Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Reciprocity and Profit Sharing: Is There an Inverse U-shaped Relationship?

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Free-riding potentially limits the effectiveness of profit sharing in motivating workers. While reciprocity can mitigate this problem, it need not be uniformly productive. We show that the probability of receiving profit sharing takes an inverse U-shape as detailed individual survey measures of reciprocity increase. This is consistent with moderate but not extreme reciprocity stimulating productivity. We support one potential causation path by showing that extreme positive (negative) reciprocity is associated with extremely high (low) socializing and among workers receiving profit sharing, an intermediate degree of socializing is associated with the maximum amount of paid and unpaid overtime, a productivity proxy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Kruse (1993) presents his own evidence and reviews earlier studies while Ugarkovic (2007) provides a more recent review. Blasi et al. (2010) present evidence that profit sharing improves worker effort, reduces turnover and increases loyalty to the firm.

  2. See Cornelissen et al. (2010) for a theoretical model.

  3. This statistic is taken from the 2007 Time Wasting Survey conducted by the HRM firm salary.com. In each of the 5 years of the survey, socializing at work has been either the first or second largest source of wasted time.

  4. See Brown and Heywood (2009) for additional evidence that individual performance pay reduces incentives to help on the job.

  5. We focus on male workers as previous research has shown that women are less responsive to profit sharing than men. Other work using the GSOEP suggests that women under profit sharing are often less able to respond to the pressure from co-workers that is generated by profit sharing (Heywood et al. 2005). Moreover, evidence from the U.S. indicates that women are less likely to act against shirking co-workers (Freeman et al. 2004). In line with this previous research, we find no link between reciprocity and profit sharing when we perform our analysis for female workers. While we can only speculate about this result, it may be that the intention to be reciprocal as elicited in the survey and the actual ability to reciprocate differ more for women than for men.

  6. Missing values of the schooling variable have been replaced by the mean value of years of schooling and a dummy variable added indicating the observations with missing values of schooling.

  7. The code is provided by the authors: http://fmwww.bc.edu/repec/bocode/u/utest.ado.

  8. Several studies for Germany suggest that overtime is indeed associated with greater effort and productivity. Schank (2003) finds that establishments using overtime work are more efficient. Bauer and Zimmermann (1999) show that skilled workers do more overtime and Pannenberg (2005) and Anger (2008) demonstrate that workers use overtime to signal ability and motivation.

  9. As discussed in our theoretical development, the sorting into and out of profit sharing jobs reflects both stochastic elements and factors other than reciprocity. While our hypothesis suggests the profit sharing subsample will be disproportionately those of intermediate reciprocity, some variation will remain. Indeed, in both subsamples, there is sufficient variation in the socializing variables (which reflect, in part, reciprocity) so that separate regressions can be performed to examine the link between socializing and productivity. For example, in the profit sharing sample 3 % of workers report not having good relations with co-workers, 20 % report partially good relations and 77 % report completely good relations. Also within the profit sharing sample, 5 % of workers report no friends, 73 % report 1–5 friends, 19 % report 6–10 friends and 3 % report more than 10 friends. While there is sufficient variation to make sensible estimates, it is worth noting that these distributions are more concentrated in the intermediate categories than are those in the sample without profit sharing (available upon request) and that, if anything, the dampening of the variance makes it harder to find the statistical relationships we report.

  10. Heywood and Jirjahn (2002, 2009) confirm that team production is positively associated with profit sharing.

References

  • Adams CP (2006) Optimal team incentives with CES production. Econ Lett 92:143–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altmann S, Dohmen T, Wibral M (2008) Do the reciprocal trust less? Econ Lett 99:454–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anger S (2008) Overtime as a signaling device. Scott J Polit Econ 55:167–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azfar O, Danninger S (2001) Profit sharing, employment stability and wage growth. Ind Labor Relat Rev 54:619–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barron JM, Gjerde KP (1997) Peer pressure in an agency relationship. J Labor Econ 15:234–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer T, Zimmermann K (1999) Overtime work and overtime compensation in Germany. Scott J Polit Econ 46:419–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg J, Dickhaut J, MacCabe K (1995) Trust, reciprocity and social history. Games Econ Behav 10:122–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg S, Carpenter J, Goette L (2009) Performance pay and worker cooperation: evidence from an artefactual field experiment. J Econ Behav Organ 70:458–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger J, Herbertz C, Sliwka D (2011) Incentives and Cooperation in Firms: Field Evidence. IZA Discussion Paper No. 5618, Bonn

  • Blasi JR, Freeman RB, Mackin C, Kruse DL (2010) Creating a bigger pie? The effects of employee ownership, profit sharing, and stock options on workplace performance. In: Kruse D, Freemand RB, Blasi J (eds) Shared capitalism at work: employee ownership, profit and gain sharing, and broad-based stock options. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2003) Homo reciprocans. Nature 415:125–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown M, Heywood JS (2009) Helpless in finance: the cost of helping effort among bank employees. J Lab Res 30:176–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown M, Falk A, Fehr E (2004) Relational contracts and the nature of market interactions. Econometrica 72:747–780

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter J, Seki E (2005) Do Social Preferences Increase Productivity? Field Experimental Evidence from Fisherman in Toyama Bay. IZA Discussion Paper 1697

  • Carpenter J, Bowles S, Gintis H, Hwang S-H (2009) Strong reciprocity and team production: theory and evidence. J Econ Behav Organ 71:221–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case A, Paxton C (2008) Stature and status: height, ability and labor market outcomes. J Polit Econ 116:499–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che Y-K, Yoo S-W (2001) Optimal incentives for teams. Am Econ Rev 91:525–541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornelissen T, Heywood JS, Jirjahn U (2010) Profit Sharing and Reciprocity: Theory and Survey Evidence. Research Papers in Economics No. 4/10, University of Trier

  • Cornelissen T, Heywood JS, Jirjahn U (2011) Performance pay, risk attitudes and job satisfaction. Labour Econ 18:229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Friedman D, Gjerstad S (2007) A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games Econ Behav 59:17–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Friedman D, Sadiraj V (2008) Revealed altruism. Econometrica 76:31–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson R (2006) Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity. Econ Inq 45:199–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curme M, Stefanec N (2007) Worker quality and labor market sorting. Econ Lett 96:202–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U (2008) Representative trust and reciprocity: prevalence and determinants. Econ Inq 46:84–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U (2009) Homo reciprocans: survey evidence on behavioral outcomes. Econ J 119:592–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drago R, Garvey GT (1998) Incentives for helping on the job: theory and evidence. J Labor Econ 16:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drago R, Heywood JS (1995) Choice of payment schemes: Australian establishment data. Ind Relat 34:507–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dur R, Sol J (2010) Social interaction, co-worker altruism, and incentives. Games Econ Behav 69:293–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyaram L, Kamalanabhan TJ (2005) Unearthed: the other side of group cohesiveness. J Soc Sci 10:185–190

    Google Scholar 

  • Encinosa WE, Gaynor M, Rebitzer JB (2007) The sociology of groups and the economics of incentives: theory and evidence on compensation systems. J Econ Behav Organ 62:187–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Fischbacher U (2006) A theory of reciprocity. Games Econ Behav 54:1347–1381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gachter S (2000) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90:980–994

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitzRoy F, Kraft K (1986) Profitability and profit sharing. J Ind Econ 35:113–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitzRoy F, Kraft K (1987) Cooperation, productivity and profit sharing. Q J Econ 102:23–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitzRoy F, Kraft K (1992) Forms of profit sharing and firm performance: theoretical foundations and empirical problems. Kyklos 45:209–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FitzRoy F, Kraft K (1995) On the choice of incentives in firms. J Econ Behav Organ 26:145–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman RB, Kruse DL, Blasi JR (2004) Monitoring colleagues at work: profit sharing, employee ownership, broad-based stock options and workplace performance in the United States. Discussion paper no. 647. Centre for Economic Performance, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman RB, Kruse DL, Blasi JR (2010) Worker responses to shirking under shared capitalism. In: Kruse DL, Freeman RB, Blasi JR (eds) Shared capitalism at work: employee ownership, profit and gain sharing, and broad-based stock options. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 77–103

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gregg PA, Machin SJ (1988) Unions and the incidence of performance linked pay schemes in Britain. Int J Ind Organ 6:91–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grund C, Sliwka D (2010) Evidence on performance pay and risk aversion. Econ Lett 106:8–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heineck G (2005) Up in the skies? The relationship between body height and earnings in Germany. Labour 19:469–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood JS, Jirjahn U (2002) Payment schemes and gender in Germany. Ind Labor Relat Rev 56:44–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood JS, Jirjahn U (2009) Profit sharing and firm size: the role of team production. J Econ Behav Organ 71:246–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood JS, Jirjahn U (2013) Variable pay, industrial relations and foreign ownership: evidence from Germany. Br J Ind Relat. doi:10.1111/bjir.12032

  • Heywood JS, Jirjahn U, Tsertsvadze G (2005) Getting along with colleagues—does profit sharing help or hurt? Kyklos 58:557–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huebler O (1993) Productivity, earnings, and profit sharing—an econometric analysis of alternative models. Empir Econ 18:357–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichniowski C, Shaw K (2003) Beyond incentive pay: insider’ estimates of the value of complementary human resource management practices. J Econ Perspect 17:155–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones D, Pliskin J (1997) Determinants of the incidence of group incentives: evidence from Canada. Can J Econ 30:1027–1045

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kandel E, Lazear E (1992) Peer pressure and partnerships. J Polit Econ 100:801–817

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knez M, Simester D (2001) Firm-wide incentives and mutual monitoring at Continental Airlines. J Labor Econ 19:743–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kruse DL (1993) Profit sharing: does it make a difference? W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo

    Google Scholar 

  • Kruse DL (1996) Why do firms adopt profit sharing and employee ownership plans? Br J Ind Relat 34:515–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lind JT, Mehlum H (2010) With or without u? The appropriate test for a u-shaped relationship. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 72:109–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacLeod B (1988) Equity, efficiency, and incentives in cooperative teams. In: Jones DC, Svenjar J (eds) Advances in the economic analysis of participatory and labor-managed firms, vol 3. JAI Press, Greenwich, pp 5–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Orr SW (2001) The economics of shame in work groups: how mutual monitoring can decrease cooperation in teams. Kyklos 54:49–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oyer P (2004) Why do firms use incentives that have no incentive effects? J Financ 59:1619–1649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pannenberg M (2005) Long-term effects of unpaid overtime. Scott J Polit Econ 52:177–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pannenberg M, Spiess M (2009) GEE estimation of the covariance structure of a bivariate panel data model with an application to wage dynamics and the incidence of profit sharing in West Germany. Adv Stat Anal 93:427–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast C (1999) The provision of incentives in firms. J Econ Lit 37:7–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg J (1994) Human relations in the workplace. J Polit Econ 102:685–717

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schank T (2003) The impact of working time on employment, wages and productivity. BeitrAB 269, Nuremberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Stogdill RM (1972) Group productivity, drive, and cohesiveness. Organ Behav Hum Perform 8:26–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ugarkovic M (2007) Profit sharing and company performance. DUV (Gabler Edition Wissenschaft), Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagemann R, Baker G (1997) Incentives and cooperation: the joint effects on task and reward interdependence on group performance. J Organ Behav 18:139–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner G, Frick J, Schupp J (2007) The German Socio-economic Panel Study: scope, evolution and enhancements. J Appl Soc Sci Stud 127:139–169

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John S. Heywood.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 6 Variable definitions and sample means
Table 7 Correlation coefficients of reciprocity measures and the other explanatory variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cornelissen, T., Heywood, J.S. & Jirjahn, U. Reciprocity and Profit Sharing: Is There an Inverse U-shaped Relationship?. J Labor Res 35, 205–225 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-014-9179-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-014-9179-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation