Skip to main content
Log in

The Existential Threat: Varieties of Socialism and the Origins of Electoral Systems in Early Democracies

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The origins of electoral systems in early democracies have received a great deal of attention in recent years, as scholars seek to explain why at the time of suffrage expansion some countries adopted proportional representation (PR) while others chose single-member plurality (SMP). This paper offers a systematic explanation of the choice of electoral systems based on the “existential threat” posed by rising workers’ parties after suffrage expansion, that is, the extent to which these parties threatened the institutions of capitalism and liberal democracy. Original historical research offers important correctives to the dominant scholarly narrative, revealing that PR and SMP were both novel systems at the time, devised to replace the “mixed” systems that prevailed in the predemocratic period. Both, moreover, were seen as elite safeguards that, through different mechanisms, would protect right parties from the impact of suffrage expansion. Mid-range analysis of 18 historical cases reveals that the choice ultimately turned on the different strategic advantages and time horizons associated with the two systems as well as the existential threat presented by new workers’ parties.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to this definition, the “democratic” period is understood to begin (though certainly not end) with manhood suffrage, which opened up the sphere of political participation.

  2. The term “right parties” refers to both Conservative and Liberal parties who would often find themselves to the right of the median voter after suffrage expansion.

  3. Rokkan originally explained the Belgian case as an exception where the move to PR had more to do with concerns for the representation of ethnic and religious minorities. However, there is little in the historical accounts to support such a claim, as the religious and ethnic cleavage had receded in Belgian politics by the time of the adoption of PR (see Kalyvas 1996; Caramani 2004, p. 98).

  4. This was true particularly in Sweden, Denmark, and Belgium. In other cases, socialist parties were often either agnostic on the issue or expressed lukewarm support, often using PR as a bargaining chip to extract other concessions. Only in the case of the German SPD did the socialists truly embrace PR. The logic behind this support was that PR would allow the party to appeal to a primarily working class electorate, thus sparing it the need to moderate its platform to appeal to other electors. It was a position criticized by many pragmatists who recognized that PR would hurt the left, but proportionalists ultimately prevailed and PR was adopted in the SPDs platform in 1891.

  5. SMP could only be considered the originating system in cases of late state formation or where the regime was interrupted: in Italy, SMP was adopted at the time of unification in 1861, in Germany the Electoral Law of 1871 established SMP as part of the Federal Constitution, and in the same year SMP was adopted with the founding of the French Third Republic. Elsewhere, however, the lack of systematic apportionment meant that the electoral configurations varied widely within countries.

  6. The earliest instances in which we find SMP implemented explicitly as an electoral safeguard came in the USA in 1842, Denmark in 1848, and the UK in 1884 (see below).

  7. A long line of scholarship has explored the dynamics of party realignment under majoritarianism, particularly in the USA. See for example the work of Key (1955), Burnham (1970), and Sundquist (1983). Though such realignments are rare, they tend to happen during periods of significant ideological and demographic transformation, such as that experienced with suffrage expansion.

  8. The measure for electoral viability is binary: a party is considered to be viable once it has successfully contested three consecutive elections. The level of ideological radicalism is broken down into three categories: “moderate” representing a commitment to cross-class cooperation to achieve progressive reform but tacit acceptance of the institutions of capitalism and liberal democracy, “mixed” representing a divided movement combining elements of reformism and radicalism into a distinct doctrine of revolutionary syndicalism; and “radical” representing a commitment to productive class struggle and a desire for radical transformation of the institutions of capitalism and liberal democracy. A detailed discussion of the measures for both electoral viability and ideological radicalism can be found in the Appendix.

  9. An assessment of changes in the electoral threat could only be made in three cases: Denmark, Norway, and Switzerland. In the remaining cases, any change in the electoral threat during this period cannot be assessed because PR was adopted before post-war elections had taken place.

  10. It should be noted that in some cases the independence of the worker’s party was compromised through ongoing cooperation with an established right party. This is accounted for in the measure of ideological radicalism below.

  11. There has been some disagreement in the case of Switzerland, which is identified by some as being on the more moderate end of the spectrum (Marks et al. 2009), and by others on the more radical end (Bartolini 2000; Steenson 1991). While the Swiss SDP did for a time look to be moving in the direction of moderation, it maintained a doctrinal commitment to Marxism and experienced a sustained period of radicalization prior to WWI which extended through the interwar years (Luebbert 1991). Because it is this later period that is of interest in examining the choice of electoral systems, for the purposes of this analysis the Swiss SDP will be identified as ideologically radical.

References

  • Aardal B. Electoral systems in Norway. In: Grofman B, Lijphart A, editors. Parties and electoral systems in the Nordic Countries. New York: Agathon; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahmed A. Reading history forward: the origins of electoral systems in advanced democracies. Comparative Political Studies. 2010;43:1059–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahmed A. Democracy and the politics of electoral system choice: engineering electoral dominance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2012.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Glaser EL. Fighting poverty in Europe: a world of difference. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2004.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews JT, Jackman RW. Strategic fools: electoral rule choice under extreme uncertainty. Electoral Studies. 2005;24:65–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anonymous. 1903. Acts of parliament of the dominion of Canada. Ottowa: Samuel Edward Dawson.

  • Atkinson N. Adventures in democracy: a history of the vote in New Zealand. Otago: University of Otago Press; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartolini S. The political mobilization of the European left, 1860–1980: the class cleavage. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2000.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bean C. Class and party in the Anglo-American democracies: the case of New Zealand in perspective. The British Journal of Political Science. 1988;18:303–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman S. The social democratic moment: ideas and politics in the making of interwar Europe. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard M. Institutions and the fate of democracy: Germany and Poland in the twentieth century. Pittsburg: University of Pittsburg Press; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blais A, Dobrzynska A, Indridason IH. To adopt or not to adopt proportional representation. British Journal of Political Science. 2005;35(1 (January)):182–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix C. Setting the rules of the game: the choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review. 1999;93(3):609–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buiting H. The Netherlands. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990. p. 1870–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burgmann V. In our time: socialism and the rise of labor, 1885–1905. Sydney: Allen & Unwin; 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham WD. Critical elections and the mainsprings of American politics. New York: Norton; 1970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busky D. Democratic socialism: a global survey. Wetport, CT.: Praeger Publishers; 2000.

  • Callesen G. Denmark. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990. p. 1870–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo E. The competitive road to proportional representation: partisan biases and electoral regime change under increasing party competition. World Politics. 2009;61:2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capoccia G, Ziblatt D. The historic turn in democratization studies: a new research program and evidence from Europe. Comparative Political Studies. 2010;43:931–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caramani D. The nationalization of politics: the formation of national electorates and party systems in Western Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2004.

  • Carstairs AM. A short history of electoral systems in Western Europe. London: George Allen & Unwin; 1980.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castillo S. Spain. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990. p. 1870–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole GDH. British working class politics, 1832–1914. London: Routledge & Kegan; 1941.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole A, Campbell P. French electoral systems and elections since 1789. Aldershot: Gower; 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colomer J. Spain: from civil war to proportional representation. In: Colomer J, Grofman B, editors. Handbook of electoral system choice. New York: Palgrave; 2004.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Colomer J. On the origins of electoral systems and political parties: the role of elections in multi-member districts. Electoral Studies. 2007;26(2 (June)):262–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crepaz M. Inclusion versus exclusion: political institutions and the welfare State. Comparative Politics. 1998;31:61–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cusack TR, Iversen T, Sokice D. Economic interests and the origins of electoral systems. American Political Science Review. 2007;101(August):373–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eley G. Forging democracy. The history of the left in Europe, 1850-2000. New York: Oxford University Press; 2002.

  • Elklit J. The politics of electoral system development and change: the Danish case. In: Grofman B, Lijphart A, editors. Parties and electoral systems in the Nordic Countries. New York: Agathon; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell DM, McAllister I. 1902 and the origins of preferential electoral systems in Australia. Australian Journal of Politics & History. 2005;51(2):155–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell D, McAllister I. The Australian electoral system. Sydney: University of New South Wales; 2006.

  • Foner PS. History of the labor movement in the United States, vol. 1. New York: International Publishers; 1947.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garner JW. Electoral reform in France. The American Political Science Review. 1913;7(4 (Nov)):610–638.

  • Garrido A. Electors and Electoral Districts in Spain: 1974-1936. In: Romanlli R, editor. How did they become voters: a history of the franchise in modern Europe. The Hague: Kluwer law International; 1998.

  • Goblet d’Aviella, E. 1900. la représentation proportionelle en Belgique: histoire d’une réforme. Brussels: P. Weissenbruch.

  • Graham BD. The Choice of Voting Methods in Federal Politics, 1902-1918. In: Hughes C, editor. Readings in Australian Politics. Queensland: University of Queensland Press; 1968.

  • Grofman B, Lijphart A. The evolution of electoral and party systems in the nordic countries. New York: Agathon Press; 2002.

  • Haggard S, Kaufmann R. Democracy, development, and welfare States. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamer D. The second ballot: a New Zealand electoral experiment. New Zealand Journal of History. 1987;21:97–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansard TC. Hansard’s parliamentary debates. London: Cornelius Buck; 1885.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen E. Between reform and revolution: social democracy and Dutch society, 1917-21. In: Schmitt HS, editor. Neutral Europe between war and revolution 1917-23. Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia; 1988.

  • Hardarson Ó. The Icelandic electoral system 1844–1999. In: Grofman B, Lijphart A, editors. Parties and electoral systems in the Nordic Countries. New York: Agathon; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hare T. Representation and misrepresentation. The Fortnightly Review. 1885;43:202–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart J. Proportional representation: critics of the British electoral system 1820–1945. Oxford: Clarendon Press; 1992.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hinton J. Labour and socialism: a history of the British labour movement 1867–1974. Amherst: University of Massachusetts Press; 1983.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoag CG, Hallet GH. Proportional representation. New York: The Macmillan Company; 1926.

  • Hunt EH. British labour history 1815–1914. New Jersey: Humanities Press; 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen T, Soskice D. Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review. 2006;100:165–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalyvas S. The rise of Christian democracy in Europe. Cornell: Cornell University Press; 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson G. The history of Iceland. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzenstein P. Small States in world markets: industrial policy in Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kergoat J. France. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements 1870–1914. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Key VO. A theory of critical elections. Journal of Politics. 1955;17:3–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby D. Finland. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements 1870–1914. Leiden: E. J. Brill; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirwan JW. The Australian labor party. The Nineteenth Century. 1905;(Nov):822–837.

  • Kreuzer M. Historical knowledge and quantitative analysis: the case of the origins of proportional representation. American Political Science Review. 2010;104:404–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreuzer, M. 2011. “Taking Plausibility seriously: the cognitive basis of theory development”. Working Paper.

  • Lafferty W. Industrialization and labor radicalism in Norway. Scandanavian Political Studies. 1972;7:157–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindemann A. The red years: European socialism vs. bolshevism, 1919-1921. London: University of California Press; 1974

  • Lorwin L. The American federation of labor: history, politics, and prospects. Clifton: Augustus M. Kelley Publishers; 1972.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luebbert G. Liberalism, fascism, or social democracy: social classes and the political origins of regimes in interwar Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lutz G. Electoral reform from below: the introduction of proportional representation in Switzerland 1918. In: Colomer J, editor. The handbook of electoral system choice. London: Palgrave; 2004.

  • Mackie T, Rose R. International almanac of electoral history. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly; 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahaim E. Proportional representation and the debates upon the electoral question in Belgium. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 1900;15:69–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markey R. Australia. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements 1870–1914. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marks G, Mbaye H, Kim H. Radicalism or reformism? Socialist parties before World War I. American Sociological Review. 2009;74(4):615–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin CJ, Swank D. The political origins of coordinated capitalism. American Political Science Review. 2008;102:181–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCormack AR. Arthur Puttee and the liberal party. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; 1970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meaker G. The revolutionary left in Spain, 1914-1923. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 1974.

  • Moyne M. Resultats des elections belges entre 1847 et 1914. Brussels: Bibliotheque de l’Insitut Belge de Science Politique; 1970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Müller W. Austria: a complex electoral system with subtle effects. In: Gallagher M, Mitchell P editors. The politics of electoral systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2005.

  • Olssen E. New Zealand. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990. p. 1870–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penadés A. Choosing rules for government: the institutional preferences of early socialist parties. In: Maravall JM, Sanchéz-Cuenca I, editors. Controlling governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G. The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polasky J. A revolution for socialist reforms: the Belgian general strike for universal suffrage. Journal of Contemporary History. 1992;27(3):449–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter G. The electoral systems of imperial Germany. In: Noriet S, editor. Political strategies and electoral reforms. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft; 1990.

  • Rodden, J. 2006. “Political geography and electoral rules: why single-member districts are bad for the left.” Working Paper.

  • Rodden J. The geographic distribution of preferences. Annual Review of Political Science. 2010;13:321–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogowski R. Trade and the variety of democratic institutions. International Organizations. 1987;41(Spring):203–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rokkan S. Citizens, elections, parties: approaches to the comparative study of the process of development. New York: David McKay; 1970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salomone A. Italian democracy in the making. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press; 1945.

    Google Scholar 

  • Särlvik B. Party and electoral system in Sweden. In: Grofman B, Lijphart A, editors. Parties and electoral systems in the Nordic Countries. New York: Agathon; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scudamore C. Belgium and the Belgians. Edinburgh: William Blackwood; 1895.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seton-Watson C. Italy from liberalism to fascism: 1870–1925. London: Methuen; 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shields J. Whigs reform the "bear garden": representation and the apportionment Act of 1842. Journal of the Early Republic. 1985;5(3):355–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sperber J. The Kaiser’s voters: electors and elections in imperial Germany. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steenson GP. After Marx, before Lenin: Marxism and socialist working-class parties in Europe, 1884–1914. Pittsburg: University of Pittsburg Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephens J. The transition from capitalism to socialism. London: MacMillan; 1979.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strikwerda C. A house divided: Catholics, socialists, and Flemish nationalists in nineteenth century Belgium. Boston: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundberg J. The electoral system of Finland: old and working well. In: Grofman B, Lijphart A, editors. Parties and electoral systems in the Nordic countries. New York: Agathon; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundquist JL. Dynamics of the party system: alignment and realignment of political parties in the United States. Washington: Brookings Institute; 1983. 1973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Talsma J. Traditional politics, religion, and social relationships in the dutch electoral process. In; Romanlli R, editor. How did they become voters: a history of the franchise in modern Europe. The Hague: Kluwer law International; 1998.

  • Terjesen E. Norway. In: Van Der Linden M, Rojahn J, editors. The formation of labour movements 1870–1914. Leiden: E.J. Brill; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uhr J. Deliberative democracy in Australia: the changing place of parliament. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1998.

  • Tingsten H. The Swedish social democrats: their ideological development. Totowa: Bedminster Press; 1973. 1941.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Amel Ahmed.

Additional information

I am grateful to Ivan Ascher, Jose Cheibub, Jorgen Elklit, Gary Marks, Csaba Nikolenyi, Tatishe Nteta, M.J. Peterson, and Jesse Rhodes for valuable comments on drafts of this paper. The paper has also greatly benefited from feedback received at the University of Illinois, Urbana-Champagne Comparative Politics Workshop, as well as the ECPR Joint Sessions Workshop “Why Electoral Reform.” In addition, I would like to thank the Editors of Studies in Comparative International Development as well as two anonymous reviewers for their constructive feedback on the manuscript.

Appendix

Appendix

Measurements of the Existential Threat

The existential threat is understood to be a function of two variables: the electoral viability of workers’ parties and the extent of ideological radicalism they displayed. In this section, I offer a more detailed discussion of the measurements used for these indices.

Electoral Viability

The first indicator, “electoral viability” assesses whether or not an independent workers’ party had a permanent presence in the party system. In many cases, workers’ representatives contested elections as independents or under the auspices of one of the major right party before the formation of an independent workers’ party. These efforts, though often having a significant impact are not included in the measure of electoral viability as they would not in themselves indicate an existential threat. In fact, so long as workers’ representatives remained fragmented or relied on right parties, the latter could be confident of their continued dominance. Thus, electoral viability is measured with the rise of an independent worker’s party.Footnote 10 Such parties are considered viable once they have contested three consecutive elections.

The only cases where workers’ parties did not meet this minimal threshold of viability were the USA and Canada. There, despite some notable electoral achievements, workers’ parties were unable to maintain representation at the national level. In the USA, independent working class mobilization began in the decades after suffrage expansion with Workingmen’s parties established in several states (Foner 1947). Despite the promising start, labor leaders ultimately failed to unite these disparate groups into a unified movement. By the 1890s, the labor movement had definitively moved away from direct political action (Lorwin 1972, p. 91). The Socialist Party of America would emerge at that time espousing a radical platform, but ultimately proved ineffective electorally. In Canada, labor was more successful in electing individual candidates. Representatives of labor consistently won elections beginning in the late nineteenth century. However, labor never consolidated its efforts to form a viable national party (McCormack 1970). The CLP was established in 1917 but disbanded after a few unsuccessful electoral campaigns. In both the USA and Canada, right parties would come to represent the interests of workers, maintaining the predemocratic status quo.

Ideological Radicalism

The second important indicator of existential threat—ideological radicalism—is decidedly more complicated to assess. In developing a measure of radicalism, I use a number of sources. I begin with Marks, Mbaye, and Kim’s examination of nineteenth-century socialist party radicalism (Marks et al. 2009). Using socialist party platforms, they score parties along four important dimensions of radicalism: (1) attitude towards the political system, (2) attitude towards the economic system, (3) methods sanctioned, and (4) number of dissenting factions. These measures are subjective in that they are based on party platforms rather than actual party behavior, but given that many of these parties were fairly new at the time, their espoused beliefs and goals were the only source of information available to their contemporaries. Therefore, subjective measures are useful in capturing how these parties were perceived and situating them in relation to one another (Table 2).

Table 2 Measures of ideological radicalism, 1900

Useful as these measures are, however, they do not in themselves indicate what is to be considered radical. For that, we need to consider the substantive positions reflected by the scores. In the category of political orientation, positions 3 and 4 indicate an antisystemic stance that “democracy is not legitimate” and thus clearly constitute radical positions. However, even position 2 that “democracy is legitimate but requires major reform” represents a radical departure from the status quo as the socialists could potentially use their political position to change the rules of the game to their advantage. Thus, I consider a score of 2 to be the cutoff for radicalism in this category. On economic orientation, similarly a score of 2 will be the cutoff score for radicalism. While challenging the legitimacy of capitalism (positions 3 and 4) clearly reflects a radical position, the threat of major reform with potentially major redistributive consequences as indicated by position 2 would also represent a radical departure from the status quo.

In the category of “methods,” Marks, Mbaye, and Kim consider a range of activities from lobbying and advocacy to violent insurrection. However, electoral competition, which is precisely the method that right parties were most concerned about and aimed to contain through electoral reform, scores low on the scale of radicalism (score of 1). To be sure, more radical methods such as strike activity and the threat of violence (positions 2, 3, and 4) were a great concern; however, the threat did not have to rise to that level for a party to be considered radical. Simply using elections as a method combined with the threat of major changes to the political and economic status quo would suffice for a party to be considered radical. For this reason, the cut-off for methods in this analysis will be a score of 1.

Thus as a starting point, a score of 2 on political and economic orientation, and 1 on methods, with no dissenting factions would be considered the minimum threshold for radicalism. According to this classification scheme, socialist parties in The UK, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, and Switzerland would be considered moderate and socialist parties in Germany, Finland, the Netherlands, Belgium, Norway, Sweden, the USA, Iceland, Denmark, France, Spain, and Italy would be considered radical.

For the most part, this would seem consistent with the broader literature. Most accounts place the British model of parties based in trade-unionism with a reformist agenda and strong tradition of cross-class cooperation on the more moderate end of the spectrum (Bartolini 2000, p. 70). The BLP embraced a vision of harmonious class relations which deviated significantly from the rigid socialist principles that guided its counterparts on the Continent (Hunt 1981, pp. 275–281; Hinton 1983, p. 33; Cole 1941, pp. 42–43). The moderate model was highly influential in Australia and New Zealand as well where workers’ parties similarly rejected the notion that revolutionary social transformation was necessary for progress (Burgmann 1985; Olssen 1990). The NZLP advanced a program of constitutionally grounded reform and remained committed to the political process as a means of improving the lives of workers (Olssen 1990, p. 616). Australian labor similarly embraced a doctrine of ‘Laborism’ as a positive alternative to socialism (Markey 1990, p. 595). Notably, Labor parties in all three cases accepted not only parliamentary democracy, but the capitalist system as well. These parties often faced more radical socialist challenges and sometimes experienced periods of radicalization themselves, but overall they maintained a commitment to achieving progress through the existing social order (Hinton 1983, p. 35; Stephens 1979, p. 143).

At the other end of the ideological spectrum was the German model of parties adhering to more orthodox Marxist principles emphasizing class conflict and the need for revolutionary social transformation (Bartolini 2000, pp. 72–73; Berman 1998, p. 66). Though there was a great deal of variation in this category, these were all cases where workers’ parties espoused a platform that posed an existential challenge to the prevailing capitalist democratic order. The SPD beginning with the Erfurt Congress in 1891 adopted a platform that emphasized the role of productive class conflict and endorsed revolutionary tactics to bring about social transformation (Bartolini 2000, pp. 72–73; Steenson 1991, pp. 70–72). The Erfurt program would influence workers’ parties throughout Europe, and though the German SPD may have been unique in the extent of its embrace of socialist doctrine, workers’ parties in several other cases also incorporated these principles at various levels of orthodoxy.

The closest in ideological orientation to the Germans were the Finnish and Austrian Social Democrats, who at times displayed greater radicalism than even the Germans (Marks et al. 2009, p. 633). In Finland, after an extended period of isolation from the international socialist movement, labor would have an abrupt introduction to Marxism in the wake of the Russian revolution of 1905. The Finnish Social Democratic Party would come to embrace one of the most radical doctrines of European socialist parties (Kirby 1990, pp. 525–526). The SPÖ also had a decidedly radical orientation. Its platform explicitly identified the “proletariat” as the object of its efforts to forge a class conscious movement, splitting with moderate forces that used more inclusive rhetoric such as “the oppressed people” or “toiling masses” (Steenson 1991, p. 186).

Elsewhere, workers’ parties adhered to Marxism in a less orthodox fashion, adopting a more conciliatory tone, but still maintaining a commitment to class conscious action and radical social transformation. In the Netherlands, the Social Democratic Workers’ Party established in 1894 modeled itself on the German SPD, from which it derived its party program as well as its organizational structure (Buiting 1990, p. 67). The Belgian Workers’ Party founded in 1885 also adopted a radical platform and under the leadership of Emile Vandervelde the party would utilize more revolutionary tactics (Strikwerda 1997, p. 109; Polasky 1992). The Danish Social Democratic Party similarly adopted a Marxian doctrine, though from the 1890s on it rejected militarism (Callesen 1990, p. 159). In SDPI, established in 1916, was in fact the first modern party to form. And in the absence of strong moderating influences, it would develop a radical platform espousing orthodox Marxian principles (Karlsson 2000, pp. 302–303).

For a number of other cases, in the early stages of working class mobilization, labor would maintain a relatively moderate orientation but would later come to embrace more radical doctrines. For the Swedish Social Democrats, radicals who had been in the minority for the first decades of the party’s existence acquired greater influence by the turn of the century and by 1908, a more orthodox Marxism had firmly taken root (Tingsten 1973; Bartolini 2000, p. 83). In Norway, the Socialist Labor Party (DNA) established in 1887, began contesting elections under the patronage of the Liberal party. But dissatisfaction with their subordinate position led to a radicalization of workers and the embrace of more orthodox socialist doctrine. This was marked in 1891 with the adoption of a new platform closely following the German SPD’s Erfurt Program (Terjesen 1990, pp. 115–116; Lafferty 1972). The PS, which looked to be moving in the direction of moderation also experienced a sustained period of radicalization prior to WWI which extended through the interwar years (Luebbert 1991, p. 98; Bartolini 2000, p. 85).Footnote 11

There are a number of cases, however, that due to conflicting ideological influences do not fit into this simple radicalism vs. reformism classification. This includes France, Italy, and Spain, where the strength of anarchist factions divided workers’ movements, resulting in a doctrine of revolutionary syndicalism, which many have identified as a separate ideological orientation altogether (Kergoat 1990, pp. 169–171; Seton-Watson 1967, pp. 157–158; Castillo 1990, pp. 227–228). In these three cases, the ideological divisions were so deep that in the early stages of working class mobilization separate workers’ parties successfully competed for the support of working class electors. In France, the movement was split between the radical socialism of Jules Guesde and the moderate social democratic perspective of Jean Jaurès (Steenson 1991, p. 137). The movement would later unite under the leadership of Jaurès to form the SFIO, but tensions between the two factions would persist. The Spanish labor movement was even more deeply divided, delaying the consolidation of the left until after the First World War. The PSOE maintained a relatively moderate position but was continuously confronted with radical challenges and extended periods of fragmentation (Meaker 1974, pp. 207–208). The PSI, from its inception in 1892 was a combined movement, bringing together disparate socialist and anarchist groups (Steenson 1991, p. 233). Throughout the first decade of the twentieth century, the PSI was able to maintain unity among these different groups and even seemed to be moving toward moderation. However, divisions within the movement over a number of issues, most notably Italy’s imperial policy, led to fragmentation and the greater radicalization of workers. By the First World War, the movement had turned more definitively towards radicalism (Seton-Watson 1967, pp. 264–271). In all three cases, the division would leave a lasting mark on the movement which, even during periods of greater unity, would maintain a mixed ideological program, combining elements of radicalism and reformism. Thus, for the purposes of this analysis, France, Spain, and Italy will be considered under a third category of revolutionary syndicalism.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ahmed, A. The Existential Threat: Varieties of Socialism and the Origins of Electoral Systems in Early Democracies. St Comp Int Dev 48, 141–171 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-012-9121-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-012-9121-8

Keywords

Navigation