, and NC variables control for nearby foreclosed houses, open market (non-foreclosure) houses, and new construction in the neighborhood at the same time the subject property is for sale. The timeframe windows before and after are included to capture other properties on the market at the same time as the subject property, some of which sell before and some after the subject sells.Footnote 9 The estimated coefficients for local market conditions variables provide important information regarding the extent of possible foreclosure and new construction externalities. FS captures the effect of foreclosures increasing the supply of existing houses on the market plus the negative foreclosure externality. MS captures the increasing supply associated with open (non-foreclosure) market sales of new construction and existing houses. The coefficient on the NC variable measures any externality associated with new construction (holding the total supply of houses constant).

These variables may include endogenous responses to neighborhood market conditions. Our identification strategy hinges on comparing short-run changes in values within very small areas arising from changes in the local or neighborhood housing market context. Following the procedure in Campbell et al. (2011), the externality effect estimate is the difference between the coefficient for foreclosures before the subject property transaction and the coefficient for foreclosures after the transaction, \({[\beta }_{\mathrm{FS}}^{\mathrm{before}}-{\beta }_{\mathrm{FS}}^{\mathrm{after}}]\). The standard error of the estimate can be calculated using the delta method. If foreclosure spillovers are present, then we should observe a negative impact as the largest negative impacts of foreclosure on property values are prior to the sale. The same identification strategy applies to the new construction and open market sales variables. To the extent that local economic shocks impact house prices, we include in one of the models also past and future foreclosures slightly farther away (between one-tenth and a quarter of a mile) as controls (Linden and Rockoff 2008; Campbell et al. 2011).

Second, because foreclosures generate both negative externality and supply effects (or pecuniary externality), we follow Anenberg and Kung (2014) and Hartley (2014), and use the difference in estimates relative to market sales to remove the supply effects of foreclosures on price, which in our application reduces toFootnote 10

$$\mathrm{Foreclosure\, externality}={[\beta }_{\mathrm{FS}}^{\mathrm{before}}-{\beta }_{\mathrm{FS}}^{\mathrm{after}}]- {[\beta }_{\mathrm{MS}}^{\mathrm{before}}-{\beta }_{\mathrm{MS}}^{\mathrm{after}}].$$
(2)

The above calculation measures the combined effect of increasing nearby foreclosures by one, while decreasing the number of non-distressed properties on the market by one, to arrive at the net externality effect of an additional foreclosure.

Finally, to the extent that new construction creates a positive spillover in the neighborhood, the difference in the before and after coefficient estimates for the new construction variables should reflect the new construction externality:

$$\mathrm{New\, construction\, externality} ={[\beta }_{\mathrm{NC}}^{\mathrm{before}}-{\beta }_{\mathrm{NC}}^{\mathrm{after}}].$$
(3)

In this case, there is no need to remove a supply effect because the number of non-distressed properties for sale (which includes new houses) is already being captured by the market sales variables (which includes new houses). The estimated new construction effect reflects the effect of increasing the number of new houses for sale by one, while simultaneously decreasing the number of existing houses for sale by one.

If the (negative) FS coefficient is algebraically less than the MS coefficient, then increasing the number of foreclosures while holding neighborhood supply constant reduces the prices of surrounding properties. This result is consistent with a negative real externality effect from neighboring foreclosures. If, on the other hand, the FS and MS coefficients are not significantly different, neighboring foreclosures have no real externality effect on surrounding properties. Finally, if the (negative) MS coefficient is less than the FS coefficient, then increasing the number of foreclosures while holding neighborhood market supply constant increases the prices of surrounding properties. Although it may seem counter-intuitive at first blush, this outcome is nonetheless consistent with foreclosed properties generating a stronger shopping externality for the neighborhood than open market properties. In this case, the presence of nearby foreclosures for sale is a stronger draw for potential buyers than open market properties; the resultant increases in buyer arrival rates increase the probabilities of higher priced matches for nearby sellers, including sellers of open market properties. It is important to remember that the coefficients on the new construction variables (NC) do not capture supply effects and instead solely pick up the neighborhood quality signaling or the housing investment externality effect arising from new construction.

To provide evidence on the extent of variation in foreclosure effects by neighborhood configuration, we estimate separate models by the built structure of the neighborhood. The neighborhood configuration is often defined in terms of streets, lots, and buildings.Footnote 11 Along with physical elements, the social aspects of urban morphology have also been deemed important (Nedovic-Budic et al. 2016). We summarize neighborhood configuration using a set of simple dimensions of urban form: urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, development period, vacancy rate, and whether the property is in a gated or non-gated neighborhood subdivision.

3 Data

The data are drawn from property assessment records of Orange County, Florida, covering all of the 426,021 parcels in the county as of August 24, 2012. Orange County is part of the Orlando-Kissimmee-Sanford Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA), and has been experiencing long-term population growth from 896,344 (2000 Census) to 1,145,956 (2010 Census). Orange County is an interesting case study to explore whether foreclosure price effects vary across neighborhoods. Orange County is one of the epicenters of the foreclosure crisis. While so, foreclosures were not evenly distributed across neighborhoods. We focus on how foreclosure price effects vary by neighborhood configuration.

Local assessor records in Florida have been used as the primary data source in a number of studies and have several advantages (Ihlanfeldt and Mayock 2012; Turnbull and Van der Vlist 2023). One advantage of local assessor records over multiple listing service (MLS) data for broker-assisted transactions is that tax records provide information on the entire stock of existing properties, not just those that sell. Another is that MLS data do not cover all public transactions and, most important for the question addressed here, likely underreport foreclosure transactions (Daneshvary and Clauretie 2012; Chinloy et al. 2017)—which may be critically important in this sample, as increasing numbers of foreclosed properties in Orange County were sold directly to investment firms and other organized investors without first being offered to individual buyers through traditional channels like the MLS.

Conversely, a disadvantage of tax assessment records is that they provide no direct information about liquidity or time-on-the market for sold properties (although most existing foreclosure studies using MLS data also have not exploited liquidity data). Krainer (2001) shows that changes in buyer willingness-to-pay is reflected in both selling price and liquidity in search markets; recent empirical studies provide evidence of price-liquidity capitalization for both individual property and neighborhood characteristics (Turnbull et al. 2013; Turnbull and Zahirovic-Herbert 2011). Therefore, the absence of marketing time measures in this study means that the price effects of foreclosures identified here, as well as in most of the foreclosure literature, may reflect only one dimension of the possible capitalization effects.

The tax records yield detailed information on property characteristics as well as addresses, transaction prices, transaction dates, and deed types (which allows us to identify foreclosed properties).Footnote 12 We focus on built-up areas of the county, excluding the sparsely settled northwestern and eastern parts of the jurisdiction. The single family detached house (SFD) data cover 266,897 separate properties during the sample period of January 2007 through August 2012.

The data include transaction price, transaction date, and deed type. The structure of the data source allows us to observe the transaction history over 2007-to mid-2012. This sample period captures the declining market over 2008–2010 and the weak recovery starting in early 2012. The dependent variable is the transaction price. The control variables measure property characteristics and location and time fixed effects. The analysis focuses on single family detached houses (SFD). Living area indicates the square feet of air-conditioned/heated area. Other property characteristics include number of bedrooms and bathrooms, presence of a private swimming pool, house age, and type of exterior walls. Total land acreage is the measure of parcel size and encompasses both upland and any submerged area lying within the parcel legal boundary. The data allow us to construct GIS-based neighborhood housing market conditions indicators based on the number of FS, MS, and NC in the neighborhood within distance d (one-tenth, a quarter of a mile) taking place within time frame τ before and after transaction time t (90, 180 days) of each subject property.

We define neighborhood configuration using a set of simple dimensions of urban form. First, we measure urban density, development period, and vacancy at the neighborhood census blockgroup-level, using the 2000 American Community Survey (ACS). Next, at a more granular level, we measure neighborhood mix of homes (variation in development period, and size of living area) at the census block-level, using the administrative parcel-level data for the year 2000. Last, we identify for each transaction whether a property lies within a private gated or publicly accessible non-gated subdivision, using administrative information on subdivisions.Footnote 13 We use these measures to examine how foreclosure effects vary with neighborhood configuration.

The sample consists of open market transactions transferring warranty deeds, and excludes all legal administrator’s deed, tax deed, and quit claim deeds (all for administrative non-arm’s length transaction purposes), including all transactions for $100, the usual indicator of a non-market transfer of property interest. Following Daneshvary et al. (2011), we trim the lower and upper 1 percent of the distribution of price and living area to control for outliers. Furthermore, we define the maximum spatial extent of the surrounding neighborhood for each property as one mile, so while observations within one mile of the county boundary are used to construct instruments for total number of properties, foreclosed sales, market sales, and new construction, they are not otherwise included in the price equation sample. Similarly, observations in the first six-month time frame are excluded from the model estimation to construct the proper burn-in period for our instruments. The number of observations in the sample for estimating the price equation is 39,913 open market transactions.Footnote 14 Variable definitions are given in Appendix 1.

Table 1 reports the descriptive statistics. The table indicates a mean price of almost $235,000 and a median of $185,000, thus reflecting a distribution skewed to the right. We therefore use the natural logarithm of transaction price in the empirical analysis. Structural property characteristics indicate the type of building construction material (63% have walls made of stucco covered concrete block versus wood frame construction), number of bedrooms (3.45 average), living area (2,040 square feet average), number of bathrooms (2.32 average), presence of a private pool (27%), lot size (40,079 square feet average), and actual age of the house (22.6 years). Location controls include the (quadratic) distance to the Orlando CBD (8.98 miles linear distance average) and zip code fixed effects. Over 70 percent of the transactions lie within the City of Orlando, the largest and most populous municipality in Orange County.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

A further decomposition of descriptive statistics by neighborhood configuration is found in Appendix 2. The descriptive statistics report some structural differences in average property characteristics across type of neighborhood. Low density neighborhoods have lower mean house prices ($206,809) than high density neighborhoods ($281,254). Also, older neighborhoods (in terms of mean building age) have lower mean house prices ($165,234) relative to newer neighborhoods ($311,275). The typical property in these older neighborhoods is smaller in terms of living area, and of less quality in terms of construction materials, but they generally have larger parcels. Note further that house prices are higher in neighborhoods with more heterogeneous housing stock measured in terms of property age or property size.

The lower panel of Table 1 provides summary statistics for the constructed variables measuring neighborhood market conditions including the number of foreclosures (FS), the number of market transactions (MS), and the number of newly constructed properties (NC). The data reveal that a large majority of sales occur in areas with no surrounding foreclosures. This is consistent with Campbell et al. (2011) although the overall incidence of foreclosures in Orange County is greater. In total, 82.6 percent of sellers do not have any foreclosure within one-tenth mile and 180 days. Multiple nearby foreclosures are even less frequent. The data reveal that 95.7 percent of the sellers do not observe two or more foreclosures, while 98.8 percent of the sellers do not observe three or more foreclosures, all within one-tenth mile and 180 days.Footnote 15

The mean number of nearby foreclosures is 0.235 but varies across neighborhood types. Likewise, one observes differences in the number of market sales and in the number of newly constructed properties. Looking at the number of newly constructed properties within the indicated geographic area and time frame, the average new construction (0.542 for the pooled sample) varies between 0.117 and 4.522 across neighborhood types. These transactions can be interpreted relative to the density or mean total property which varies across neighborhood types between 19.59 and 36.76. Overall, the FS, MS, and NC measures all show substantial variation across neighborhood configuration.

4 Empirical results

4.1 Foreclosure spillover effects

Table 2 reports the results for the pooled models of Eq. (1). The models indicate joint significance of the specification. The estimates for the structural characteristics of the property are as expected. Property value decreases with distance to the CBD and the effect becomes less pronounced at greater distances. House structure quality and exterior construction matter. Concrete block construction covered with stucco exhibits higher market value relative to wood frame construction. In addition, larger houses in terms of number of bedrooms, living area and number of bathrooms are associated with higher property values. A pool has a significant positive effect on property value in this market, as does parcel size.

Table 2 Estimation results pooled model

The lower panel in Table 2 reports associated estimates for the price effects of surrounding foreclosures on property prices based on Eqs. (2) and (3). The estimates reveal that foreclosures within one-tenth mile and 180 days before the sale of a given subject property have significant negative effects on surrounding open market sales.Footnote 16 The marginal effect of a foreclosure before a sale is significantly stronger than the coefficient of a foreclosure after a sale, a result consistent with Campbell et al. (2011). Note that sales of some properties occurring after the subject property sells are also on the market before the subject sells. Also observe that the foreclosure coefficient is stronger than the coefficient on open market or non-distressed sales, which implies that the negative foreclosure externality effect dominates its associated supply effect. In our model 1, the foreclosure externality effect calculated using Eq. (2) is − 0.0152 with a standard error of 0.005 and is significant at the 1 percent level.Footnote 17 For model 2, where we control for local housing market conditions by adding local housing market measures of number of foreclosure sales, market sales, and new construction within one-tenth and a quarter of a mile, the foreclosure effect on surrounding property remains economically significant and, not surprisingly, negative.Footnote 18 Note further that the foreclosure externality effect within one-tenth and one quarter of a mile (denoted with ‘far’) is − 0.0162 and statistically not significantly different from the obtained foreclosure externality effect nearby.Footnote 19

The new construction coefficient before a sale relative to the coefficient after a sale indicates that new construction has a positive externality effect on neighborhood housing. This finding is consistent with the notion that potential buyers regard new construction as a positive signal of neighborhood stability or growth (Ioannides 2002; Helms 2012; Zahirovic-Herbert and Gibler 2014; Gonzalez-Pampillon 2022) or that new construction generates positive shopping externalities for surrounding existing properties. The associated new construction externality effect calculated using Eq. (3) is 0.005, with a standard error of 0.002 and is significant at the 2 percent significance level.

It is interesting to compare the negative foreclosure externality and the positive new construction externality in detail. Our estimates indicate that the negative externality effect of a foreclosure outweighs the positive externality effect of new construction. A linear test on equality of the parameters of Eqs. (2) and (3) gives an F value of 14.0 and is beyond the critical value at the 1 percent significance level. Hence, while new construction provides a positive signal to the neighborhood, the marginal effect of the (negative) foreclosure externality dominates.

Table 3 reports key estimates for various location and time (interaction) fixed effects. Pulling these results together we find foreclosure externality effects anywhere between − 0.0156 and − 0.0096. These estimates are similar to our main results. For new construction externality effects we find estimates between 0.001 and 0.0055, which for some fixed effects specifications are not significantly different from zero.

Table 3 Summary of results for models with varying fixed effects

4.2 Foreclosure spillover effects and neighborhood configuration

We turn now to the variation in foreclosure effect by neighborhood configuration. What we have obtained thus far is an average effect of foreclosure on property prices. But we have argued that foreclosure effects may vary across neighborhoods. We probe more deeply into urban morphology and how foreclosure effects vary with a set of simple dimensions of urban structure, viz. urban density, neighborhood mix of homes, and development period, vacancy rate, and whether the property is in a gated or non-gated neighborhood subdivision.

First we consider urban density based on the premise that foreclosures in low density neighborhoods may have stronger price effects because they are more visible than in high density neighborhoods. We test for this effect by examining foreclosure price effects for subsamples partitioned by density. We partition the data into low density and high density and re-estimate the basic model on the resultant subsamples.Footnote 20

In order to probe more deeply into how foreclosures may depend more subtly on the neighborhood mix, we use a variety of ways to measure differences between neighborhoods. One way to control for type of neighborhood is to segment by mean vacancy rate (low and high vacancy ratesFootnote 21) or mean age of the neighborhood (new and old neighborhoodsFootnote 22). We use these measures of between-neighborhood variation to identify the extent to which differences in the foreclosure externality arise across neighborhoods. Table 4 reports the key estimates.

Table 4 Summary of results for models by neighborhood type

Looking at the results summarized in Table 4, the point estimates of the foreclosure externality effect, as measured by the difference in before and after FS and MS coefficients, indicate a somewhat stronger impact in the lowest density neighborhoods. The implied pattern of the foreclosure signaling/density relationship is consistent with that suggested by Schuetz et al. (2008).

Another way to control for type of neighborhood is to use the coefficient of variation to measure within-neighborhood variation in terms of age or size of house (homogeneous versus heterogeneous neighborhoodsFootnote 23). Overall, the results indicate strongest effects for homogeneous neighborhoods, both in terms of age or size of the housing units. We interpret this as strong evidence of a signaling effect of neighborhood stability. The estimates suggest two factors at work. First, the foreclosure externality varies with the physical structure of the neighborhood as measured by density and (variation in) age and size of houses. Second, the foreclosure externality varies with the specific neighborhood housing market conditions as measured by vacancy rate.

We next turn to the possibility that the main effect of foreclosures on prices might be nonlinear. Figure 1 depicts the structure by mapping the parameter estimates for the various neighborhood types. These results are based on models that employ a set of foreclosure dummy variables as a flexible structure to capture any nonlinear effects associated with the number of foreclosures. The effects are consistent with the basic models examined earlier. There appears to be a cumulative negative real externality from additional foreclosures varying by neighborhood configuration. Summarizing the results, we find that older, homogeneous neighborhoods with high vacancy rates are most in jeopardy when foreclosures are present.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Nonlinear foreclosure effects across neighborhood types, number of foreclosures FS (near, before). Note Graphs plot coefficient for I1 (FS = 1), I2 (FS = 2), and I3 (FS = 3 or more), based on model specification (1) in Table 2. The dependent variable is log transaction value. The reference category includes Number of Bedrooms equals 3, Number of Bathrooms equals 2.00. All models include location fixed effects for ZIP code, and time fixed effects for year and month

Table 4 also reports the key estimates when comparing neighborhoods in gated versus non-gated subdivisions. Gated subdivisions in this market are private communities that offer their residents amenities which are unavailable to the general public. Properties in gated communities are also typically subject to stricter controls regarding maintenance and use than are properties in non-gated neighborhoods. The community associations governing gated neighborhoods often have legal powers to compel maintenance or undertake actions to maintain the neighborhood character. It is therefore not surprising that results reported in Table 4 show that foreclosure and new construction externalities vary significantly across gated and non-gated neighborhood types. Legal governing powers used by community associations in gated neighborhoods appear to obviate both types of externalities, in contrast to the significant effects observed for non-gated neighborhoods.

5 Conclusion

Foreclosures influence nearby property values, but the marginal effects vary significantly across neighborhoods. Our approach estimates the foreclosure effects across neighborhoods while controlling for the increasing supply of housing for sale as erstwhile foreclosed owners are removed from the market. We also introduce new construction into the empirical framework to control for possible externality effects arising when buyers interpret new construction as a signal of neighborhood stability or future growth, removing these possibly confounding influences on the estimated foreclosure externality effects across neighborhood types.

Data from an epicenter of the US foreclosure experience, Orange County, Florida, reveal that nearby foreclosures appear to reduce property prices by 1.43 percent overall. Removing the supply effect, these estimates imply a foreclosure externality of − 1.27 percent. The new construction externality is 0.5 percent.

Turning to the main point of this paper, we find that foreclosure spillover effects systematically vary across types of neighborhoods, exhibiting almost tenfold variation in some cases. For example, the marginal foreclosure externality ranges from − 0.38 percent for newer neighborhoods to − 3.59 percent for older ones. Overall, the strongest foreclosure effects are found in low density neighborhoods, structurally homogeneous neighborhoods, and non-gated subdivisions. We also find that nonlinear foreclosure effects vary across types of neighborhoods, with older, structurally homogeneous neighborhoods with high vacancy rates most in jeopardy in this regard.

Admittedly, urban morphology includes more dimensions than the ones we have considered, including street connectivity and accessibility. Likewise, as foreclosures force affected households to move, foreclosures may well have long-term implications for the composition and social stability of urban neighborhoods. Hawley and Turnbull (2019) show that the built environment affects household behavior, but at the same time households choose neighborhoods with built environments conducive to pursuing lifestyles they prefer. Taking this type of endogenous household sorting into account, while we find that neighborhood built environment does matter for foreclosure price effects on surrounding properties, the Hawley and Turnbull (2019) conclusions suggest a need for future work to identify the extent to which these effects are specifically related to the built environment or to the mix of residents attracted to neighborhoods with those characteristics.