“Give a man a fish and he will eat for a day. Give a woman microcredit, and she, her husband, her children, and her extended family will eat for a lifetime” (Bono 2010, page 1).

But who feeds (repays) the lender?

Introduction

Microcredit has grown exponentially since 1983 and is viewed as a revolutionary tool for global poverty alleviation (Yunus 1999).Footnote 1 The rise in prominence is attributed to the joint-liability lending model pioneered by Grameen Bank whereby traditional lender requirements for physical collateral are bypassed through mutual responsibility for individual loans. Theoretical hypotheses predict microcredit groups outperform others in the joint-liability setting, however the extent to which this contributes to repayment rates in excess of 95 % in microcredit remains unexplained. The shift in world industry structure toward for-profit lendersFootnote 2 means sustainability of this annual US$ 38 billionFootnote 3 global market is contingent on the application of these theories in practice.

Theoretical hypotheses predict sustainable long-run repayment as microcredit groups foster positive non-economic social ties from interactions. From a borrower perspective, joint-liability suggests individuals in microcredit groups show moral discipline by foregoing short-run benefits from non-repayment in preference for long-run dynamic gains from repayment. Joint-liability success utilises social ties between microcredit borrowers (Besley and Coate 1995; Ghatak and Guinnane 1999); however it incentivizes free riding (Kono 2013). There remains dispute among lenders on the optimal observable individual and group characteristics to maximise repayment.

Empirical results from repeated experimental games used to model joint-liability settings are applied alongside questionnaire findings to test the theoretical hypotheses, with particular focus on differences between treated microcredit borrower groups compared to the control non-microcredit borrower groups.Footnote 4 The author conducts the games in the district of Manikganj, Dhaka, Bangladesh.

Results from the joint-liability games show evidence of treated groups more likely choosing repayment and subsequently partaking in more rounds compared to control groups. This holds even controlling for unobservable development of relationships over time among treated groups. Treated individuals also comparatively forego short-run gains from non-repayment to benefit from higher long-run dynamic gains. Furthermore they are less likely to free ride and more likely to shoulder (support) partners compared to controls, suggesting relative fostering of social ties. From a lender perspective, this paper identifies characteristics including female-gender and neighbours that optimise repayment. However it finds factors such as income and age are insignificant contrary to popular thought.

Related Literature

Microcredit gained traction subsequent to implementation of joint-liability lending.Footnote 5 Between 1997 and 2005 the number of clients increased by 740 % and institutions by 406 %.Footnote 6 Higher market concentration and transition toward for-profit lenders demand repayment rates in excess of 95 % for sustainability (Hossain 1988; Morduch 1999).Footnote 7 Theoretically, joint-liability success revolves around social ties within groups which counteract three key problems:Footnote 8 moral hazardFootnote 9 (Banerjee et al. 1994; Laffont and Rey 2003), adverse selectionFootnote 10 (Ghatak 1999; Gangopadhyay et al. 2005), and free ridingFootnote 11 (Besley and Coate 1995; Wydick 2001; Bhole and Ogden 2010). This paper isolates free riding, extending games by Kono (2013) by setting income exogenously and randomly selecting participants to control for moral hazard and adverse selection respectively.

Focusing therefore on social tiesFootnote 12 as a solution to free riding, Besley and Coate (1995) and Ghatak and Guinnane (1999) theoretically prove high social ties deter group member shirking on repayments.Footnote 13 The former model defines benefits from repaying through dynamic incentivesFootnote 14 of future loans and avoiding social punishment. The latter uses historic and contemporary examples as proof, although there is ambiguity on the extent social ties explain the increased repayment.

Cason et al. (2012) and Zeller (1998) empirically show stronger social ties lead to improved repayment rates and lender profitability if it exceeds monitoring costs. Abbink et al. (2006) finds group-lending to outperform individual-lending, although curiously self-selected groups show a higher yet less stable willingness to repay. This variance can be explained by contagion, a subset of group free riding where dominant strategy for individuals is to default should they observe high likelihood of default by the group. Contagion in joint-liability is evident in Mexico (Allen 2012), Pakistan (Kurosaki and Khan 2012) and India (Breza 2012). Abbink et al. (2006) provides evidence that the larger the loans, the bigger the incentive to free ride although the less lender and group tolerance toward defaulters. Inability to control behavioural endogeneity which positively influences social ties and repayment is persistent across empirics.

The counter-hypothesis is social ties reduce repayment through forgiveness toward defaults (Guinnane 1994). Empirical study by Wydick (1999) and Cassar et al. (2007) applying games by Abbink et al. (2006) in Guatemala, South Africa, and Armenia respectively emphasise no significant gains from social ties, particularly for the latter comparing acquaintance groups against strangers.Footnote 15 The unobservable social ties are however measured by weakly correlated proxy dependant variables in the game structure which invalidate findings.

Theoretical research into changes from joint-liability to individual-liability hypothesise decreases in repayment ceteris paribus for groups with sufficient social ties (Banerjee et al. 1994), empirical examples being Peru where there is positive correlation between intra-group trustworthiness and strong social ties with higher repayment rates (Karlan 2005; Karlan 2007). In contrast, other experiments show no difference after change from joint to individual liability (Giné and Yang 2009; Giné and Karlan 2009). Against popular literature, the latter deems excessive pressure of joint-liability to discourage good borrowers. The consensus however supports social ties, alongside features such as dynamic incentives and frequent installment as important drivers of repayment rather than joint-liability itself (Armendáriz de Aghion and Morduch 2010). Townsend (2003) describes under theories of selection the ambiguity of Pareto optimal regimes subject to exogenous environmental characteristics. Joint-liability as a cure to free riding cannot be exemplified through one theory.

Comparing alternative game structures, findings in Malawi suggest no difference in repayment between joint and individual-liability (Schaefer-Kehnert 1980). Kono (2006) counter-intuitively finds Vietnamese borrowers have lower repayment rates under joint-liability, even with peer monitoring and punishments through social ties. Thai microcredit programs show similar patterns of negative effects on repayment from social ties. Positive gains to repayment are found to be possible only through high local sanctions and correlated returns (Ahlin and Townsend 2007). Critically, however, the empirics did not control for other lending characteristics and endogenous selection of borrowers, and questions are raised at the excess regional variability. Kono (2013) bypasses endogeneity problems in conducting framed joint-liability experiments in Vietnam. His empirical findings conclude free-riding exceeds players helping group members, resulting in relative underperformance of joint-liability.

To the author’s knowledge, this paper is the first to investigate differences in repayment decisions between treated groups of microcredit borrowers and control groups of non-microcredit borrowers in identical joint-liability settings through game theoretical application. Attanasio et al. (2001) and Duflo et al. (2013) pioneered comparisons with treated groups. However, the studies focus on poverty alleviation for women and development effects respectively.

Model

This paper models joint-liability settings through repeated experimental games to compare actions of treated microcredit groups against control non-microcredit groups, and in particular identifies the role of social ties versus free riding. The methodology used extends the model of repayment decisions utilised by Kono (2013).

The game is designed where at the beginning of each round each player i is allocated a stochastic income \( {g}_i\in \left[0,\overline{g_i}\right] \) which is independent and identically distributed over individuals and rounds, representing exogenous investment returns funded by the loans.Footnote 16 Players in an n-person group are required to pay a repayment sum of nB collectively. Player i first chooses the action r i of whether to repay personal liability, B. If yes (r i  = B), then player i is given the choice to shoulder (repay) d i toward any remaining group liabilities. Repayment is dynamically incentivised as participation in the next round contingent on full group repayment such that \( {\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{r}_i}+{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{d}_i}=nB \). Otherwise, all members in the group are eliminated. This represents borrowers only being able to access further loans subject to full group repayment under joint-liability irrespective of individual repayment decisions.Footnote 17 The discount factor, λ, is applied between periods to replicate a finite time horizon to the games where irrespective of outcome the game may end with probability 1/6 after each round (λ = 5/6).Footnote 18 Utility for player i of not receiving loans (thus inability to invest) is 0.

The model assumes for two-player groups (n = 2) that all players are unable to engage in any strategic interaction within groups outside of the experiment,Footnote 19 and that each stage is independent from the previous (players cannot save income from past periods). In contrast to prior experiments, imperfect monitoring is assumed whereby players cannot observe their group members’ income levels and decisions, and can only observe personal income, g i , and personal decisions r i and d i ; hence players are unable to determine with certainty if group members are free riding. Note that if the group defaults where \( {\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{r}_i}+{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{d}_i}<nB \), player i loses r i  + d i as the lender does not return an individual’s repayment.Footnote 20 Lender terms are not considered and are assumed to be homogenous as it does not contribute to the paper’s focus on individual choice in a joint-liability setting.

The order of the decisions in round t can be summarised as follows:

  1. 1.

    Players i = 1, 2 are allocated stochastic income gi and simultaneously choose their repayment amount, r i , where i = 1, 2. The decisions (r i , r j ) are observed by both players.

  2. 2a.

    If r i  = r j  = B then both players have met group repayment conditions for the round.

  3. 2b.

    If r i  = B but r j  < B, j ≠ i, then player i has the option of shouldering (paying) d i  = B − r j for the deficit of player j. By joint-liability, both players meet group repayment conditions for the round only in the scenario where player i pays the full deficit of player j. Vice versa if r j  = B but r i  < B, j ≠ i.

  4. 2c.

    If r i , r j  < B, both players have not met group repayment conditions for the round (group default) and are eliminated.

  5. 3.

    Given that both players have met group repayment conditions for the round where \( {\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{r}_i}+{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{d}_i}=nB \), progression onto the next round is conditional on the discount factor λ = 5/6.

  6. 4.

    Both players in groups that progress participate in a further repetition in round t + 1.

Experimental Procedures

The repeated experimental game is conducted in five rural villages in Manikganj, Bangladesh in December 2014. The experiments are conducted in village centres on random groups of n = 2 players, sampling 10 % of the population from each village. Participating players first complete a verbal questionnaire before an explanation on taking part in the game.Footnote 21 This includes information on variables including if the group is a treated microcredit or control non-microcredit group.Footnote 22

The repeated game is then administered. Stochastic income for each player at the start of each period is privately allocated through the sum of the points of three randomly allocated cards, each representing either 10 points or 0 points forming three possible income values: g ∈ {0, 10, 20}. Footnote 23 The probability distribution of g i is determined by q = (q 0, q 10, q 20) where given q g  = Pr(g i  = g), let q = (25 %, 25 %, 50 %). Each player then simultaneously submits a card face down to represent repayment (10) or default (0). Should player i default, player j is then given the option of shouldering and must submit a further card face down to shoulder on their behalf (10) or otherwise (0). Players have satisfied group liabilities upon total group repayment of value 20. If satisfied, progress onto the next repeated round is contingent on not rolling six on a standard six-sided dice.Footnote 24 Figure 1 illustrates the game tree for player i in the repeated experimental game.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Game tree

Players are given economic incentives in the field experiments to better reflect reality. Each player earns a fixed fee of 50 taka for the opportunity cost of participation, and a variable bonus of 10 taka for each 10 card that is unused for repayment and accumulated at game end. This replicates incentives of short-run gains from free riding and long-run gains from cooperation to participate in future rounds.

To prevent implications on external social ties, players cannot observe group member’s income levels (cards allocated). ProshikarFootnote 25 also runs a regional monopoly in microcredit lending in Manikganj, hence it is rational to assume near homogenous terms of lending to treated groups.Footnote 26

Dataset

The dataset records 430 players forming 215 groups sampling 10 % of the population by five villages in Manikganj. Treated groups make up 40 % which is upward biased given the willingness for microcredit borrowers to participate.Footnote 27 Summary statistics show a balanced range of observations. Gender is split male: female at 49: 51 overall, but 64 % female in the treated groups confirming preference toward female empowerment by lenders. Age follows a quadratic relationship with the majority of the sample between 21 and 40 years oldFootnote 28; treated groups contribute strongly as microcredit is directed toward the most able-bodied (86 % treated, 58 % control). Muslims make up 91 % with the Hindu 9 % minority predominantly from Shahapara.Footnote 29 No significant religious differences for treated groups suggests Islamic principles against lending are not practised due to necessity for credit.

Statistics document low financial-economic status with 31 % of workers earning below the poverty line of “$1-a-day” (Ravallion et al. 2009).Footnote 30 Forty-four percent of treated individuals (22 % of control) live below the threshold, providing evidence of microcredit geared toward poverty alleviation. Agriculture is the predominant occupation (51 %) followed by garments (11 %) and labour (8 %) given proximity to garment factories and brick-fields. Socio-economic status is poor; 54 % report no education and 67 % are educated below expected literacy.Footnote 31 There has however been improvement as parental education records 76 % with none and 87 % below literacy. Households are large with the mean number of children, siblings and dependants at 2.1, 2.2 and 2.2 respectively. Smoking is reported by 3 %, however this is dropped due to misrepresentation given its negative connotation with lending is well-known. There are no significant group differences in age or education for the treated, although there is suggestion that gender, job and income differences are minimized in treated groups. The premise is improved social ties in homogenous groups.

Theoretical Hypotheses

Hypothesis 1

Treated microcredit groups are more sustainable borrowers than control non-microcredit groups under joint-liability.

Individuals in treated groups choose repayment and subsequently progress onto more rounds compared to control groups under joint-liability controlling for other characteristics. Theory hypothesises stronger social ties from past interactions to promote non-economic factors of cooperation and trust within treated groups, hence more rounds are played in the repeated games. This effect is forecasted to increase positively with the number of years the group has been together.

Hypothesis 2

Treated microcredit groups forego short-run gains from non-repayment in preference for long-run dynamic gains compared to control non-microcredit groups under joint-liability.

Treated group individuals are predicted to earn less income in the short-run given rounds played as they choose repayment, but dynamic gains from participation in more total rounds as a consequence leads to higher total income overall compared to control groups. Theory anticipates treated groups show moral discipline; they forego short-run gains preferring that longer-term gains from future loans. The hypothesis also expects mutual gains from lending to treated groups: lenders are more likely repaid and treated borrowers make higher long-run gains.

Hypothesis 3

Developments in non-economic factors foster social ties which encourage shouldering and discourage free riding within treated microcredit groups compared to control non-microcredit groups.

Treated groups show significant development of social ties which promote shouldering (supporting partners) and deter free riding as a consequence of non-economic factors increasing cooperation and relationships. Theoretically treated groups are significantly more likely to shoulder (support) their partner and less likely to free ride compared to control groups under joint-liability (Besley and Coate 1995; Ghatak and Guinnane 1999).

Hypothesis 4

Lenders can maximise repayment rates under joint-liability by selecting individuals/groups that meet optimal characteristics.

Theory suggests various observable characteristics of individuals and groups that can maximise repayment decisions. Controlling for differences between treated and control groups, there are optimal physical, individual, relational, and group characteristics.Footnote 32

Literature on physical characteristics supports female lending as females are risk averse with loan investment (Armendáriz de Aghion and Morduch 2010) and are genetically dutiful with payments (D’Espallier et al. 2011). Lenders also choose to lend to the able-bodied aged 20 to 30, who are most likely to earn repayment returns and to seize the initiative for future loans.

From a relational perspective, blood relatives and neighbours likely have the strongest social ties, albeit at marginal risk that they anticipate a partner’s bad repayment behaviour. Inconclusive evidence suggests that the group support mentality increases with marriage, children, siblings, and dependants. Conversely, emotional constraints may reduce the willingness to support additional others. Popular thought suggests that higher parental education is positively correlated with childhood teachings on right-and-wrong, and that village differences affect social ties.

Predictions regarding individual attributes are uncertain. Increased education increases repayment due to the strong positive correlation with good behaviour, however educated players may attempt to cheat the system. Similarly higher incomes and savings mean relative repayments are less of a burden, but also diminish the dynamic incentive for future loans. Optimal job guidelines are broad, allowing for any possibility that loan investment can be made into self-employment schemes.

Maximum repayment is anticipated from homogenous groups on the premise that they show improved social ties. Group members build stronger relationship when related in age, education and gender. Similar lifestyles and challenges from equal income, occupation and marital status also positively impact group repayment.

Empirical Results

Empirical findings from the questionnaire and repeated experimental games are recorded and analysed. The field experiments are used to empirically test the four key theoretical hypotheses proposed in “Theoretical Hypotheses.” The cross-sectional data is econometrically analysed by ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions and maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) binary estimation.

The key dependant variables analysed are as follows: rounds measures sustainability of joint-liability, counting the number of rounds the group plays and repays. Points represent total earnings by the individual for the duration of the game (number of 10 cards accumulated and unused for repayment). Binary variables shoul and free determine whether an individual chose to shoulder or free ride respectively throughout the game.

Preliminary Findings

Preliminary analyses illustrated in Fig. 2 suggest treated groups perform differently than control groups as hypothesised. Treated groups have a 91 % higher mean rounds played at 4.18 rounds versus 2.20 rounds for control groups. They also score 53 % more points on average (1.90 versus 1.24 points) throughout the duration of the game. This provides evidence treated groups comparatively play more rounds and score more total points.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Illustrations of preliminary findings: points scored and rounds played

Of treated individuals, 79 % shouldered for partners compared to 59 % for the controls as in Fig. 3. Treated players are also significantly less likely to free ride at only 15 % compared to 40 % in control groups. There is the suggestion of comparatively stronger non-economic social ties encouraging shouldering and discouraging free riding.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Illustrations of preliminary findings: shouldering and free riding

Testing Hypothesis 1

Major Model: Rounds

To determine sustainability under joint-liability between treated and control groups, an OLS regression with dependant variable rounds and the main explanatory variable microcredit is analysed. Model C in Table 1 shows the final output given by:

$$ \begin{array}{r}\hfill rounds=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 sex+{\beta}_3 blood\_rel+{\beta}_4 see\_ house+{\beta}_5i. vill+{\beta}_6i. educ+{\beta}_7i. job\\ {}\hfill +{\beta}_8 educ\_ diff+{\beta}_9 job\_ diff+\varepsilon \end{array} $$
Table 1 Hypothesis 1 OLS regression results

Model C provides evidence verifying that treated microcredit groups are significantly more sustainable borrowers than control groups. Treated groups play 1.771 more rounds compared to controls, all other significant covariates held constant. Robustness of the finding is confirmed as the hypothesis holds true when introducing further insignificant covariates based on the literature and on all observed variables with treated groups partaking in 1.723 and 1.711 more rounds respectively compared to control groups.

Minor Model: Rounds Controlling for Relationship over Time

To isolate the difference in sustainability between treated and control groups controlling for relationship development from past interactions under the joint-liability setting in treated groups, the covariate years_partner is added as a proxy for unobservable growth in cooperation and trust. The extended Model D in Table 1 shows the following:

$$ \begin{array}{r}\hfill rounds=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 years\_ partner+{\beta}_3 sex+{\beta}_4 blood\_rel+{\beta}_5 see\_ house+{\beta}_6i. vill\\ {}\hfill +{\beta}_7i. educ+{\beta}_8i. job+{\beta}_9 educ\_ diff+{\beta}_{1 0} job\_ diff+\varepsilon \end{array} $$

In line with theory, the coefficient on years_partner dictates that treated groups play 0.486 more rounds for every additional year of having taken microcredit loans together, suggesting increasing social ties with past interactions. Introducing this proxy for relationship development over time explains 48.5 %Footnote 33 of the difference between treated and control groups in Model C; hypothesis 1 still holds true as treated groups nevertheless play 0.912 more rounds than controls ceteris paribus. This result unambiguously supports joint-liability, suggesting sustainable repayment by groups entrusted with loans comparable to otherwise controlling for relationship growth over time. This suggests success in passing responsibility onto borrowers and in lender initiatives such as group meetings and local ambassadors, although further research beyond the dataset is required.

Note the coefficient on microcredit is likely negatively biased as growth in social ties over time outside of borrowing situations may exponentially impact control groups more and is not controlled for as relationship measures are subjective. However the assumption that this affects all groups linearly (constant marginal returns to relationship development) means the bias should not significantly change the difference in rounds played between treated and control groups.

Testing Hypothesis 2

Major Model: Points

To analyse long-run gains to joint-liability borrowers, an OLS regression is run on points from the experimental games with the main independent variable of microcredit among other covariates. Model C in Table 2 shows:

$$ \begin{array}{r}\hfill points=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 sex+{\beta}_3i. vill+{\beta}_4i. parental\_ educ+{\beta}_5 relig+{\beta}_6 house\_ income\\ {}\hfill +{\beta}_7 save+{\beta}_8i. job+\varepsilon \end{array} $$
Table 2 Hypothesis 2 OLS regression result

Results validate the theoretical predictions under Hypothesis 2 as treated groups accumulate 0.589 more points than controls ceteris paribus. This is interpreted as earning a significantly higher total income of 5.89 taka comparatively from the experimental games. It is supported by findings in Hypothesis 1 where treated groups play more rounds as it is logical to assume additional rounds lead to more points accumulated given the nature of the game. Robustness checks including covariates based on theory and all observable variables find the hypothesis holds, with treated groups scoring significantly more points 0.607 and 0.612 respectively.

Major Model: Points Controlling for Rounds

To test if treated groups forego short-run gains, a similar OLS regression is modelled with points as the dependant variable and microcredit as the main independent variable, however this time including ‘controls’ for rounds. Model D in Table 2 shows the specification:

$$ \begin{array}{r}\hfill points=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 sex+{\beta}_3i. vill+{\beta}_4i. parental\_ educ+{\beta}_5 relig+{\beta}_6 house\_ income\\ {}\hfill +{\beta}_7 save+{\beta}_8i. job+^{\prime } controls^{\prime }+\varepsilon \end{array} $$

By controlling for rounds the interpretation of coefficients is the difference in points scored for a fixed number of rounds played. Hypothesis 2 predicts a significantly negative coefficient on microcredit as treated groups are theoretically predicted to show moral discipline and repay in each round, thus earning less over rounds than had they shirked. Empirical findings confirm a negative coefficient of −0.160, however it is statistically insignificant. Further inspection of Fig. 4 infers a problem of lack of observations above six rounds played by control groups. The regression in Model D+ in Table 2 is run as a correction, restricting observations up to six rounds played.Footnote 34 Microcredit becomes significant and treated groups score 0.280 fewer points than controls for fixed rounds played as hypothesised; treated groups indeed forego 2.80 taka of short-run gains from non-repayment.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Bar chart to show mean points scored between treated and control groups, over rounds

Testing Hypothesis 3

Major Model: Shouldering

Maximum likelihood estimation is used focusing on probitFootnote 35 binary estimation results for the variable shoul to test if treated groups show a higher likelihood of shouldering compared to control groups. The main independent variable is microcredit as in Probit C in Table 3:

$$ \begin{array}{r}\hfill shoul=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 age+{\beta}_3 sex+{\beta}_4 see\_ house+{\beta}_5 children+{\beta}_6i. vill+{\beta}_7 relig+{\beta}_8i. job\\ {}\hfill +{\beta}_9 school\_ diff+\varepsilon \end{array} $$
Table 3 Hypothesis 3 free riding and shouldering binary estimation results

Relatively stronger social ties in treated groups predict fostering of non-economic factors toward shouldering for a partner’s repayment. Empirically, treated groups are indeed 26.6 % more likely to shoulder compared to control groups ceteris paribus. Results are consistent and significant applying alternative estimation methods of logit estimation (Logit C) and linear probability model (LPM C); 25.7 and 22.9 % more likely for the treated, respectively. Robustness checks are confirmed on Probit A and Probit B models.

Major Model: Free Riding

Econometric techniques are next applied to the variable free for which the hypothesis anticipates microcredit to have a significant negative coefficient. The interpretation is that treated groups have a lower likelihood of free riding compared to control groups. As in Probit C in Table 3:

$$ free=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 sex+{\beta}_3 blood\_rel+{\beta}_4i. vill+{\beta}_5 house\_ income+{\beta}_6i. job+\varepsilon $$

Results show individuals in treated groups are 27.4 % significantly less likely to free ride on their partner as hypothesised. This provides evidence toward stronger social ties within treated groups, and is further confirmed by consistent findings when applying alternative estimation methods of Logit C and LPM C, 25.8 and 26.2 % less likely respectively.

Interpretation of Independent Variables for Shouldering and Free Riding

Different factors variably influence non-economic social tie drivers of shouldering and free riding when comparing the significance of covariatesFootnote 36 holding constant differences between treated and control groups.

Physically, females are 17.3 % more likely to shoulder and 10.1 % less likely to free ride than male counterparts as reconciled by gender economics (D’Espallier et al. 2011). Each additional year in age increases shouldering probability by 1 %. This suggests younger generations are less inclined to help partners, whether to avoid income loss or weaker social ties given fewer years in the community, yet this is not reflecting in free riding for which character dominates and is constant irrespective of age.

Relationship factors show neighbours are 20.3 % more likely to shoulder and blood relatives 18.2 %; less likely to free ride. Overlap whereby blood relatives locate in close proximity to neighbours distorts individual effects, but there is clear overall significance. Furthermore each additional child decreases the likelihood of shouldering by 8.9 % as parent’s face emotional constraints. For each additional child’s needs they are less inclined to help borrowing partners. Culturally, Hindus are 40.2 % more likely to shoulder than Muslims, all else constant, due to collectiveness among the religious minority in Manikganj.Footnote 37 There are also significant differences between villages, with inconclusive proof that smaller populations show comparatively stronger internal social ties. Free riding shows no difference given character is its main driver which is ambiguous over religion and children.

For individual variables, each additional taka of annual household income decreases the probability of free riding by 0.320 % as there is reduced necessity for guaranteed short-run earnings. Surprisingly this is not replicated for shouldering but the explanation is that relationship factors dominate. Occupation significantly explains shouldering and free riding. Of particular note are housewives and woodcutters compared to agriculture due to the prior fostering motherly behaviour and strong social ties in occupational community in the latter.

Group differences in age, gender, marital status, income and occupation to optimise non-economic factors is minimally significant contrary to popular thought regarding homogeneity. There is only a suggestion that each additional year gap in schooling between partners increases shouldering. This may be due to the highly educated pitying partners and the lowly educated supporting inferiority.

Testing Hypothesis 4

OLS regression specifications in Table 4 with rounds as the dependant variable are used to identify optimal characteristics to maximise joint-liability repayment. Rounds are a measure of returns to lenders as further rounds are contingent on group repayment. Initial specifications on individual and group characteristics are refined for combination toward optimal characteristicsFootnote 38 specified below. Note microcredit is retained to control for differences between treated and control groups.

Table 4 Hypothesis 4 OLS regression results
$$ \begin{array}{r}\hfill rounds=\alpha +{\beta}_1 microcredit+{\beta}_2 sex+{\beta}_3 blood\_rel+{\beta}_4 see\_ house+{\beta}_5i. vill+{\beta}_6i. educ+{\beta}_7i. job\\ {}\hfill +{\beta}_8 educ\_ diff+{\beta}_9 job\_ diff+\varepsilon \end{array} $$

The physical optimum in favour of female empowerment is to lend to females who are more sustainable borrowers, playing 0.934 more rounds than male counterparts. Age is not seen to impact repayment choice, disproving the notion of young workers having stronger motivation to repay future loans to escape poverty. However this overlooks age affecting ability to work and generate income for repayment as game income is set exogenously independent of productivity.

Based on relationships, lenders maximizing repayment from blood relatives and neighbours depicts strong social ties as hypothesised, playing 0.641 and 0.915 more rounds than otherwise. Cooperation is higher and there is significant opportunity cost of punishment from losing trust in these groups. The data also find no significant evidence to select borrowers based on children, siblings, dependants or upbringing based on parental education affecting the helping mentality. There is however significant varying strength of cultural relationships between village groups, although further research is required to pinpoint drivers.Footnote 39

Focusing on the individual, lower education promotes repayment, confirming the theory that better educated players attempt to ‘cheat the system’ by not repaying. Significant levels are at Class 7, O-Level and Masters who participate in 1.565, 0.980 and 1.535 rounds less than baseline no education, respectively. The financial variables of income and savings are insignificant in influencing repayment. The story may be that increases in income or savings lead to less repayment burden but also less dynamic incentive for future loans which trade-off perfectly in equilibrium. It is more likely, however, that by setting income exogenously and not incorporating the possibility of financial losses, borrowers do not act realistically based on financials. Against acceptance of a broad return on jobs, the analysis finds more significance should be placed on occupation. There are higher long-run repayments from workers in predominantly niche forms of employment that form small work-communities as they better cooperate: messengers (+2.245), fisherman (+1.962), craftsman (+3.765) and woodcutters (+1.593) play more rounds than baseline agriculture workers who make up 51 % of sampled treated borrowers.

Optimal group criteria suggest same sex groups perform better by 0.483 rounds compared to others, however, it is inconclusive when controlling for individual characteristics. Robustness checks confirm repayment differences due to individual gender explain the majority of the variation in group gender. Age difference is insignificant disproving less cooperation for bigger age gaps between partners. Partners with differing education levels play 0.450 less rounds than the identically educated. Highly educated players chose non-repayment to attempt to cheat lenders and their partners, particularly if educational differences exist with the latter. Group income disparity shows no significance which can be explained by similar lifestyles over the range of incomes observed. Negative non-economic factors such as jealousy are not problematic as the population has 90,413 taka mean annual household income with 48,058 standard deviation.Footnote 40 The availability of goods for conspicuous consumption is constrained and anyone with high income relocates away from rural villages. Moreover homogenous job groups outperform others by 0.450 rounds, placing importance on relationships within work communities.

Concluding Remarks

Pioneering repeated experimental games are modelled to evaluate social ties and free riding under practical joint-liability microcredit borrowing in Bangladesh. Focus is given to repayment decisions by treated microcredit borrower-groups compared to control non-microcredit groups. The paper hypothesises and empirically challenges key theories.

Empirical evidence supports theoretical predictions of more sustainable treated groups likely repaying loans and participating in more rounds compared to control groups. Treated groups foster positive non-economic social ties from repeated interactions. This holds controlling for past joint-liability interactions over time, but relationship growth outside of this is assumed to equally affect all groups. Partial solutions would be to measure number of years groups have known each other or to include subjective measures of relationship strength.

Treated individuals in the experiments show moral discipline as hypothesised, foregoing short-run gains from non-repayment to benefit from higher dynamic long-run total earnings. A second-best policy of restricting rounds is however essential to conclude significantly lower short-run earnings for treated group. First-best policy would be to expand the dataset, sampling 20 % of all populations or exploring more villages, particularly because of multicolinearity problems from the Hindu village of Shahapara.

Hypothesis 3 states stronger social ties in treated groups encourages shouldering and discourages free riding compared to control groups. Empirically this is well-proven with treated groups 26.6 % more likely to shoulder and 27.4 % less likely to free ride compared to control groups holding all else constant. By extension, different observable characteristics affect the likelihood of shouldering or free riding differently. Findings of shouldering being sensitive to physical and relational characteristics and free riding to individuals’ situation are suggested.

The story for lenders, when selecting optimal borrowers in joint-liability, is to choose predominantly women that are blood relatives and neighbours. To maximise repayments, lenders must select those educated below Class 7 and in niche forms of employment so they benefit from stronger work-community social ties. Homogenous groups in sex, education and occupation should be formed. Optimum values based on income and village are uncertain because of exogenously setting income outside of the loss domain and inability to identify cultural differences between villages respectively.

The contemporary game theoretical application to joint-liability microcredit lending is novel. There remains expansive scope for future literature. Extensions to this paper include but are not limited to allowing observation of group incomes to a degree of certainty to better replicate signals of repayment ability,Footnote 41 and finding proxy variables to measure unobservable behavioural characteristics which limit all empirical research in microcredit.Footnote 42 Alternative application of the experimental games can be made to test social ties in solving moral hazard by setting income endogenously or in solving adverse selection by comparing microcredit borrowers to those only deterred by high interest rates. Experimental games can also be adapted to model comparisons between joint-liability and other lending models such as individual-liability.

The paper finds significant evidence supporting theoretical hypotheses in joint-liability microcredit lending. Nevertheless whether joint-liability is the optimal lending model for alleviating world poverty remains undetermined.Footnote 43