Skip to main content
Log in

Economics, Democracy, and the Distribution of Capital Ownership

  • Published:
Forum for Social Economics

Abstract

This article holds that widespread, practical access to capital acquisition is essential for sustainable widespread economic prosperity and democracy. The founders of the U.S.A. agreed that sustainable democracy required widespread ownership of land to provide a viable earning capacity sufficient to support robust participation in democratic government. The importance of widespread land ownership to individual prosperity and sustainable democracy was supported not only by the prevailing philosophical views of property, it was also apparent to the common man and woman. Compared to Europe, America offered widespread access to land ownership, higher wages, better work conditions, cheaper staples and greater individual freedom, equal opportunity, prosperity, and political participation. This conviction that widespread access to ownership is a necessary condition for widespread prosperity and sustainable democracy continued throughout most of the nineteenth century, but today public discourse reveals virtually no trace of this once universally held opinion. This article suggests that the disappearance of this conviction can be traced to an erroneous view shaped by neoclassical economics and Keynesian economics. According to this view, (1) the disappearance of the American frontier and industrialization made the goal of widespread capital ownership either impractical or of little or no economic significance and (2) by way of technological advance, sufficient earning capacity and consumer demand to promote growth and sustain democracy can be achieved, without widespread ownership, primarily through jobs and welfare. Although differing in many respects, both mainstream schools, along with Adam Smith’s classical economics, share one common but unstated economic assumption: the broader distribution of capital acquisition (in itself) has no fundamental relationship to the fuller employment of people and capital, the broader distribution of greater individual earning capacity, and growth. Contemporary thinking, shaped by these economic schools, also tacitly assumes that widespread capital ownership is not essential for the sustainable individual earning capacity needed to support robust democracy. This erroneous “ownership-neutrality assumption” (1) contradicts both the views of America’s founders and the colonial experience, and (2) provides theoretical justification for structuring capital markets and capital acquisition transactions to unfairly and dysfunctionally favor existing owners at the expense of broader ownership distribution, more widely shared prosperity, greater efficiency, ecologically friendly growth, and a vital democracy. America’s conscientious founders would be shocked by the diminished importance of the distribution of ownership in the mainstream analysis of prices, efficiency, production, growth, and democracy. Rather than enhancing democracy, they would view the “ownership-neutrality assumption” of mainstream economics as contributing to its deterioration and corruption. They would openly search for economic analysis built on an alternate assumption more consistent with their understanding of the requisite conditions for sustainable democracy. This article advances an economic analysis that suspends the ownership-neutrality assumption, replaces it with a “broader-ownership-growth assumption,” and suggests a voluntary market strategy for substantially broadening capital ownership, enhancing individual earning capacity, and providing the widespread economic prosperity needed for robust democracy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Conlin (1984) p 48.

  2. Brown (1935,1955) pp. 1–20, 37, Perkins (1988).

  3. See e,g., Matson (2006) and McClusker and Menard (1985).

  4. http://www.russell.com/Indexes/data/US_Equity/Russell_US_equity_indexes.asp

  5. Wolff (1995, 2011). These statistics include all the holdings in pension, stock ownership and profit sharing plans.

  6. Smith (1937) p. 344–345.

  7. “It is preferable to regard labour, including of course, the personal services of the entrepreneur and his assistants, as the sole factor of production, operating in given environment of technique, natural resources, capital equipment and effective demand. This is why we have been able to take labour as the sole physical unit which we require in our economic system, apart from units of money and of time.” Keynes (1936) pp. 213–214.

  8. Ashford (2010). The economic approach discussed in this reference is based on the work of Louis Kelso. See the Kelso Institute: <<http://www.kelsoinstitute.org>>.

References

  • Ashford, R. (2010). Broadening the right to acquire capital with the earnings of capital: the missing link to sustainable economic recovery and growth. Forum for Social-Economics, 37, 89–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brealey, R. A., Myers, S. C., & Allen, F. (2004). Principles of corporate finance Chapter 14, pp. 561–563 3rd edition.

  • Brown, R. E. (1935, 1955). Middle class democracy and the revolution in Massachusetts 1691–1780, pp. 1–20, 37. Ithica, NY: Cornell University Press.

  • Conlin, J. R. (1984). The morrow book of quotations in American history. New York: William Morrow and Company, Inc. p 48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1936). General theory of employment, interest and money (pp. 213–214). Harcourt, Brace & World, Inc.

  • Korff, J. D. (2008). Reviving the forgotten American dream. Penn-State Law Review, 113, 417–460.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matson, C. (2006). The economy of early America: Historical perspectives and new directions. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McClusker, J. J., & Menard, R. R. (1985). The economy of British America, 1607–1789. Chapel Hill and London: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perkins, E. J. (1988). The economy of colonial America (2nd ed.). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776, 1937). Wealth of nations (pp. 345–347). Modern Library Edition, Random House. New York 1937.

  • The Kelso Institute. (2011). http://www.kelsoinstitute.org. Accessed 20 Sept 2011.

  • Wolff, E. N. (1995). Top heavy: A study of increasing inequality in America. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolff, E. N. (2011). Recent trends in household wealth in the U.S.: Rising debt and the middle class squeeze. In J. M. Gonzales (Ed.), Economics of wealth in the 21st century (pp. 1–41). Nova Science Publishers, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert Ashford.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ashford, R. Economics, Democracy, and the Distribution of Capital Ownership. For Soc Econ 40, 361–370 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12143-011-9092-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12143-011-9092-y

Keywords

Navigation