Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How to safeguard world heritage sites? A theoretical model of “cultural responsibility”

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We outline a model in which preservation of UNESCO heritage sites is analyzed as a classical global public good problem where the decentralized Nash equilibrium yields suboptimal contribution vis-à-vis the Social Planner equilibrium. The absence of a Global Social Planner and the need of coordination across different countries for the implementation of the second solution make the Social Planner equilibrium hardly attainable. The same problem arises when trying to enforce symmetric or asymmetric tax deductions in different countries. We analyze the contribution that cultural corporate responsibility can give to the solution of the problem discussing its limits and potential vis-à-vis the other two alternatives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The UNESCO Web site definition highlights the global public good characteristics of heritage sites by saying that “Heritage is our legacy from the past, what we live with today, and what we pass on to future generations. Our cultural and natural heritages are both irreplaceable sources of life and inspiration. Places as unique and diverse as the wilds of East Africa’s Serengeti, the Pyramids of Egypt, the Great Barrier Reef in Australia, and the Baroque cathedrals of Latin America make up our world’s heritage. What makes the concept of World Heritage exceptional is its universal application. World Heritage sites belong to all the peoples of the world, irrespective of the territory on which they are located.” (http://whc.unesco.org/en/about/. Accessed on May 20, 2014).

  2. As is well known in the literature, the problem of free riding leads to underprovision of public goods. Several theoretical papers have analyzed the problem in noncooperative games (Bergstrom et al. 1986; Cornes and Sandler 1986) focusing on the implementation of incentive mechanisms for an efficient allocation of public goods (see, for instance, Clarke 1971; Groves 1973; Groves and Ledyard 1977; Green and Laffont 1979; Laffont 1987; Bagnoli and Lipman 1989; Varian 1994). However, as has been emphasized by this literature, the proposed mechanisms are frequently rather complicated and, as a consequence, difficult to implement (Falkinger et al. 2000). Other works have proposed incentive mechanisms which induce efficient contributions to the public good but whose implementation requires a rather complex and particular refinement of the Nash equilibrium. Other authors (see, for instance, Warr 1982, 1983; Andreoni and Bergstrom 1996; Falkinger 1994, 1996) devised mechanisms based on tax subsidy schemes in which a central authority, the government, tries to increase contributions to the public good. These mechanisms however require perfect information about private characteristics.

  3. The relevance of this problem is evidenced by the World Monuments Fund (WMF)’s announcement of the launch of a 2-year advocacy for 67 sites in 41 countries. Created in 1996, the WMF has concentrated on giving national and international exposure to cultural heritage sites that are at risk. To mention just one specific example on July 3, 2012. “The UN World Heritage Committee has condemned the destruction of sites in Mali, including the fabled city of Timbuktu, and decided on measures to help the West African country protect its heritage, including the creation of a special fund to help it conserve its cultural heritage. UNESCO agreed to help the Government of Mali in reinforcing protection for all of its cultural properties and raise awareness in neighboring countries and among the international community of the situation to help fight the illicit trade in cultural artifacts” (http://www.un.org/apps/news/story.asp?NewsID=42387). As is clear from this example, war and conflicts (beyond poverty) may as well play an important role in deterioration, but, also in these cases, economic resources for protection, restoration after war destruction, education, and local economic development are urgently needed to tackle the problem.

  4. The expression was originally formulated by Besley and Gathak (2001). The literature on corporate social responsibility produced in the last decades several theoretical contributions. See among others, Arora and Gangopadhyay (1995), Bagnoli and Watts (2003), Glazer et al. (2010), Becchetti et al. (2011, 2014) and Reinstein and Song (2012).

  5. The Nielsen multicountry survey on the “Globally Conscious Consumer” (28,000 interviews in 56 countries, downloadable at http://www.nielsen.com/us/en/newswire/2012/the-global-socially-conscious-consumer.html) identifies an average share of 46 % respondents willing to pay more for social and environmental characteristics of the products. Even though the contingent evaluation literature tells us that figures of virtual willingness to pay are upward biased (Carson et al. 2001), observed market shares of ethically responsible products (fair trade or ethical investment funds) tell us that the actual share is nonetheless quite relevant.

  6. For a recent survey on CSR, see Kitzmueller and Shimshack (2012), Hoi et al. (2013) and Dhaliwal et al. (2012).

  7. KPMG International Survey of Corporate Responsibility Reporting documents that CSR reporting was adopted by 90 % of Japanese companies, 71 % of UK companies, and 32 % of US companies in 2005, up to involve 95 % of the 250 largest companies in the world in 2011 (KPMG Global Sustainability Services, 2005 and 2011, both available at the KPMG Web site at http://www.kpmg.com). The Corporate Social Responsibility Report (ICCA 2010, downloadable at: iccaworld.com/dcps/doc.cfm?docid=1246) documents that a separate CSR department was created by 31 % of the top 500 Fortune companies.

  8. Satisfaction of a wider range of stakeholders in CSR entails certain costs which may however be compensated by potential benefits. Among the latter, we mention minimization of conflicts with stakeholders (Minor and Morgan 2011), higher workers productivity due to efficiency wage (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984), turnover and intrinsic motivation mechanisms (Deci 1975), innovation in waste/emission management which anticipates more restrictive regulation and creates technological leadership, consumer surplus extraction due to the willingness to pay for social and environmental responsibility of concerned consumers. This last point will be the focus of our analysis. Empirical findings on the nexus between CSR and corporate performance investigated in different countries and sample periods reflect this uncertain balance between CSR gains and costs. Some of them document a positive nexus (Hart and Ahuja 1996; Feldman et al. 1996; Russo and Fouts 1997; Butz and Plattner 1999; Dowell et al. 2000; Konar and Cohen 2001; King and Lenox 2001; Hibiki and Welch 2003; Becchetti et al. 2008; Margolis et al. 2007; Baron 2009), others document a negative relationship (see, for instance, Cordeiro and Sarkis 1997; Wright and Ferris 1997; Wagner et al. 2001), while a third group of contributions documents the absence of significant differences between SR and conventional firms (McWilliams and Siegel 2000).

  9. A further problem is that concrete occasions for contributing to the preservation of heritage sites in distant countries (such as donation to international NGOs taking care of the issue, i.e., through collection of coins in Airports) may be very limited. For a discussion of the general issue of heterogeneous valuations of global public goods, see Kaul et al. (2003).

  10. The case of foreigners who care for cultural and natural heritage sites in other countries is not at all uncommon. The same activity and financing from private sources of private and governmental institutions such as the World Monuments Fund described in footnote 3 confirm it. From a theoretical point of view, the situation envisaged here with free riding of the low-income country is clearly a case in which “the exploitation of the great” in the provision of international public goods holds (Boadway and Hayashi 1999).

  11. Tax deductions of this kind exist in several countries. For an overview of the tax policies from a macro and comparative perspective by country, number and nature of tax benefits, see for instance The Ernst and Young international survey 2009, available at http://www.forum-avignon.org.

  12. It is important to remark that the two solutions have quite different characteristics. In the first case, private donations are enhanced with tax advantages, separately decided in the two countries, and they increase disposable income for the consumption of the private good. In the second case, a global benevolent planner (an international authority) decides how much individuals in the two countries must donate for the global public good.

  13. What we assume in this section is not unjustified by empirical evidence. Many corporations engage actively in restoration of monuments and consider it as part of their marketing strategies. Their interest for arts and her safeguard should therefore be explained not only in terms of firms’ philanthropic attitudes but also in a traditional model of profit maximization. According to a recent survey in the year 2008(http://www.tafterjournal.it/2008/07/25/limpresa-incontra-arte-e-cultura) on 63 firms engaged and active in the arts and culture of the city of Montreal, most of them declared they had significant reputational gains from their support to the arts and culture sector. One of the most interesting examples from this point of view is that of companies, such as those working in the tourism industry, which can exploit complementarities between the private and the public good contribution sold in their (private/public good) bundle. An example is Expedia, Inc., the world’s leading online travel company which created the partnership of the World Heritage Alliance with the UNESCO World Heritage Centre. The World Heritage Alliance is currently involved in the protection of 20 World Heritage sites in seven countries including Mexico, Costa Rica, Belize, Jordan, Dominica, Ecuador, and the USA. Over the last four years, the Alliance has expanded to include 59 corporate members and partners, such as the Fairmont Hotels and Resorts and Mandarin Oriental, which contribute with grants, stimulate them on behalf of responsible tourists and promote environmental, cultural, and social responsibility, and support local community tourism initiatives at World Heritage sites. Another example of mutually beneficial partnership between private sector and cultural heritage preservation is the World Monuments Fund’s long-term project at Preah Khan, a temple in Cambodia, sponsored by the American Express Company (Starr 2013). The latter supported a risky project which has been paid off in the long run in term contributing to corporate philanthropic reputation. Other examples of profitable partnerships between culturally responsible companies and heritage protection may be found in Labadi and Long (2010) who refer to the cases of the French Bank Credit Agricole which invested 1.4 million Euros for the reopening and restauration of the historical rooms of the Cheateau of the Fontaneibleau and the group Vinci which invested 12 millions for the restauration of the rooms of mirrors at the Cheateau of Versailles in France. Corporate cultural responsibility may as well take other forms: IBM created virtual sites devoted to the UNESCO heritage site, while, more traditionally, several tour operators, such as EF Tours and JET Tours, promote responsible tourism, asking their clients to donate for the conservation of the visited heritage site (http://business.un.org/en/entities/36).

  14. More details on this result are available upon request.

References

  • Andreoni J, Bergstrom TC (1996) Do government subsidies increase the private supply of public goods? Public Choice 88:295–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arce M, Daniel G, Sandler T (2001) Transnational public goods: strategies and institutions. Eur J Polit Econ 17(3):493–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arezki R, Cherif R, Piotrowski J (2009) Tourism specialization and economic development: evidence from the UNESCO world heritage list. IMF working paper 176

  • Arora S, Gangopadhyay S (1995) Toward a theoretical model of voluntary overcompliance. J Econ Behav Organ 28:289–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli M, Lipman B (1989) Provision of public goods: fully implementing the core through private contributions. Rev Econ Stud 56(4):583–601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli M, Watts SG (2003) Selling to socially responsible consumers: competition and the private provision of public goods. J Econ Manag Strategy 12(3):419–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron DP (2009) A positive theory of moral management, social pressure, and corporate social performance. J Econ Manag Strategy 18(1):7–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti L, Giacomo SD, Pinnacchio D (2008) Corporate social responsibility and corporate performance: evidence from a panel of us listed companies. Appl Econ 40(5):541–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti L, Federico G, Solferino N (2011) What to do in globalised economies if global governance is missing? The vicarious role of competition in social responsibility, competition in social responsibility. Int Rev Econ 58(2):185–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti L, Palestini A, Solferino N, Tessitore ME (2014) The socially responsible choice in a duopolistic market: a dynamic model of ethical product differentiation. Econ Model 43:114–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benabou R, Tirole J (2010) Individual and corporate social responsibility. Economica 77(305):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertacchini E, Dalle Nogare C (2014) Public provision vs. outsourcing of cultural services: evidence from Italian cities. Eur J Polit Econ 35:168–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertacchini E, Saccone D, Santagata W (2009) A political economy analysis of world heritage listing. mimeo, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Gathak M (2001) Government versus private ownership of public goods. Q J Econ 16(4):1343–1372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom TC, Blume L, Varian H (1986) On the private provision of public goods. J Public Econ 29:25–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway R, Hayashi M (1999) Country size and the voluntary provision of international public goods. Eur J Polit Econ 15(4):619–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butz C, Plattner A (1999) Nachhaltige Aktienanlagen: Eine Analyse der Rendite in Abhangigkeit von Umwelt und Sozialkriterien (Sustainable share investments: an analysis of returns depending on environmental and social criteria). Sarasin Sustainable Investment/Bank Sarasin, Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson RT, Flores NE, Meade NF (2001) Contingent valuation: controversies and evidence. Environ Resour Econ 19:173–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chengyu L (2011) Matching offer in the provision of public goods. Duke Journal of Economics, vol VIII, Spring

  • Clarke EH (1971) Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice 11(2):17–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordeiro JJ, Sarkis J (1997) Environmental proactivism and firm performance: evidence from security analyst earnings forecasts. Bus Strategy Environ 6(2):104–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes RC, Sandler T (1986) The theory of externalities, public goods, and club, goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Deci EL (1975) Intrinsic motivation. Plenum, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dhaliwal DS, Radhakrishnan S, Tsang A, Yang GY (2012) Nonfinancial disclosure and analyst forecast accuracy: international evidence on corporate social responsibility disclosure. Account Rev 87(3):723–759

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dowell G, Hart S, Yeung B (2000) Do corporate global environmental standards create or destroy value? Manag Sci 46(8):1059–1074

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkinger J (1994) The private provision of public goods when the relative size of contributions matters. Finanzarchiv 51(3):358–371

    Google Scholar 

  • Falkinger J (1996) Efficient private provision of public goods by rewarding deviations from average. J Public Econ 62(3):413–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkinger J, Fehr E, Gachter S, Winter-Ebmer R (2000) A simple mechanism for the efficient provision of public goods: experimental evidence. Am Econ Rev 90(1):247–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman SJ, Soyka PA, Ameer P (1996) Does improving a firm’s environmental management system and environmental performance result in a higher stock price? J Invest 6:87–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Pamini P (2009) Making world heritage truly global: the culture certificate scheme. Working paper no. 419, Institute for Empirical research in Economics, University of Zurich, June

  • Furubotn EG, Pejovich S (1976) The long-run analysis of the labor-managed firm. Am Econ Rev 66:104–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Glazer A, Kanniainen V, Poutvaara P (2010) Firms’ ethics, consumer boycotts, and signalling. Eur J Polit Econ 26(3):340–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groves T (1973) Incentives in teams. Econometrica 41(4):617–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groves T, Ledyard J (1977) Optimal allocation of public goods: a solution to the free rider’ problem. Econometrica 45(4):783–809

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green JR, Laffont J-J (1979) Incentives in public decision making. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Guccio C, Mazza I (2014) On the political determinants of the allocation of funds to heritage authorities. Eur J Polit Econ 34:18–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart S, Ahuja G (1996) Does it pay to be green? An empirical examination of the relationship between emission reduction and firm performance. Bus Strategy Environ 5:30–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibiki A, Welch E (2003) An institutional framework for analysis of voluntary policy: the case of voluntary environmental agreements in Kita Kyushu, Japan. J Environ Plan Manag 46(4):523–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman A (2009) Public finance and public policy: responsibilities and limitations of government, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hoi CK, Wu Q, Zhang H (2013) Is corporate social responsibility (CSR) associated with tax avoidance? Evidence from irresponsible CSR activities. Account Rev 6(17):2025–2059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaul I, Conceicao P, Le Goulven K, Mendoza RU (2003) Providing global public goods: managing globalization. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • King A, Lenox M (2001) Does it really pay to be green? An empirical study of firm environmental and financial performance. J Ind Ecol 5(1):105–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitzmueller M, Shimshack J (2012) Economic perspectives on corporate social responsibility. J Econ Lit 50(1):51–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konar S, Cohen MA (2001) Does the market value environmental performance? Rev Econ Stat 83(2):281–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Labadi S, Long C (2010) Heritage and globalisation. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J-J (1987) Incentives and the allocation of public goods. In: Auerbach AJ, Feldstein M (eds) Handbook of public economics, vol 2. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 537–569

    Google Scholar 

  • Margolis J, Elfenbein H, Walsh J (2007) Does it pay to be good? A meta-analysis and redirection of research on the relationship between corporate social and financial performance. Working paper, http://stakeholder.bu.edu/2007/Docs/Walsh

  • McWilliams A, Siegel D (2000) Corporate social responsibility and financial performance: correlation or misspecification? Strateg Manag J 21(5):603–609

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minor D, Morgan J (2011) CSR as reputation insurance. Primum non nocere. Calif Manag Rev 53(3)

  • Reinstein D, Song J (2012) Efficient consumer altruism and fair trade products. J Econ Manag Strategy 21(1):213–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Russo M, Fouts F (1997) A resource-based perspective on corporate environmental performance and profitability. Acad Manag J 40:534–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandler T (2004) Global collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C, Stiglitz JE (1984) Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. Am Econ Rev 74(3):433–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Starr F (2013) Corporate responsibility for cultural heritage: conservation, sustainable development, and corporate reputation, vol 4. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1994) Sequential contributions to public goods. J Public Econ 53(2):165–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner M, Schaltegger S, Wehrmeyer W (2001) The relationship between the environmental and economic performance of firms. Greener Manag Int 34:95–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Ward B (1958) The firm in Illyria: market syndicalism. Am Econ Rev 48:566–589

    Google Scholar 

  • Warr PG (1982) Pareto optimal redistribution and private charity. J Public Econ 19(1):131–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warr PG (1983) The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Econ Lett 13(3):207–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright P, Ferris S (1997) Agency conflict and corporate strategy: the effect of divestment on corporate value. Strateg Manag J 18:77–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Leonardo Becchetti.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Becchetti, L., Solferino, N. & Tessitore, M.E. How to safeguard world heritage sites? A theoretical model of “cultural responsibility”. Int Rev Econ 62, 223–248 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-015-0237-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-015-0237-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation