Skip to main content
Log in

Insularity and economic development: a survey

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This survey reviews theoretical and empirical evidence on the impact of insularity on regional economic development. Far from being a mere geographical condition, insularity can be regarded as a permanent phenomenon of economic and social peripheralization that prevents islands to reach the goals of sustainable development that are reached by the mainland. Even if the issue of the consequences of insularity on economic development is garnering greater interest in the light of the growing recognition of the significant economic disadvantage faced by islands, both the theoretical and empirical literature in this regard are fragmented. More importantly, the effects of insularity on economic development are not disentangled from similar conditions such as remoteness, smallness and peripherality. The survey focuses as well on the two-sided nature of insularity, since if it is true that islands suffer from permanent handicaps, adequate policy interventions may not only mitigate insularity effect, but also transform insularity into an asset leading a great potential for growth. Finally, some policy suggestions are drawn, highlighting the need for custom-tailored policy measures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Even if islands may have some degree of self-administration, they do not benefit from high political autonomy (Gloersen et al. 2012).

  2. “In order to promote its overall harmonious development, the Community shall develop and pursue its actions leading to the strengthening of its economic and social cohesion. In particular, the Community shall aim at reducing disparities between the levels of development of the various regions and the backwardness of the least favoured regions or islands, including rural areas”.

  3. The report by ESPON (2010) identifies two indexes that have been used in order to summarize the main findings about the islands regions: a “state index”, for the situation of the islands in comparison with the member states they are located in, and a “change index”, capturing changes that have taken place approximately during the last decade.

  4. Supply-side constraints, interpreted as labour–supply constraints, are at odds with reality. Using southern Italy as an example, D’Acunto et al. (2004) highlight that in the last fifty years, southern Italy has never suffered from a lack of labour force.

  5. These literature contributions focus on Italy, which represents an interesting case study, having an homogenous institutional and political environment but high observed level of discrepancy between northern and southern regions.

  6. Armstrong and Read (1995) analysis regarded Western Union, whereas Armstrong et al. (1996, 1998) and Armstrong and Read (2000, 2002) analyse a global dataset.

  7. The existence of fixed links can be associated, to some extent, to regular ferry (Gloersen et al. 2012). However, as Armstrong et al. (2006) point out, excluding island with fixed links is not as clear as it appear. Indeed, there may be limits (i.e. tools, bad weather) preventing the usage of such linkages, so that they remain barriers to integration.

  8. As Musotto (2007) pointed out, one should look at others indicators besides per capita GDP and unemployment when exploring the socio-economic situation of island region. The fact that GDP is broken down on the basis of NUTs categories discriminates against the smallest regions and it does not consider heterogeneity among different territories. This may lead to significant distortions, penalizing territories which experience significant migration, public transfers and transfers of private funds.

  9. In over half the islands, the public sector accounts for over 25 % of jobs (Musotto 2007).

  10. The highest share of employees in tourism can be found in medium-sized islands with populations of 100,000 to 1 million (Gloersen et al. 2012).

  11. Borgatti (2007), using an augmented gravity model, analyses the Pacific islands’ bilateral trade between 1980 and 2004. She eventually found that trade is negatively affected by distance, since the positive effect of remoteness is not big enough to compensate for distance.

  12. As Briguglio (1995) point out, the role of remoteness in the definition of islands needs to be tackled with care, since not all islands are situated in remote areas. However, since insularity and remoteness give rise to similar problems associated with transport and communication, these two issues can be analysed together.

  13. Dependency from maritime and air transport causes an agglomeration of firms nearby airport and port zones, where there is the concentration of all the logistical services for stocking, trading and distributing goods.

  14. Keeping large stocks is the only way to face unexpected changes in demand in the case transport is not frequent or regular. In the case of archipelagos, internal geographic fragmentation may exacerbate these problems (Armstrong et al. 1998).

  15. “First contribution to the future of social and economic cohesion”, Conference of the presidents of the RUP, Las Palmas, February 2002.

  16. Roll-on/roll-off (RORO or ro-ro) ships are vessels designed to carry wheeled cargo such as automobiles, trucks, semi-trailer trucks, trailers or railroad cars that are driven on and off the ship on their own wheels.

  17. In Tinbergen (1962), original formulation of the gravity equation, the size of the trade flow between any pair of countries is estimated by an OLS regression, where the explanatory variables are the import of exports, the size of the importing market and the geographical distance between the two countries, used as a proxy of the transport costs.

  18. In order to ensure a proper conduct of transactions and to prevent opportunistic behaviour, international trade requires some level of trust and degree of commitment between the involved parties. From this perspective, trust and commitment are facilitated by a deep understanding of the norms and values of the trading countries (Elsass and Viega 1994). Furthermore, pronounced cultural differences can complicate interactions and hinder development of the rapport and trust necessary to complete transactions (Doz and Hamel 1998).

  19. Besides traditional agglomeration advantages related to clusters, there are other two agglomeration forces which affect the relocation of economic activities. On one hand, agglomeration may help in reducing innovation costs, so that relocating in the agglomerated region may be cost-saving for R&D performing firms. On the other hand, a firm might be attracted in the agglomerated area because it will find a wider variety of inputs at a lower cost.

  20. Besides traditional agglomeration advantages related to clusters, there are other two agglomeration forces which affect the relocation of economic activities. On one hand, agglomeration may help in reducing innovation costs, so that relocating in the agglomerated region may be cost-saving for R&D performing firms. On the other hand, a firm might be attracted in the agglomerated area because it will find a wider variety of inputs at a lower cost.

  21. R&D is made more difficult to fund as a result of a small domestic market, weakening the development of indigenous technologies and restricting the emergence of high-tech industrial sectors (Briguglio 1995).

  22. There are only few cases of clusters created with adjacent countries, i.e. Malaysia with Indonesia and Singapore.

  23. This is due not only to economies of scale constraints, but also to a limited labour supply.

  24. In particular, trade often happens with adjacent states, with the main ferry terminals.

  25. As Armstrong and Read (2004a) point out, many small states such as Andorra or the Isle of Man either choose not to have their own currency or to operate with a rigidly fixed exchange rate and guaranteed convertibility with the adjacent large state. Indeed, currency devaluation serves simply to directly drive up the domestic price level, and moreover, import substitution will not occur on any large scale since the wholly domestic sector from which resources would need to be freed up is so small.

  26. In the case of archipelagoes, because of heterogeneity between islands, benefits related to social capital are likely to be weaker.

  27. The authors also found that neither being an archipelago nor a mountainous territory negatively affects GDP levels. However, states which are remote from global markets or landlocked are shown to have weaker levels of economic performance. The authors do not explain the reason behind such result. Furthermore, they show that the significance of the coefficient associated with being landlocked is not robust to the inclusion of other regressors in the multivariate analysis.

  28. Planistat (2003) identified 286 EU15 islands using other objective criteria: (a) being at least one kilometre from the continent and (b) have no permanent link with the continent.

  29. These policies support the key export sector as soon as things go well, moving to another niche sector when the first one has been exploited.

  30. This is subject to the condition that adequate fiscal policies are implemented.

  31. The authors use a data set where public capital stock is disaggregated by economic macro-sectors (economic infrastructures, HK infrastructures, social infrastructures and housing and by levels of government.

  32. Ascari and Di Cosmo (2005) and Aiello and Scoppa (2000) investigate TFP determinants in Italian regions. They eventually found that endowment of infrastructures, structure and development of the financial system, enforcement of property rights and crime rates, level of public intervention are the main determinants of TFP differences across Italian regions.

  33. The ADE report (2009) identifies three types of governance arrangements to deal with island problems: (1) high degree of political autonomy, (2) local government with no overlap with the mainland and (3) local government areas shared with the mainland.

References

  • ADE (2012) Study on the relevance and the effectiveness of ERDF and cohesion fund support to regions with specific geographical features—islands, mountainous and sparsely populated areas. Final report, vol. 1. Report prepared by ADE at the request of the European commission. http://ec.europa.eu/regional_policy/sources/docgener/evaluation/pdf/eval2007/geographical_final1.pdf

  • Adrianto L, Matsuda Y (2004) Study on assessing economic vulnerability of small island regions. Environ Dev Sustain 6(3):317–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiello F, Scoppa V (2000) Uneven regional development in Italy: explaining differences in productivity levels. Giornale degli Economisti 59(2):270–298

  • Armstrong, HW, Ballas D, Staines A (2006) A comparative analysis of the economic performance of Greek and British small Islands. In: Paper presented at the 36th regional science association international (British and Irish Section) conference, Jersey, Channel Islands, 16–18 August 2006

  • Armstrong HW, Read R (1995) Western European micro-states and EU autonomous regions: the advantages of size and sovereignty. World Dev 23:1229–1245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong HW, Read R (2000) Comparing the economic performance of dependent territories and sovereign micro-states. Econ Dev Cult Change 48:285–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong HW, Read R (2002) The phantom of liberty?. Economic growth and the vulnerability of small states. J Int Dev 14(3):435–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong HW, Read R (2004a) Insularity, remoteness, mountains and archipelagos: a combination of challenges facing small states?. In: Paper presented for the regional studies association conference Europe at the margins: EU Regional Policy, Peripherality and Rurality, University of Angers

  • Armstrong HW, Read R (2004b) The economic performance of small states and islands: The Importance of Geography, paper presented at Island of the world VIII International Conference “Changing Islands—Changing Worlds”, Kinmen Island (Quemoy), Taiwan, 1–7 November 2004

  • Armstrong HW, de Kervenoael RJ, Li X, Read R (1996) The economic performance of micro-states. Report for the UK ODA (DfID)

  • Armstrong HW, de Kervenoael RJ, Li X, Read R (1998) A comparison of the economic performance of different micro-states and between micro-states and larger countries. World Dev 26:639–656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ascari G, Di Cosmo V (2005). Determinants of total factor productivity in the Italian regions, Sci Reg 4(2):27–50

  • Ashoff G (1989) Economic and industrial development options for small third world countries, occasional paper No 91. German Development Institute, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkins JP, Easter CD, Mazzi S (2000) A commonwealth vulnerability index for developing countries: The position of small states. Economic Paper No. 40, Commonwealth Secretariat, Londons

  • Baldacchino G (2004) The impact of bridges and other “fixed links” on island communities: when small islands are connected to Mainlands. Islands of the World VIII, changing islands–changing worlds: proceedings (1), Kinmen, Taiwan & International Small Islands Studies Association, 99–110

  • Baldacchino G (2006) Small Islands versus big cities: lessons in the political economy of regional development From the world’s small islands. J Technol Transf 31(1):91–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertram G, Karagedikli XX (2004) Are Pacific economies converging or diverging? In: Poot J (ed) On the edge of the global economy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohme K, Doucet P, Komornicki T, Zaucha J, Światek D (2011) How to strengthen the territorial dimension of ‘Europe 2020’ and the EU Cohesion Policy. Report based on the territorial agenda 2020, prepared at the request of the Polish Presidency of the Council of the European Union. Warsaw. http://www.mrr.gov.pl/rozwoj_regionalny/Prezydencja/Documents/Background_report_territorial_dimension_of_EU2020_CP.pdf

  • Borgatti L (2007) Pacific Islands’ Bilateral Trade The Role of Remoteness and of Transport Costs, United Nations University, World Institute for Development Economic Research, Research Paper No. 2007/21

  • Briguglio L (1995) Small island developing states and their economic vulnerabilities. World Dev 23:1615–1632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bronzini R, Piselli P (2009) Determinants of long-run regional productivity with geographical spillovers: the role of R&D, human capital and public infrastructure. Reg Sci Urban Econ 39(2):187–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunello G, Lupi C, Ordine P (2001) Widening differences in Italian regional unemployment. Labour Economics 8:103–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CEC (1994) Eurostat: portrait of the islands. Office of the Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerina F, Pigliaru F (2007) Agglomeration and growth in NEG: a critical assessment. In: Fingleton B (ed) New Directions in Economic Geography, chap. 5

  • D’Acunto S, Destefanis S, Musella M (2004) Exports, supply constraints and growth: an investigation using regional data. Int Rev Appl Econ 18(2):167–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Monte A, Giannola A (1997) Istituzioni economiche e Mezzogiorno. Nuova Italia Scientifica, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Liberto A, Symons J (1998) Human capital stocks and the development of Italian regions: a panel approach, Crenos WP No. 98-4

  • Diani M (2004) How associations matter. An empirical assessment of the social capital-trust-voluntary action link, in investigating social capital. In: Prakash S, Selle P (eds) Comparative perspectives on civil society, participation, and governance. Sage, New Delhi, pp 137–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimou M (2006) Insularity and urban hierarchies: the case of la Reunion, University of La Reunion, CERESUR, mimeo

  • Dolman AJ (1985) Paradise lost? The past performance and future prospects of small island developing countries. In: Dommen EC, Hein PL (eds) States, microstates and islands. Croom Helm, London, pp 40–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Doz YL, Hamel G (1998) Alliance advantage: the art of creating value through partnering. Harvard Business School Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Elsass PM, Viega JF (1994) Acculturation in acquired organizations: a force-field perspective. Hum Relat 47(4):431–453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ESPON (2010) The development of the islands—European islands and cohesion policy (EUROISLANDS), interim report v.3

  • Eurisles (1998) Regional disparities: statistical indicators linked to insularity and ultra-Peripherality, Summary report

  • EURISLES (2002) Off the coast of Europe: European construction and the problem of the islands, Study undertaken by EURISLES on the initiative of the Islands Commission of CPMR

  • EUROMONTANA (2009) The green paper on territorial cohesion ‘turning territorial diversity into strength’-Response to consultation. http://ec.europa.eu/regional_policy/archive/consultation/terco/pdf/4_organisation/114_euromontana_en.pdf

  • Europe Planistat (2002) Analyse des régions insulaires de l’Union Européenne (Survey of insular regions of the EU). In Interreg Project, DG Regio, Brussels, European Commission

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J, Verpagen B, Caniels MCJ (1997) Technology gaps. Growth Unempl Across European Reg Reg Stud 31(5):457–466

    Google Scholar 

  • Faini R (1999) Trade unions and regional development. Eur Econ Rev 43:457–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faini R, Galli G, Giannini C (1993) Finance and development: the case of southern Italy. In: Giovannini A (ed) Finance and development: issues and experience. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gloersen E, Michelet JF, Corbineau C, Giraut F, Price MF, Borowski D, Schuiling R (2012) GEOSPECS-European perspectives on specific types of territories, ESPON programme

  • Hache JD (1987) The island question: problems and prospects. Ekistics 323(324):88–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Geography and trade. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1998) What’s new about economic geography? Oxf Rev Econ Policy 14:7–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Venables AJ (1995) Globalization and the inequality of nations. Q J Econ 110(4):857–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lodde S (2000) Education and growth: some disaggregate evidence from the Italian regions. RISEC Int Rev Econ Bus 47:267–293

    Google Scholar 

  • Marrocu E, Paci R (2010) The effects of public capital on the productivity of the Italian regions. Appl Econ 42(8):989–1002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ, Ottaviano GI (2008) Market size, trade, and productivity. Rev Econ Stud 75(1):295–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moncada S, Camilleri M, Formosa S, Galea R (2010) From incremental to comprehensive: Towards island-friendly European Union policymaking. Isl Stud J 5(1):61–88

    Google Scholar 

  • Musotto F (2007) Report on the islands and natural and economic constraints in the context of the regional policy. A6-0044/2007, European Parliament, Committee on Regional Development. http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?type=REPORT&reference=A6-2007-0044&language=EN

  • Ottaviano G (2003) Regional policy in the global economy: insights from new economic geography. Reg Stud 37(6–7):665–673

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano G, Thisse JF (2005) New economic geography: what about the N? Environ Plan A 37(10):1707–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano GI, Tabuchi T, Thisse JF (2002) Agglomeration and trade revisited. Int Econ Rev 43:409–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paci R, Pigliaru F (2002) Technological diffusion, spatial spillovers and regional convergence in Europe. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg, pp 273–292

    Google Scholar 

  • Paci R, Usai S (2000) Technological enclaves and industrial districts. Anal Reg Distrib Innov Act Eur Reg Stud 34:97–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Planistat (2003) Analysis of the island regions and outermost regions of the European Union: part I: the island regions and territories, Report No. 2000.CE.0.AT.118 to the European Commission, DG Regional Policy, Brussels

  • Read R (2004) The implications of increasing globalization and regionalism for the economic growth of small island states. World Dev 32(2):365–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streeten P (1996) ‘Why small Countries Succeed’, paper presented at the Conference on The Effects of Economic Globalisation and Regional Integration on Small Countries, Nicosia, Mimeo, 4th–6th September, 1996

  • Tinbergen J (1962) Shaping the world economy: suggestions for an international economic policy. Twentieth Century Fund, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Venables AJ (1996) Equilibrium locations of vertically linked industries. Inter Econ Rev 37(2):341–359

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Manuela Deidda.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Deidda, M. Insularity and economic development: a survey. Int Rev Econ 63, 107–128 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-015-0238-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-015-0238-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation