Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Commerce and institutions: Trade, scope, and the design of regional economic organizations

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The design of current regional economic organizations (REOs) is remarkably diverse. Some REOs address numerous economic issues, while others have only limited mandates. Some REOs have an independent bureaucracy and a legalized dispute settlement mechanism (DSM), while others do not. What determines this institutional variation? Thinking about these institutions as devices that generate credible commitment to a rule-based regional cooperation, institutionalists maintain that the intensity of commercial ties determine regional institutionalization and institutional independence. A number of studies question this logic and argue that it is “naïve.” Empirical evidence on the links between commerce, economic scope, and regional institutions is scant, however. Using an original data set that contains detailed information on the economic activities and institutional structure of twenty-eight REOs over three decades, this paper presents one of the first systematic analyses of these relationships. The empirical analysis indicates that the institutionalist wisdom is right after all. It shows that higher levels of regional trade are associated with greater institutionalization and economic scope, but only if implementation of signed agreements is accounted for, and that regional commerce and greater economic scope are associated with more independent bureaucracies and more legalized DSMs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See the Online Appendix at this Journal’s webpage for the full name of these organizations.

  2. This criterion results in the exclusion of bilateral preferential trade agreements (PTAs), which almost always lack a continuous institutional framework, as well as economic agreements between REOs and individual states or other REOs (such as agreements between the EU and third countries).

  3. Implementation is related to but distinct from compliance. The former is usually a key step towards, but it is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for the latter (Raustiala and Slaughter 2002: 539). Implementation is also different from effectiveness, which refers to the relative success of an institution in obtaining its stated goals (Acharya and Johnston 2007: 24–25; Gray and Slapin 2012; Raustiala and Slaughter 2002; Victor et al. 1998).

  4. In some cases, members agreed to form a tribunal but its establishment was postponed for several years or indefinitely. Establishment is different from utilization, DSMs may be operational but underutilized. The design of DSMs may affect their utilization and effectiveness (Gray and Slapin 2012; Kono 2007; Posner and Yoo 2005).

  5. REOs that were formed after 1982 include fewer observations.

  6. I offer a detailed description of this process elsewhere (Haftel 2012).

  7. For each REO, the value represents the average across the different time points. Even though the level of institutionalization changes over time, most REOs remain in the same category.

  8. Newly formed REOs have low levels of regional institutionalization that may lead to an artificially low average. It is thus more informative to compare the same group of organizations across time.

  9. Most, but not all, REOs have experienced increasing institutionalization. Some organizations, such as APTA and LAIA, showed little dynamism and others, such as MRU and CEPGL, have experienced declining levels of institutionalization over time.

  10. This is sometimes dubbed as the “new” or “open” regionalism.

  11. Nonetheless, the EU has much in common with other REOs and serves a useful yardstick (Acharya and Johnston 2007; Kahler 1995).

  12. Many REOs have a non-binding DSM, see Smith (2000).

  13. In particular, the analysis conducted here does not explain why states form or join REOs in the first place. Instead, given their existence, it makes inferences about the sources of variation across REOs. For a recent and illuminating study that accounts for the growing number of trade agreements, see Baccini and Dür (2012).

  14. A Hausman test indicates that the random effects model is consistent and therefore preferable to the fixed effects model. Given Baier and Bergstrand’s (2007) recommendation to use the fixed effects specification, four such models are reported in Table A3 of the Online Appendix. The analysis indicates that the results for implemented scope are robust to this specification, but the results for regional institutionalization are not. It is also noteworthy that all the year dummies except 1987 are positive and highly significant, reflecting the growing institutionalization of REOs in the post Cold War era.

  15. The full models that pertain to regional bureaucracy did not converge. A reduced model is therefore presented. In addition, none of the year dummies is statistically significant in all models related to bureaucracy and DSM.

  16. Trade data for SACU is not available, and most likely does not exist (Page 2000a, 117).

  17. I tested for two alternative specifications of this variable: the actual Polity average and the score of the least democratic member. I also tested for the effect of the standard deviation on the regional Polity score. These three variables were not statistically significant and did not change the results.

  18. Dropping the most institutionalized, and arguably unique, REO – the EU – from the sample does not change these results (not reported here).

  19. These results are robust to various model specifications and remain intact when the EU is dropped from the analysis.

References

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states act through formal international organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(1), 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2000). Hard and soft law in international governance. International Organization, 54(3), 421–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, A., & Johnston, A. I. (2007). Crafting cooperation: regional international institutions in comparative perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • African Development Bank. (2000). African development report. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baccini, L., & Dür, A. (2012). The new regionalism and policy interdependence. British Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 57–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baccini, L., & Urpelainen, J. (2011). International institutions and domestic politics: Can Preferential trade agreements promote economic reform? Unpublished Manuscript.

  • Baccini, L., & Urpelainen, J. (2012). Strategic side payments, preferential trade agreements, economic reform, and foreign aid. Journal of Politics, 74(4), 932–949.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R. W. (2009). The WTO: Theory and practice. NBER Working Paper 15445. Boston: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2007). Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 72–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balassa, B. (1961). The theory of economic integration. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bearce, D. H., & Omori, S. (2005). How do commercial institutions promote peace? Journal of Peace Research, 42(6), 659–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boehmer, C., Gartzke, E., & Nordstrom, T. (2004). Do intergovernmental organizations promote peace? World Politics, 57(1), 1–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Börzel, T. A., & Risse, T. (2012). When Europeanisation meets diffusion: Exploring new territory. West European Politics, 35(1), 192–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Büthe, T., & Milner, H. V. (2008). The politics of foreign direct investment into developing countries: Increasing FDI through international trade agreements? American Journal of Political Science, 52(4), 741–762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buzan, B., & Wæver, O. (2003). Regions and powers: the structure of international security. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Caporaso, J. A. (1998). Regional integration theory: Understanding our past and anticipating the future. In W. Sandholtz & A. Stone Sweet (Eds.), Supranational governance: the Institutionalization of the European Union (pp. 334–351). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, Y. J., & Caporaso, J. A. (2002). Comparative regional integration. In W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, & B. A. Simmons (Eds.), Handbook of international relations (pp. 480–499). London: Sage Publications.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gartzke, E., & Jo, D. J. (2002). The affinity of nations index, 1946–1996. Version 3.0. http://dss.ucsd.edu/~egartzke/datasets.htm. Accessed December 12, 2012.

  • Gleditsch, K. S. (2002). All international politics is local: the diffusion of conflict, integration, and democratization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, N. P., Wallensteen, P., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M., & Strand, H. (2002). Armed conflict 1946–2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 39(5), 615–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J. (1996). International law and domestic institutions: Reconciling North American “Unfair” trade laws. International Organization, 50(4), 541–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J., & Steinberg, R. H. (2008). Negotiate or litigate? Effects of WTO judicial delegation on U.S. trade politics. Law and Contemporary Problems, 71(1), 257–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, J. (Forthcoming). Domestic capacity and the implementation gap in regional trade agreements. Comparative Political Studies.

  • Gray, J., & Slapin, J. B. (2012). How well do regional trade agreements work? Ask the experts. The Review of International Organizations, 7(3), 309–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grieco, J. M. (1997). Systemic sources of variation in regional institutionalization in Western Europe, East Asia, and the Americas. In E. D. Mansfield & H. V. Milner (Eds.), The political economy of regionalism (pp. 164–187). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haas, E. B. (1966). International integration and the universal process. In International Political Communities: An Anthology (pp. 93–130). New York: Anchor Books.

  • Haas, E. B. (1975). The obsolescence of regional integration theory. Berekley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hafner-Burton, E. M. (2009). Forced to be good: why trade agreements boost human rights. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z. (2007). Designing for peace: regional integration arrangements, institutional variation, and militarized interstate disputes. International Organization, 61(1), 217–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z. (2010). Conflict, regional cooperation, and foreign capital: Indonesian foreign policy and the formation of ASEAN. Foreign Policy Analysis, 6(2), 87–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z. (2012). Regional economic institutions and conflict mitigation: design, implementation, and the promise of peace. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z., & Thompson, A. (2006). The independence of international organizations: Concept and applications. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(2), 253–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, S. (1997). Regionalism in Asia and the Americas. In E. D. Mansfield & H. V. Milner (Eds.), The political economy of regionalism (pp. 20–49). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, D. G., Lake, D. A., Nielson, D. L., & Tierney, M. J. (2006). Delegation under anarchy: States, International Organizations, and the principal-agent theory. In D. G. Hawkins, D. A. Lake, D. L. Nielson, & M. J. Tierney (Eds.), Delegation and Agency in International Organizations (pp. 3–38). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers R., & Aten, B. (2009). Penn World Table Version 6.3. Philadelphia: Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/php_site/pwt_index.php. Accessed December 12, 2012.

  • Hicks, R., & Kim, S. Y. (2012). Reciprocal trade agreements in Asia: Credible commitment to trade liberalization or paper tigers? Journal of East Asian Studies, 12(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann, T., & Kim, S.Y. (2010). Designing reciprocity: Dispute settlement in trade agreements. Paper presented at the Workshop on the Politics of Trade Agreements: Theory, Measurement, and Empirical Applications. April 30-May 1, 2010, Princeton University.

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). (1994). International trade policies: the Uruguay round and beyond (Vol. 2). Washington D.C.: IMF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson, H. K. (1984). Networks of interdependence: International Organizations and the global political system (2nd ed.). New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaggers, K., & Gurr, T. R. (1995). Tracking democracy’s third wave with the polity III data. Journal of Peace Research, 32(4), 469–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johns, L. (2012). Trade versus rigidity in the design of preferential trade agreement. Unpublished Manuscript. Los Angeles: University of California Los Angeles.

  • Kahler, M. (1995). International institutions and the political economy of integration. Washington D.C.: The Brooking Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahler, M. (2000). Conclusion: The causes and consequences of legalization. International Organization, 54(3), 661–683.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katzenstein, P. J. (1997). Introduction: Asian regionalism in comparative perspective. In P. J. Katzenstein & T. Shiraishi (Eds.), Network power: Japan and Asia (pp. 1–44). Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kono, D. Y. (2007). Making anarchy work: international legal institutions and trade cooperation. Journal of Politics, 69(3), 746–759.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kono, D. Y., & Rickard, S. J. (2010). Buying national: Preferential trade agreements and public procurement. Paper presented at the Workshop on the Politics of Trade Agreements: Theory, Measurement, and Empirical Applications. April 30–May 1, 2010, Princeton University.

  • Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 55(4), 761–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. S., & Freeze, J. (2005). Regression models for categorical outcomes using Stata (2nd ed.). College Station: Stata Corp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Majone, G. (2001). Two logics of delegation: agency and fiduciary relations in EU governance. European Union Politics, 2(1), 103–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., & Milner, H. V. (1999). The new wave of regionalism. International Organization, 53(3), 529–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V., & Pevehouse, J. C. (2008). Democracy, Veto Players, and the Depth of Regional Integration. The World Economy, 31(1), 67–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V., & Rosendorff, B. P. (2002). Why democracies cooperate more: Electoral control and international trade agreements. International Organization, 56(3), 477–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., & Pevehouse, J. C. (2000). Trade Blocs, trade flows, and international conflict. International Organization, 54(4), 775–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2009). Polity IV Project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2007. Dataset users’ manual. Center for Systemic Peace, George Mason University.

  • Martin, L. L. (2000). Democratic commitments: Legislatures and international cooperation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mattli, W. (1999). The logic of regional integration: Europe and beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H. V. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: domestic politics and international relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (1998). The choice for Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nye, J. S. (1971). Peace in parts: integration and conflict in regional organization. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Page, S. (2000a). Regionalism among developing countries. London: MacMillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Page, S. (2000b). Intensity measures for regional groups. In S. Page (Ed.), Regions and development: politics, security and economics (pp. 67–89). London: Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J. C. (2005). Democracy from above: Regional organizations and democratization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J. C., Nordstrom, T., & Warnke, K. (2004). The correlates of war 2 international governmental organizations data version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21(2), 101–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J. C., & Russett, B. (2006). Democratic international governmental organizations promote peace. International Organization, 60(4), 969–1000.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poast, P. (2010). (Mis)Using dyadic data to analyze multilateral events. Political Analysis, 18(4), 403–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, E., & Yoo, J. (2005). Judicial independence in international tribunals. California Law Review, 93(1), 1–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raustiala, K., & Slaughter, A. M. (2002). International law, international relations and compliance. In W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, & B. A. Simmons (Eds.), Handbook of international relations (pp. 538–558). London: Sage Publications.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Signorino, C. S., & Ritter, J. M. (1999). Tau-B or not Tau-B: Measuring the similarity of foreign policy positions. International Studies Quarterly, 43(1), 115–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. A. (2000). International law and state behavior: Commitment and compliance in international monetary affairs. American Political Science Review, 94(4), 819–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. A., & Danner, A. (2010). Credible commitments and the international criminal court. International Organization, 64(2), 225–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. M. (2000). The Politics of dispute settlement design: Explaining legalism in regional trade pacts. International Organization, 54(1), 137–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone Sweet, A., & Sandholtz, W. (1998). Integration, supranational governance, and the institutionalization of the European polity. In W. Sandholtz & A. Stone Sweet (Eds.), Supranational governance: the institutionalization of the European Union (pp. 1–26). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A. (2006). Coercion through IOs: The security council and the logic of information transmission. International Organization, 61(1), 1–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Union of International Associations (UIA). (Various Years). Yearbook of international organizations. Edition 36. Munich: K. G. Saur Verlag.

  • United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). (1996). Handbook of economic integration and cooperation groupings of developing countries: Volume I – Regional and Subregional economic integration groupings. Geneva: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Victor, D. G., Raustiala, K., & Skolnikoff, E. (1998). Introduction and overview. In D. G. Victor, K. Raustiala, & E. Skolnikoff (Eds.), The implementation and effectiveness of international environmental commitments (pp. 1–46). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (Various Years). World Development Indicators. Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

  • Yarbrough, B., & Yarbrough, R. (1992). Cooperation and governance in international trade: The strategic organizational approach. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yarbrough, B., & Yarbrough, R. (1997). Dispute settlement in international trade: Regionalism and procedural coordination. In E. D. Mansfield & H. V. Milner (Eds.), The political economy of regionalism (pp. 134–163). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yoram Z. Haftel.

Additional information

Author’s note

Earlier drafts of this paper were presented at the Workshop on the Politics of Trade Agreements: Theory, Measurement, and Empirical Applications, April 30-May 1, 2010, Princeton University as well as the 2011 ISA Annual Convention and the 2011 APSA Annual Meeting. For helpful comments, I would like to thank Vinod Aggarwal, Mark Copelovitch, Soo Yeon Kim, Peter Rosendorff, and the anonymous reviewers.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(PDF 63.1 KB)

ESM 2

(DTA 15 kb)

ESM 3

(DO 4 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Haftel, Y.Z. Commerce and institutions: Trade, scope, and the design of regional economic organizations. Rev Int Organ 8, 389–414 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-012-9162-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-012-9162-9

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation