Skip to main content
Log in

Bequest motives and household money demand

  • Published:
Journal of Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The bequest motive is an important motive determining intergenerational transfers of income, saving, and money. However, it has received little or no attention from past studies on money demand. This study utilizes panel data to show that the bequest motive is positively related to money demand and interacts with the life-cycle motive during various stages of an individual’s life. Householders with bequest motives are more likely to transfer a greater proportion of their permanent incomes to monetary assets than those without bequest motives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The study by Browning and Lusardi (1996) contains an excellent survey of the literature on household life-cycle savings, while a survey of the literature on bequest motives and inheritance is provided by Masson and Pestieau (1997).

  2. It should be noted that in his restatement of the quantity theory of money Friedman (1956) did not raise any objection to the Keynesian notion that money-holders demand money partly from the transactions motive and partly from the precautionary, speculative, or asset motive. Indeed, Friedman’s concept of money as a “temporary abode of purchasing power” may be viewed as the monetarist counterpart of the Keynesian precautionary money demand, as depicted in the buffer stock model of money demand.

  3. General Theory, pp. 107–109, 166.

  4. SIPP samples in each wave are usually divided into four rotation groups of similar sizes and from each rotation group four reference months of data are collected. In the interview assigned for each rotation, respondents are asked to provide information for the previous four months or reference periods. The last day of the reference period refers to the last day of the most recent month prior to the interview. In this study, regression results are generated by data obtained from the fourth reference month of waves 3, 6, and 9. The 2001 SIPP documents and data files can be obtained from the Census Bureau’s web site: <www.sipp.census.gov/sipp/>.

  5. As shown by Bernheim et al (1985), the bequest motive of a householder may not be altruistic if there exists an exchange of services among family members.

  6. Three waves of data are used to capture the existence of a bequest motive so that those with a bequest motive but could not afford the premiums in one or two waves can be included in the analysis. Those who had life insurances prior to wave 3 but were no longer covered in waves 3, 6, or 9 are given a value of zero because of the lack of historical data. Similarly, those who did not have life insurances in waves 3, 6, and 9 but had life insurances thereafter are given a value of zero because of data limitations.

  7. The 2001 SIPP panel only contains information on the gross return and the gross amount of these assets held at financial institutions. As a result, the rate of return on each of these assets can not be dis-aggregated for further analysis.

  8. As pointed out by Browning and Lusardi, although age and age square are often included in past studies to capture the life-cycle motive, life-cycle choices about education, marriage, and childbearing are also inseparable parts of the life-cycle framework.

  9. Types of occupation, housing tenure status, and regional differences are included as instrumental variables, primarily because, after repeated trials, they appear to be correlated with the endogenous variables, especially with permanent income. Additionally when the number of instrumental variables is equal to or a subset of the number of demographic variables representing the life-cycle motive in the money demand equation, the problem of multi-collinearity becomes serious and renders most parametric estimates meaningless. Life insurance coverage is not used as an instrumental variable so that the effect of multi-collinearity on the coefficient of the bequest motive can be minimized.

  10. The sign of the bequest motive is negative, probably because households covered by life insurances had to pay premiums, whereas households without life insurance coverage did not have to make such payments.

References

  • Baba Y, Hendry DF, Starr RM (1992) The demand for M1 in the USA 1960–1988. Rev Econ Stud 59:25–61. doi:10.2307/2297924

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball L (2001) Another look at long-run money demand. J Monet Econ 47:31–44. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(00)00043-X

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett WA (1980) Economic monetary aggregates: an application of aggregation and index number theory. J Econom 14:11–48. doi:10.1016/0304-4076(80)90070-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett WA, Offenbacher EK, Spindt PA (1984) The new divisia monetary aggregates. J Polit Econ 96:1049–1085. doi:10.1086/261275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (1952) The transactions demand for cash: an inventory-theoretic approach. Q J Econ 66:545–556. doi:10.2307/1882104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1974) A theory of social interaction. J Polit Econ 82:1063–1093. doi:10.1086/260265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Sheleifer A, Summers LH (1985) The strategic bequest motive. J Polit Econ 93:1045–1076. doi:10.1086/261351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Lusardi A (1996) Household saving: micro theories and micro facts. J Econ Lit XXXIV:1797–1855

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr J, Darby M (1981) The role of money supply shocks in the short-run demand for money. J Monet Econ 8:183–199. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(81)90024-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley TF, LeRoy SF (1981) Identification and estimation of money demand. Am Econ Rev 71:825–844

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson P (1965) Keynes’s finance motive. Oxf Econ Pap 17:47–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel RF, Granger CWJ (1987) Cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica 55:251–276. doi:10.2307/1913236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel J, Jovanovic B (1980) On transactions and precautionary demand for money. Q J Econ XCV:25–43. doi:10.2307/1885347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1956) The quantity theory of money: a restatement. In: Friedman M (ed) Studies in the quantity theory of money. Chicago University Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman BM, Kuttner KN (1992) Money, income, prices, and interest rates. Am Econ Rev 82:472–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldfeld SM (1973) The demand for money revisited. B Papers Econ Act 3:577–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorman WM (1953) Community preference fields. Econometrica 21:63–80. doi:10.2307/1906943

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hafer RW, Jansen DW (1991) The demand for money in the United States: evidence from cointegration tests. J Money Credit Bank 23:155–168. doi:10.2307/1992774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman DL, Rasche RH (1991) Long-run income and interest elasticities of money demand in the United States. Rev Econ Stat 73:665–674. doi:10.2307/2109405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman DL, Rasche RH, Tieslau MA (1995) The stability of long-run money demand in five industrial countries. J Mon Econ 35:317–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1988) Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J Econ Dyn Control 12:231–254. doi:10.1016/0165-1889(88)90041-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd JP, Scadding JL (1982) The search for a stable money demand function: survey of the post-1973 literature. J Econ Lit 20:993–1023

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest, and money. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1937) Alternative theories of the rate of interest. Econ J 47:241–252. doi:10.2307/2225525

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreinin ME (1961) Analysis of liquid asset ownership. Rev Econ Stat 43:76–80. doi:10.2307/1926839

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laidler D (1977) The demand for money: theory and evidence, 2nd edn. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee TH (1964) Income, wealth, and the demand for money: some evidence from cross-section data. J Am Stat Assoc 46–62

  • Lydall FH (1958) Income, assets, and the demand for money. Rev Econ Stat 40:1–14. doi:10.2307/1926475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mark NC, Sul D (2003) Cointegration vector estimation by panel DOLS and long-run money demand. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 65:655–680. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0084.2003.00066.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masson A, Pestieau P (1997) Bequest motives and models of inheritance: a survey of the literature. In: Erreygers G, Vandevelde T (eds) Is inheritance legitimate? Ethical and economic aspects of wealth transfers. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller SM (1991) Monetary dynamics: an application of cointegration and error-correction modelling. J Money Credit Bank 28:365–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller M, Orr D (1966) A model of the demand for money by firms. Q J Econ LXXIX:413–435. doi:10.2307/1880728

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Brumberg R (1954) Utility analysis and the consumption function: an interpretation of the cross-section Data. In: Kurihara K (ed) Post-Keynesian economics. Butgers U. Press, New Brunswick. NJ, pp 388–436

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesek BP (1963) Determinants of the demand for money. Rev Econ Stat 45:419–424. doi:10.2307/1927926

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarno L, Taylor MP, Peel DA (2003) Nonlinear equilibrium correction in US real money balances, 1869–1997. J Money Credit Bank 35:787–797. doi:10.1353/mcb.2003.0039

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH (1987) Asymptotic properties of least squares estimators of cointegrating vectors. Econometrica 55:1035–1056. doi:10.2307/1911260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (1993) A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors in higher order integrated systems. Econometrica 61:783–820. doi:10.2307/2951763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1956) The interest elasticity of the transactions demand for cash. Rev Econ Stat 38:241–247. doi:10.2307/1925776

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1958) Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Rev Econ Stud 25:65–86. doi:10.2307/2296205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsiang SC (1956) Liquidity preference and loanable funds theories, multiplier and velocity analysis: a synthesis. Am Econ Rev XLVI:539–564

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts H, Tobin J (1960) Consumer expenditures and the capital account. Proc of the Conf on Con and Saving, Vol. 2, Edited by Irwing and Robert Jones, Philadelphia

  • Whalen E (1966) A rationalization of the precautionary demand for cash. Q J Econ LXXX:314–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

The author is indebted to an anonymous referee for many valuable comments. The views expressed here are those of the author and do not reflect those of the U. S. Commerce Department or the Census Bureau.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jan Tin.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Tin, J. Bequest motives and household money demand. J Econ Finan 34, 269–283 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-009-9079-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-009-9079-1

Keywords

JEL

Navigation