Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Contracts, Labor Supply and Income Targeting

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In many professions and personal services, a firm offers a contract with either proportional revenue sharing of the worker’s output or a contract with 100% revenue accruing to the worker in exchange for a fixed (debt) payment. Contingent on the contract, the worker chooses the mechanism to achieve the desired level of productivity. A higher revenue split induces the worker to be more productive in output per hour resulting in a higher wage. The relevant price of effort is the after-split, after-tax wage controlled for after-tax household income. Incentives through a higher split raise productivity and the return to effort. The sample is 1,559 U.S. real estate sales professionals paid on contract splits in 2007 and choosing their hours and effort. The compensated labor supply elasticity is positive and between approximately zero and 0.3 suggesting the absence of income targeting for these workers on split and 100% revenue contracts. But the inclusion of contractual income split provisions in the model substantially increases the labor supply elasticity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In Ackerberg and Botticini (2002) a fixed rent is a more efficient contract because the tenant is providing the effort and is a residual claimant. This condition holds if the professional and firm have the same levels of risk aversion. Splits apply when the firm is more able to bear risk or the revenue streams are more uncertain.

  2. In Headen (1990) a premium exists for entrepreneur doctors after adjustment for self-selection. Offsetting this effect is the scale in back-office billing and built-in referral networks from having hospitals owning medical practices. By 2008 more than half the doctors in the United States were working at practices owned by hospitals up from fewer than 20% in 2002, even if the front-office look remained the same. Rosen (1992) estimates similar structures for lawyers.

  3. In Prendergast (2002) the assignment of incentive contracts depends on the risk of output. When output is less risky firms pay on input. When output is more risky, compensation is based proportionally on output. For professionals, output is not only individually observed but risky. The Holmström (1979) incentive compatibility constraints apply. Laeven and Levine (2008) evaluate contract terms.

  4. Helland and Showalter (2009) use data from the Physician Practice Costs and Income Survey. A 1% severity increase in liability lowers effort by 0.3%. For doctors over age 55 the reduction in effort is 1.2% for a similar severity increase. Allowing the wage to be exogenous in the effort equation causes a downward bias in the measured elasticity. Another source of downward bias is if the wage is determined by dividing total earnings by hours. Under income targeting drivers are working harder when fares are scarce and less when there are more customers.

  5. An example of 100% compensation is the Re/Max franchise where s = 1. Even firms such as Re/Max offering s = 1 in exchange for a debt payment will examine a broker’s prior sales performance and experience, for example, because the reputation of the franchise is based upon the abilities of their brokers.

  6. In a recursive set of equations, the solution to the nth endogenous variable involves only the first n equations of the model, and therefore, the endogenous variables on the right-hand side of the equation s do not need to be correlated to the error terms.

  7. Part-time workers defined as working less than 20 h per week are eliminated from the sample because they often sell properties to a social network of friends and family. The findings are largely the same when including part-time workers, but the inclusion of part-time workers creates a potential for sample selection bias. Part-time workers with relatively few hours are most often less experienced and tend to receive lower splits than full-time workers.

  8. The exact percentage change requires the following transformation: y = e x where x is the regression coefficient. For convenience purposes, the estimates will be discussed without the transformation

  9. The maximum is determined by solving for Exp in the following equation: \( \frac{{\delta Gross{ }Wages}}{{\delta Exp}} = 0 \)

  10. This is equivalent to using fitted values for the endogenous variables in the model.

References

  • Ackerberg DA, Botticini M (2002) Endogenous matching and the empirical determinants of contract form. J Polit Econ 110:564–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitler MP, Moskowitz TJ, Vissing-Jørgensen A (2005) Testing agency theory with entrepreneur effort and wealth. J Finance 60:539–576

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cagetti M, De Nardi M (2006) Entrepreneurship, frictions and wealth. J Polit Econ 114:835–869

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Babcock L, Loewenstein G, Thaler R (1997) Labor supply of New York City cab drivers: one day at a time. Q J Econ 111:408–441

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Salanié B (2000) Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets. J Polit Econ 108:56–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chou, YK (2000) “Testing alternative models of labor supply: evidence from taxi-drivers in Singapore,” University of Melbourne Research Paper 768

  • Farber (2005) Is tomorrow another day? The labor supply of New York cab drivers. J Polit Econ 113:46–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farber HS (2008) Reference-dependent preferences and labor supply: the case of New York City taxi drivers. Am Econ Rev 98:1069–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Goette L (2007) Do workers work more if wages are high? Evidence from a randomized field experiment. Am Econ Rev 97:298–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gompers P, Anna Kovner, Josh Lerner, and David Scharfstein (2010) “Performance persistence in entrepreneurship.” J Financ Econ. forthcoming

  • Hamilton BH (2000) Does entrepreneurship pay? An empirical analysis of the returns to self-employment. J Polit Econ 108:604–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Headen A (1990) Wage, returns to ownership, and fee responses to physician supply. Rev Econ Stat 72:30–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helland E, Showalter M (2009) The impact of liability on the physician labor market. J Law Econ 52:635–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B (1979) Moral hazard and observability. Bell J Econ 10:74–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B, Milgrom P (1994) The firm as an incentive system. Am Econ Rev 84:972–991

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurst E, Lusardi A (2004) Liquidity constraints, household wealth and entrepreneurship. J Polit Econ 112:319–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight FH (1921) Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Hart, Schaffner, and Marx, Boston MA: Houghton Mifflin Company

    Google Scholar 

  • Laeven L, Levine R (2008) Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations. Rev Financ Stud 21:579–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J-J, Matoussi MS (1995) Moral hazard, financial constraints and sharecropping in El Oulja. Rev Econ Stud 62:381–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear E (2005) Entrepreneurship. J Labor Econ 23:649–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moskowitz TJ, Vissing-Jørgensen A (2002) The returns to entrepreneurial investment: a private equity premium puzzle? Am Econ Rev 92:745–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oettinger GS (1999) An empirical analysis of the daily labor supply of stadium vendors. J Polit Econ 107:360–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Salanié B, Salanié F, Gandhi A (2009) Identifying preferences under risk from discrete choices. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 99:356–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast C (2002) The tenuous trade-off between risk and incentives. J Polit Econ 110:1071–1102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1992) The market for lawyers. J Law Econ 35:53–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel T. Winkler.

Additional information

The data for this study were provided by the National Association of Realtors®. We are grateful to John Benjamin, Paul Bishop and Michael Fratantoni for their contributions.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 6

Table 6 Labor supply elasticity using OLS

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chinloy, P., Winkler, D.T. Contracts, Labor Supply and Income Targeting. J Labor Res 32, 113–135 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-011-9104-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-011-9104-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation