Skip to main content
Log in

A note on the valuation of asset management firms

  • Published:
Financial Markets and Portfolio Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Market capitalization relative to assets under management is often used to value asset management firms. Huberman’s (2004) dividend discount model implies that cross-sectional variations in this metric are explained by cross-sectional differences in operating margins, and yet we find no evidence of this in our data set. We show that a superior model—inspired by the work of Berk and Green (2004)—includes also the level of fees as an explanatory variable. This approach dramatically increases the fit of our valuation model and casts doubt on the relevance of the so-called Huberman puzzle.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. More general valuation frameworks are available, yet despite their technical feasibility for modeling purposes, from a practical standpoint they cannot be implemented without deep insider knowledge (all internal and external contract terms) of the particular asset management firm being modeled.

  2. We also use GICS (Global Industry Classification System) codes to ensure that the matched manager is a pure asset manager.

  3. These data are given in Columns 5, 7, 9, 11, and 13 of Table 1.

  4. Influential data points are discovered by calculating Cooks distance for each regression. BX (Blackrock) and KKR (Kohlberg/Kravies/Roberts) are identified as influential (Cooks distance exceeding 1).

  5. Optionality in fee income would render the dividend discount model as a theoretical tool close to useless. Empirically, our approach might still work if income from performance-based fees is reasonably steady, i.e., if the optionality does not materialize. Asset management firms with performance-based fees have an even stronger incentive to monitor capacity and limit assets under management as eroding alpha cuts directly into their revenue stream.

  6. See Scherer (2010, 2011) concerning real-world frictions and their effect on optimal risk management by asset management firms.

  7. Suppose the CAPM is used as our asset pricing model. Then the risk-adjusted discount rate for fees on a US small cap portfolio would be the expected returns on those stocks, or \(R=R_{\mathrm {US}\_\mathrm{small}\_\mathrm{cap}} =r_f +\hat{b} _{\mathrm {US}\_\mathrm{small}\_\mathrm{cap}} \left( {R_{\mathrm {US}\_\mathrm{market}\_\mathrm{portfolio}}} -r_f \right) \).

References

  • Berk, J.B., Green, R.C.: Mutual fund flows and performance in rational markets. J. Polit. Econ. 112, 1269–1295 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, S., Pfleiderer, P.: Delegated portfolio management. J. Econ. Theory 36, 1–25 (1985)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudoukh, J., Richardson, M., Stanton, R., Whitelaw, R.: The Economics of Asset Management, NYU Stern Working Paper (2004)

  • Chevalier, J., Ellison, G.: Risk taking by mutual funds as a response to incentives. J. Polit. Econ. 105, 1167–1200 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dangl, T., Wu, Y., Zechner, J.: Market discipline and internal governance in the mutual fund industry. Rev. Financ. Stud. 21(5), 2307–2343 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E., MacBeth, J.: Risk, return and equilibrium: empirical tests. J. Polit. Econ. 81, 607–636 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goetzmann, W.N., Ingersoll, J., Ross, S.A.: High watermarks and hedge fund management contracts. J. Financ. 58, 1685–1717 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huberman, G.: What is the NPV of Expected Future Profits of Money Managers? Working Paper, Columbia University (2004)

  • Pastor, L., Stambaugh, R.F., Taylor, L.: Scale and skill in active management. J. Financ. Econ. 116(1), 23–45 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M.: Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: comparing approaches. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22(1), 435–480 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S.A.: A Neoclassical Look at Behavioral Finance: The Closed End Funds Puzzle (Chapter 4). Princeton University Press, Princeton (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, B.: Should asset managers hedge their fees at risk? J. Appl. Corp. Financ. 22(4), 96–102 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, B.: Market risks in asset management companies. Quant. Financ. 12(10), 1547–1556 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., Kahneman, D.: Belief in the law of small numbers. Psychol. Bull. 76, 105–110 (1971)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bernd Scherer.

Appendix: Present-value model for asset management firms

Appendix: Present-value model for asset management firms

We decompose the earnings of an asset management firm (for any given year) into the product of assets under management, percentage fees, and operating margins:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {Earnings}=\hbox {AuM}\times \frac{\hbox {Revenues}}{\hbox {AuM}}\times \frac{\hbox {Earnings}}{\hbox {Revenues}}=\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

We now ask: What is the value of this earnings stream over n years? Let r denote the return on a given asset management mandate (e.g., a mutual fund) gross of fees but net of trading costs, and let R be the return on its “benchmark” (the comparable, or risk-adjusted, market return). First, we write the earnings for the (equity) owners of the asset management firm at the end of year 1—while assuming zero capital inflows and fees that are applied to the end-of-period net asset value—as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {Earnings}_1 =\hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) fq. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

What is left to the investors in the asset management firm’s products then amounts to

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) \left( {1-f}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(11)

A more general expression for earnings at the end of year i is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {Earnings}_i =\hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) ^{i}\left( {1-f}\right) ^{i-1}fq. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

The series of cash flows to discount can then be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {Earnings}_1= & {} \hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) fq,\nonumber \\ \hbox {Earnings}_2= & {} \hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) ^{2}\left( {1-f}\right) fq,\nonumber \\ \hbox {Earnings}_3= & {} \hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) ^{3}\left( {1-f}\right) ^{2}fq,\nonumber \\&\vdots&\nonumber \\ \hbox {Earnings}_n= & {} \hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) ^{n}\left( {1-f}\right) ^{n-1}fq. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

At what rate should these cash flows be discounted? That is, what is the discount rate for cash flows containing the same form of systematic risks? A natural choice for such risk-adjusted returns are benchmark returns.Footnote 7 These lead to the specification of the following discounted cash flow model:

$$\begin{aligned} P\left( n\right)= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r} \right) fq}{1+R}+\frac{\hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) ^{2}\left( {1-f} \right) fq}{\left( {1+R}\right) ^{2}} \nonumber \\&+\cdots +\,\frac{\hbox {AuM}\left( {1+r}\right) ^{n}\left( {1-f}\right) ^{n-1}fq}{\left( {1+R} \right) ^{n}}. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Further simplification results in

$$\begin{aligned} P\left( n\right)= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q}{1-f}\left[ {\mathop {\sum }\limits _{i=1}^n \left( {\frac{\left( {1+r} \right) \left( {1-f}\right) }{1+R}}\right) ^{i}} \right] \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q}{1-f}\left[ {\frac{\frac{\left( {1+r}\right) \left( {1-f}\right) }{1+R}-\left( {\frac{\left( {1+r}\right) \left( {1-f}\right) }{1+R}} \right) ^{n+1}}{1-\frac{\left( {1+r}\right) \left( {1-f} \right) }{1+R}}}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(15)

To create more insight into Eq. (15), we assume \(r=R\); that is, the performance gross of fees equals the benchmark performance (hence alpha equals zero). Then

$$\begin{aligned} P=P\left( n\right) =\hbox {AuM}\times q\left[ {1-\left( {1-f} \right) ^{n-1}}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Assuming an infinite time horizon \(\left( {n=\infty }\right) \), we arrive at Eq. (3) in the main text:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P}{\hbox {AuM}}=q. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

We can extend the model by adding alpha to portfolio returns; recall that \(\left( {1+r}\right) =\left( {1+R}\right) \left( {1+a} \right) \). Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} P\left( n\right)= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q}{1-f}\left[ {\mathop {\sum }\limits _{i=1}^n \left( {\frac{\left( {1+r}\right) \left( {1-f}\right) }{1+R}}\right) ^{i}}\right] \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q}{1-f}\left[ {\mathop {\sum }\limits _{i=1}^n \left( {\frac{\left( {1+R}\right) \left( {1-a} \right) \left( {1-f}\right) }{1+R}}\right) ^{i}}\right] \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q}{1-f}\left[ {\mathop {\sum }\limits _{i=1}^n \left( {\left( {1+a}\right) \left( {1-f}\right) } \right) ^{i}}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(18)

We also assume that \(\left( {1+a}\right) \left( {1-f}\right) =1\); that is, \(f=a\left( {1-f}\right) \). Thus, fees are set so as to leave the client with no alpha. Adjusting Eq. (18) to reflect these equalities yields

$$\begin{aligned} P\left( n\right)= & {} \frac{\hbox {AuM}\times f\times q}{1-f}\left[ {\mathop {\sum }\limits _{i=1}^n 1^{i}}\right] =\frac{\hbox {AuM}\times a\times \left( {1-f}\right) \times q}{1-f}\left[ {\mathop {\sum }\limits _{i=1}^n 1^{i}}\right] \nonumber \\= & {} \hbox {AuM}\times a\times q\times n. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Hence, it is clear that when alpha is not limited, the firm valuation goes to infinity.

Now suppose the asset management company receives a fixed level of earnings forever because its assets under management are fixed at full capacity, \({\mathbf{AuM}}^{*}\). In this case, the firm’s earnings are

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {Earnings}=\hbox {AuM}^{*}\times f\times q. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Discounting this cash flow to infinity creates a corresponding firm value, \(p^{*}\), of

$$\begin{aligned} p^{*}= & {} \mathop {\lim }\limits _{n\rightarrow \infty } \left[ {\frac{\hbox {AuM}^{*}\times q\times f}{1+r}+\frac{\hbox {AuM}^{*}\times q\times f}{\left( {1+r} \right) ^{2}}+\cdots +\frac{\hbox {AuM}^{*}\times q\times f}{\left( {1+r}\right) ^{n}}}\right] \nonumber \\= & {} \hbox {AuM}^{*}\times q\times f\left[ {\frac{1}{1+r}+\frac{1}{\left( {1+r}\right) ^{2}}+\cdots +\frac{1}{\left( {1+r}\right) ^{n}}}\right] \nonumber \\= & {} \hbox {AuM}^{*}\times q\times f\left[ {\frac{\frac{1}{1+r}-\frac{1}{\left( {1+r} \right) ^{n+1}}}{1-\frac{1}{1+r}}}\right] \nonumber \\= & {} \hbox {AuM}^{*}\times q\times f\left[ {\frac{1}{r}}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(21)

This expression is equal to Eq. (5) in the main text.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Joenväärä, J., Scherer, B. A note on the valuation of asset management firms. Financ Mark Portf Manag 31, 181–199 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11408-017-0287-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11408-017-0287-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation