Skip to main content
Log in

Determining profit-optimizing return policies – a two-step approach on data from taobao.com

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Electronic Markets Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Selecting an optimal return policy requires taking into account two effects: the potential positive effect on sales and the potential negative effect of higher costs. We propose a two-step model, in which we first utilize a robust regression to explain purchase behavior, and then apply a zero-inflated negative binominal regression to model the return behavior. We apply this model to data from the most important online platform in China and obtain three main findings. First, the adoption of return policies results in increased sales, while reputation works as a moderator in this process. Second, good reputation and traditional customer friendly return policies (like the Seven-Day Return policy) can significantly increase the number of returns, while more guarantee credibility (enhanced by Guarantee Money) is related to fewer returns. Taken together, both the Seven-Day Return policy (profit increase of +0.29 %) and Guarantee Money (profit increase of +0.016 % per Yuan guarantee) ultimately increase firms’ profit.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alibaba. (2013). Alibaba group company overview. Alibaba Group. Retrieved Oct. 21, 2013, from http://www.alibabagroup.com/en/about/overview

  • Anderson, E. T., Hansen, K., & Simester, D. (2009). The option value of returns: Theory and empirical evidence. Marketing Science, 28(3), 405–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bae, S., & Lee, T. (2011). Product type and consumers’ perception of online consumer reviews. Electronic Markets, 21(4), 255–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banjo, S. (2013). Rampant returns plague e-retailers. The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved May 15, 2014, from http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702304773104579270260683155216.

  • Bechwati, N. N., & Siegal, W. S. (2005). The impact of the prechoice process on product returns. Journal of Marketing Research, 42(3), 358–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, D. (2005). Moving forward in reverse. Logistics Today, 46(7), 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, D. (2007, Aprial 10). Supply chains also work in reverse. Industry Week. Retrieved May 15, 2014, from http://www.industryweek.com/articles/supply_chains_also_work_in_reverse_13947.aspx.

  • Bonifield, C., Cole, C., & Schultz, R. L. (2010). Product returns on the internet: a case of mixed signals? Journal of Business Research, 63(9–10), 1058–1065.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, W., & Kirmani, A. (1993). A consumer-side experimental examination of signaling theory: do consumers perceive warranties as signals of quality? Journal of Consumer Research, 20(1), 111–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che, Y.-K. (1996). Customer return policies for experience goods. Journal of Industrial Economics, 44(1), 17–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chu, W., Gerstner, E., & Hess, J. D. (1998). Managing dissatisfaction how to decrease customer opportunism by partial refunds. Journal of Service Research, 1(2), 140–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, S., Hagerty, M., & CGerstner, E. (1998). Return policies and the optimal level of “hassle”. Journal of Economics and Business, 50(5), 445–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desmet, P. (2013). How retailer money-back guarantees influence consumer preferences for retailer versus national brands. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1971–1978.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbs, R., Chen, Y., Orr, G., Manyika, J., Chui, M., & Chang, E. (2013). China’s e-tail revolution. McKinsey Global Institute.

  • Dutta, S., Biswas, A., & Grewal, D. (2007). Low price signal default: an empirical investigation of its consequences. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 35(1), 76–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erevelles, S., Roy, A., & Yip, L. S. (2001). The universality of the signal theory for products and services. Journal of Business Research, 52(2), 175–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann, T., Hinz, O., & Skiera, B. (2012). Retailers’ use of shipping cost strategies: free shipping or partitioned prices? International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 16(3), 65–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glover, S., & Benbasat, I. (2010). A comprehensive model of perceived risk of e-commerce transactions. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 15(2), 47–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heilbron, D. C. (1994). Zero‐altered and other regression models for count data with added zeros. Biometrical Journal, 36(5), 531–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heiman, A., McWilliams, B., & Zilberman, D. (2001). Demonstrations and money-back guarantees: market mechanisms to reduce uncertainty. Journal of Business Research, 54(1), 71–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess, J. D., & Mayhew, G. E. (1997). Modeling merchandise returns in direct marketing. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 11(2), 20–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janakiraman, N., & Ordóñez, L. (2012). Effect of effort and deadlines on consumer product returns. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 22(2), 260–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirmani, A., & Rao, A. R. (2000). No pain, no gain: a critical review of the literature on signaling unobservable product quality. Journal of Marketing, 64(2), 66–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavlanova, T., & Benbunan-Fich, R. (2010). Counterfeit products on the internet: the role of seller-level and product-level information. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 15(2), 79–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLachlan, G., & Peel, D. (2004). Finite mixture models. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moorthy, S., & Srinivasan, K. (1995). Signaling quality with a money-back guarantee: the role of transaction costs. Marketing Science, 14(4), 442–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mwalili, S. M., Lesaffre, E., & Declerck, D. (2008). The zero-inflated negative binomial regression model with correction for misclassification: an example in caries research. Statistical Methods in Medical Research, 17(2), 123–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padmanabhan, V., & Png, I. P. (1997). Manufacturer’s return policies and retail competition. Marketing Science, 16(1), 81–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, J. A., & Kumar, V. (2009). Are product returns a necessary evil? Antecedents and consequences. Journal of Marketing, 73(3), 35–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pizzutti, C., & Fernandes, D. (2010). Effect of recovery efforts on consumer trust and loyalty in e-tail: a contingency model. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 14(4), 127–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posselt, T., Gerstner, E., & Radic, D. (2008). Rating e-tailers’ money-back guarantees. Journal of Service Research, 10(3), 207–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Purohit, D., & Srivastava, J. (2001). Effect of manufacturer reputation, retailer reputation, and product warranty on consumer judgments of product quality: a cue diagnosticity framework. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 10(3), 123–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roggeveen, A. L., Goodstein, R. C., & Grewal, D. (2014). Improving the effect of guarantees: the role of a retailer’s reputation. Journal of Retailing, 90(1), 27–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shulman, J. D., Coughlan, A. T., & Savaskan, R. C. (2009). Optimal restocking fees and information provision in an integrated demand–supply model of product returns. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 11(4), 577–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simons, J. S., Neal, D. J., & Gaher, R. M. (2006). Risk for marijuana-related problems among college students: an application of zero-inflated negative binomial regression. The American Journal of Drug and Alcohol Abuse, 32(1), 41–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su, X., & Zhang, F. (2009). On the value of commitment and availability guarantees when selling to strategic consumers. Management Science, 55(5), 713–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sum, C. C., Lee, Y. S., Hays, J. M., & Hill, A. V. (2002). Modeling the effects of a service guarantee on perceived service quality using alternating conditional expectations (ace). Decision Sciences, 33(3), 347–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suwelack, T., Hogreve, J., & Hoyer, W. D. (2011). Understanding money-back guarantees: cognitive, affective, and behavioral outcomes. Journal of Retailing, 87(4), 462–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomason, E. (2013, Sepetember 27). Online retailers go hi-tech to size up shoppers and cut returns. Reuters. Retrieved May 15, 2014, from http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/09/27/net-us-retail-online-returns-idUSBRE98Q0GS20130927

  • Timmers, P. (1998). Business models for electronic markets. Electronic Markets, 8(2), 3–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, S. L. (2001). Remote purchase environments: the influence of return policy leniency on two-stage decision processed. Journal of Marketing Research, 32(2), 157–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ye, Q., Xu, M., Kiang, M., Wu, W., & Sun, F. (2013). In-depth analysis of the seller reputation and price premium relationship: a comparison between ebay us and taobao china. Journal of Electronic Commerce Research, 14(1), 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X., Luo, J., & Li, Q. (2012). Do different reputation systems provide consistent signals of seller quality: a canonical correlation investigation of Chinese c2c marketplaces. Electronic Markets, 22(3), 155–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhuo, J., Wei, J., Liu, L., Koong, K., & Miao, S. (2013). An examination of the determinants of service quality in the Chinese express industry. Electronic Markets, 23(2), 163–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors gratelfully acknowledge the financial support from the China Scholarship Council (No. 201307080002).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wenyan Zhou.

Additional information

Responsible Editor: Andreja Pucihar

Appendix

Appendix

Change for sales (∆S): Change due to return policy [α2 or α3] /Average number of sales [116.726]

Change for returns (∆R): Change due to return policy [ß2 or ß3]* Average return rate (with return record) [0.134]

Change for return probability (RP): Change due to return policy [γ2 or γ3]* Non-return rate [45.5 %]

Profit (P) = (1 + ∆S)*[1-∆R*(1- RP)]* Margin - ∆R*(1- RP)* Return cost

where Margin is 10 % (Dobbs et al. 2013) of revenue, while Return cost is 3.8 % (Blanchard 2007) of revenue.

Profit of normal sellers (P normal ) = 1*(1–7.4 %)*10 %–7.4 %*3.8 % = 8.9788 %

Profit of sellers using Seven-Day Return (P 7-day ) = (1 + 0.0768) * [1–0.1895 * (1–45.7 %)] * 10 % - 0.1895 * (1–45.7 %)*3.8 % = 9.269 %

Increase in Profit from by Seven-Day Return Policy (∆P 7-day ) = P 7-day - P normal  = 0.29 %

Profit of sellers using Guarantee Money (P money ) = (1 + 0.00016) * [1–0.13397 * (1–45.58 %)] *10 % - 0.13397 * (1–45.58 %) *3.8 % = 8.995 %

Increase in Profit from by Guarantee Money Policy (∆P money ) = P money - P normal  = 0.016 %

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhou, W., Hinz, O. Determining profit-optimizing return policies – a two-step approach on data from taobao.com. Electron Markets 26, 103–114 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12525-015-0198-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12525-015-0198-6

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation