Skip to main content
Log in

Accounting quality, debt covenant design, and the cost of debt

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine whether debt covenant design (threshold tightness, covenants frequency, covenant interdependence, and overall covenant strictness) reduces the adverse effect of poor accounting quality on the cost of debt in the private lending market. We predict and find that when borrowing firms exhibit low accounting quality, lenders tend to increase debt contract strictness through debt covenant design (e.g., increasing the number of covenants, decreasing covenant interdependence or including covenants with greater threshold tightness). Moreover, our results indicate that the cost of debt for borrowers with low accounting quality is significantly influenced by the covenant strictness. Further evidence shows that, although debt covenant designs help mitigate adverse information risk, financial reporting quality is more important than strict debt covenants in lowering the cost of debt, a matter of concern for firm managers and lenders.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Issuing corporate bonds and borrowing from the bank are the two most important ways a firm receives debt financing. The public bond market is less liquid than the equity market while banks rely heavily on private information when making lending decisions (Diamond 1991; Ericsson and Renault 2006; Bharath et al. 2011; Liu and Magnan 2014). This largely limits the role of public accounting information in the debt market.

  2. We focus on the private loan market first because public debt represents only 17 % of the outstanding debt (Houston and James 1996) and private debt makes up 80 % of corporate debt for their sample of large Compustat firms (Dichev and Skinner 2002). Moreover, the contract information in loan contracting, such as information of covenants and other contractual terms, etc., are richer than that in the public bond market (Arena 2011; Bharath et al. 2011), which facilitates our study.

  3. Debt covenants serve as important “trip wires” that can lead to significant shifts in creditor control rights and bargaining power. For example, upon violation of covenants, control rights are transferred to lenders, granting them the opportunity to intervene in the firm’s investment and financing decisions (Chava and Roberts 2008).

  4. Using different measures of information quality, such as disclosure score or earnings quality, these studies document that higher information quality is associated with lower cost of debt.

  5. As Murfin (2012) argues, “stricter” contracts are those that provide the lender contingent control in more states of the world by making trip wires more sensitive.

  6. For example, an agreement that contains maximum and maximum leverage ratio implicitly imposes a variable limit on the minimum net worth covenant. Therefore a loan contract with a debt to EBITDA covenant and a leverage ratio covenant is unlikely to be made markedly stricter by the addition of a net worth covenant due to the high correlation between the last covenant variable and the previous two covenant variables.

  7. AIS is reported in Loan Pricing Corporation’s DealScan database. It is measured as a mark-up over LIBOR and is paid by the borrower on all drawn lines of credit. It consists of the upfront fee, the coupon spread, and the utilization fee as well as any recurring annual fees and is essentially the cost to the borrower for each dollar drawn down from the loan.

  8. Strict debt covenants could also limit the firm’s accounting flexibility because the firms need to maintain certain levels of accounting numbers on which the debt covenants are written to avoid costly covenant violations.

  9. For example, (2008) and Mansi et al. (2013) find that loan pricing is positively associated with the presence of financial covenants, while Bradley and Roberts (2004) provide both theoretical and empirical evidence that the usage of debt covenants may trade off the cost of debt.

  10. The trade-off or negative association is empirically captured by Bradley and Roberts (2004) who consider debt agreement and pricing simultaneously. Beatty et al. (2002) and Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman (2011) demonstrate the trade-off between debt covenants and the interest rate under certain conditions, such as involving accounting changes or weak internal control.

  11. DealScan reports information on 17 different financial covenants that fall into seven broad categories: cash flow, debt-to-cash flow, debt-to-balance sheet, coverage, liquidity, net worth, and capital expenditures. In this study, we select 12 covenants whose financial ratios are available in the Compustat quarterly file (see Appendix 2 for the covenants we use). We then delete those loan packages with covenants not included in these 12 types.

  12. We use the link table provided by Professor Michael Roberts to match the DealScan database with the Compustat database and I/B/E/S database.

  13. We calculate the facility amount as the weighted average of loan level amounts.

  14. We use Compustat quarterly file to obtain the initiation level of covenant variables at the firm’s quarter date prior and nearest to the contracting date which is usually 3 months prior to the deal active date.

  15. For example, the definition of leverage is not unique and could vary across borrower companies and the DealScan database that we use does not provide such detail information concerning the exact definition of covenant variables. Even if precise debt covenants could be obtained from the contracts, the detailed data required for their estimation is not available in publicly released financial statements. We thank Professor Murfin for these comments.

  16. See variable description of CovIntdep in “Appendix 1” and theoretical explanation for the definition of CovIntdep in “Appendix 3”.

  17. In investment banking, a lead arranger is an underwriting firm that leads a syndicate or group of underwriters responsible for placing a new issue of a security with investors.

  18. Table 1 Panel A reports the logarithm values of loan amount (in million), logarithm of maturity (in month), and borrowing firms’ market capitalization.

  19. Earnings volatility is negatively associated with earnings persistence. The close lender-borrower relationship established from repeat borrowing could facilitate lenders’ private information acquisition and hence lower the lenders’ demand for the borrowing firm’s financial reporting.

  20. In fact, there is no well accepted goodness of fit measure for GMM estimation.

  21. Bradley and Roberts (2004) also use a simultaneous equations approach and find a negative relation between the number of covenants and the interest rate.

  22. To obtain the relation between an−2 and the off-diagonal elements of correlation matrix, we expand the correlation matrix and match the coefficient of \(\lambda^{n - 2}\).

References

  • Aghion P, Bolton P (1992) An incomplete contracts approach to financial contracting. Rev Econ Stud 59(3):473–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altman EI (2000) Predicting financial distress of companies. New York University. In: Working paper

  • Anantharaman D, Fang V, Gong G (2014) Inside debt and the design of corporate debt contracts. Manag Sci 60(5):1260–1280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arena MP (2011) The corporate choice between public debt, bank loans, traditional private debt placements, and 144A debt issues. Rev Quant Finance Acc 36(3):391–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong CS, Guay WR, Weber JP (2010) The role of information and financial reporting in corporate governance and debt contracting. J Acc Econ 50(2–3):179–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball R, Foster G (1982) Corporate financial reporting: a methodological review of empirical research. J Acc Res 20:161–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron R, Kenny D (1986) The moderator–mediator variables distinction in social psychology research: conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. J Pers Soc Psychol 51(6):1173–1182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty A, Weber J (2003) The effects of debt contracting on voluntary accounting method changes. Acc Rev 78(1):119–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty A, Ramesh K, Weber J (2002) The importance of accounting changes in debt contracts: the cost of flexibility in covenant calculations. J Acc Econ 33(2):205–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty A, Weber J, Yu JJ (2008) Conservatism and debt. J Acc Econ 45(2):154–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharath ST, Sunder J, Sunder SV (2008) Accounting quality and debt contracting. Acc Rev 83(1):1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharath ST, Dahiya S, Saunders A, Srinivasan A (2011) Lending relationships and loan contract terms. Rev Financ Stud 24(4):1141–1203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya N, Ecker F, Olsson PM, Schipper K (2012) Direct and mediated associations among earnings quality, information asymmetry, and the cost of equity. Acc Rev 87(2):449–482

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya N, Desai H, Venkataraman K (2013) Does earnings quality affect information asymmetry? evidence from trading costs. Contemp Acc Res 30(2):482–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billet MT, King T-HD, Mauer DC (2007) Growth opportunities and the choice of leverage, debt maturity and covenants. J Finance 62(2):697–730

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley M, Roberts MR (2004) The structure and pricing of corporate debt covenants. University of Chicago. In: Working paper

  • Cain CK, Kolev CS, McVay S (2014) Qualifying special items. Yale University. In: Working paper

  • Callen JL, Chen F, Dou Y, Xin B (2012) Information asymmetry and the debt contracting demand for accounting conservatism. University of Toronto. In: Working paper

  • Callen JL, Khan M, Lu H (2013) Accounting quality, stock price delay, and future stock returns. Contemp Acc Res 30(1):269–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chava S, Roberts MR (2008) How does financing impact investment? The role of debt covenants. J Finance 63(5):2085–2121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello AM, Wittenberg-Moerman R (2011) The impact of financial reporting quality on debt contracting: evidence from internal control weakness reports. J Acc Res 49(1):97–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crabtree AD, Maher JJ (2005) Earnings predictability, bond ratings, and bond yields. Rev Quant Finance Acc 25(3):233–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Dichev ID (2002) The quality of accruals and earnings: the role of accrual estimation errors. Acc Rev 77(1):35–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Ge W, Schrand C (2010) Understanding earnings quality: a review of the proxies, their determinants, and their consequences. J Acc Econ 50(2–3):344–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Ge W, Larson C, Sloan R (2011) Predicting material accounting misstatements. Contemp Acc Res 28(1):17–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeFond M, Park C (1997) Smoothing income in anticipation of future earnings. J Acc Econ 23:115–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demiroglu C, James CM (2010) The information content of bank loan covenants. Rev Financ Stud 23(10):3700–3731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denis DJ, Mihov VT (2003) The choice among bank debt, non-bank private debt, and public debt: evidence from new corporate borrowings. J Financ Econ 70(1):3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont M, Tirole J (1994) A theory of debt and equity: diversity of securities and manager-shareholder congruence. Q J Econ 109(4):1027–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW (1991) Monitoring and reputation: the choice between bank loans and directly placed debt. J Polit Econ 99(4):689–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dichev ID, Skinner DJ (2002) Large-sample evidence on the debt covenant hypothesis. J Acc Res 40(1):1091–1123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Douglas AVS, Huang AG, Vetzal KR (2014) Cash flow volatility and corporate bond yield spreads. Rev Quant Finan Acc. doi:10.1007/s11156-014-0474-0

    Google Scholar 

  • Doyle J, Ge W, McVay S (2007) Determinants of weaknesses in internal control over financial reporting. J Acc Econ 44(1–2):193–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ericsson J, Renault O (2006) Liquidity and credit risk. J Finance 61(5):2219–2250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1997) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43(2):153–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis J, LaFond R, Olsson P, Schipper K (2005) The market pricing of accruals quality. J Acc Econ 39(2):295–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis J, Nanda D, Olsson P (2008) Voluntary disclosure, earnings quality, and cost of capital. J Acc Res 46(1):53–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ge W, McVay S (2005) The disclosure of material weaknesses in internal control after the Sarbanes–Oxley Act. Acc Horiz 19:137–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberger AR (1991) A course in econometrics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2002) Econometric analysis. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillegeist SA, Keating EK, Cram DP, Lundstedt KG (2004) Assessing the probability of bankruptcy. Rev Acc Stud 9(1):5–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houston J, James C (1996) Bank information monopolies and the mix of private and public debt claims. J Finance 51(5):1863–1889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and capital structure. J Financ Econ 3(4):305–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson SA (2003) Debt maturity and the effects of growth opportunities and liquidity risk on leverage. Rev Financ Stud 16(1):209–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy P (2003) A guide to econometrics. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kothari SP, Leone A, Wasley C (2005) Performance matched discretionary accrual measures. J Acc Econ 39(1):163–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambert R, Leuz C, Verrecchia R (2007) Accounting information, disclosure and the cost of capital. J Acc Res 45(2):385–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambert R, Leuz C, Verrecchia R (2012) Information asymmetry, information precision, and the cost of capital. Rev Finance 16(1):1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee CF, Liang W, Lin F, Yang Y (2015) Applications of simultaneous equations in finance research: methods and empirical results. Rev Quant Finan Acc. doi:10.1007/s11156-015-0526-0

    Google Scholar 

  • Leftwich R (1983) Accounting information in private markets: evidence from private lending agreements. Acc Rev 58(1):23–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Leland HE (1998) Agency costs, risk management, and capital structure. J Finance 53(4):1213–1243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu M, Magnan M (2014) Conditional conservatism and the yield spread of corporate bond issues. Rev Quant Finan Acc. doi:10.1007/s11156-014-0489-6

    Google Scholar 

  • Livnat J, Mendenhall R (2006) Comparing the post-earnings announcement drift for surprises calculated from analyst and time series forecasts. J Acc Res 44(1):177–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansi SA, Qi Y, Wald JK (2013) Debt covenants, bankruptcy risks, and issuance costs. Virginia Tech University. In: Working paper

  • Maung M, Chowdhury R (2014) Credit rating changes and leverage adjustments: concurrent or continual? Rev Pac Basin Financ Markets Polic 17(4):1–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller DP, Reisel N (2012) Do country-level investor protections affect security-level contract design? evidence from foreign bond covenants. Rev Financ Stud 25(2):408–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murfin J (2012) The supply-side determinants of loan contract strictness. J Finance 67(5):1565–1601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers SC (1977) Determinants of corporate borrowing. J Financ Econ 5(1):147–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nikolaev VV (2010) Debt covenants and accounting conservatism. J Acc Res 48(1):51–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen MA (2009) Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: comparing approaches. Rev Financ Stud 22(1):435–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petroni K (1992) Optimistic reporting in the property-casualty insurance industry. J Acc Econ 15:485–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reisel N (2014) On the value of restrictive covenants: empirical investigation of public bond issues. J Corp Finance 27:251–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross S, Westerfield R, Jaffe J (2002) Corporate finance, 6th edn. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta P (1998) Corporate disclosure quality and the cost of debt. Acc Rev 73(4):459–475

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith C, Warner J (1979) On financial contracting: an analysis of bond covenants. J Financ Econ 7(2):117–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watts R, Zimmerman J (1986) Positive accounting theory. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J (2008) The contracting benefits of accounting conservatism to lenders and borrowers. J Acc Econ 45(1):27–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joseph H. Zhang.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 8.

Table 8 Variable descriptions

Appendix 2: Types of debt covenant restriction in loan contracts

The following table shows the type (in the first column) and distribution (in the second column) of covenants in our sample of loan packages. We take the loan package 100,472 (package ID) as an example to illustrate the debt covenant design. The lender of the loan is a syndicate group of banks. The loan amount was $25 million and would become mature in 12 months. The borrowing company of this loan contract is AAR Corporation, a company providing products and services to aviation, government, and defense markets worldwide. The loan contract is activated on Apr. 11, 2001 and includes four covenants (the number of covenants is above 80 % of the sample): Max. Leverage ratio covenant (the threshold is 0.6), Min. Current Ratio covenant (the threshold is 1.5), Min. Fixed Charge Coverage covenant (the threshold is 1.2), and Min. Tangible Net Worth covenant ($240 million). When the loan contract is activated, the company’s financial ratios or amounts are: leverage ratio is 0.3, current ratio is 2.7, fixed Charge Coverage is 1.4, and tangible net worth is about $341. The company was basically in a healthy financial condition as the loan was contracted. The company’s accruals quality (AQ) near the loan activated date (at the end of 2000 fiscal year) is 0.024, which is around the median of the sample; it’s earnings surprise (ES) is 0.058 and special items (SI) is 0.007, both of which are above 75 % of the sample. The covenant strictness (CovStrict) is 0.629, which is above the median of the sample; the covenant inter-dependence index (CovIntdep) of the loan is 0.453, which is below the median of the sample; among the four debt covenants, there is one debt covenant displaying covenant threshold tightness. As we can see, the borrowing company has relatively poor accounting quality and hence the loan contract was fairly strict.

Type of covenants

Numbers/percentages of packages that contain the covenant

Covenants for financial ratio

 Max. Debt to EBITDA

4843 (47.50 %)

 Min. Fixed Charge Coverage

3417 (33.51 %)

 Min. Interest Coverage

3413 (33.47 %)

 Max. Leverage ratio

1796 (17.61 %)

 Min. Current Ratio

1044 (10.24 %)

 Max. Debt to Tangible Net Worth

989 (9.70 %)

 Min. Quick Ratio

293 (2.87 %)

 Max. Debt to Equity

71 (0.70 %)

Covenants for financial amount

 

 Max. Capex

2109 (20.68 %)

 Min. Total Net Worth

1936 (18.99 %)

 Min. Tangible Net Worth

1901 (18.65 %)

 Min. EBITDA

714 (7.00 %)

Appendix 3: Theoretical explanation of debt covenant interdependence

For the following correlation matrix for n debt covenants in a loan package

$$\varSigma_{n} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 & {\rho_{12} } & \cdots & {\rho_{1n} } \\ {\rho_{21} } & 1 & {} & \vdots \\ \vdots & {} & \ddots & {} \\ {\rho_{n1} } & \cdots & {} & 1 \\ \end{array} } \right]$$
(6)

where \(0 \le \rho_{ij} = \rho_{ji} \le 1,(i,j = 1, \cdots ,n)\). Let \(\lambda_{1} ,\lambda_{2} , \ldots ,\lambda_{n}\) be the n eigenvalues of the correlation matrix \(\sum_{n}\). When all the covenants are mutually independent, the off-diagonal elements, \(\rho_{ij} ,(i \ne j)\), of \(\sum_{n}\) become zero. Then all n eigenvalues equal to 1.0. However, when the covenants are inter-dependent, the nonzero \(\rho_{ij} ,(i \ne j)\) make the eigenvalues different from each other. Take two dimension correlation matrix \(\sum_{2} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 & \rho \\ \rho & 1 \\ \end{array} } \right]\) as an example. We compute the eigenvalues of \(\sum_{2}\) for \(\rho =\) 0, 0.5, and 1.0 respectively. When \(\rho = 0\), both the eigenvalues are equal to 1.0; when \(\rho = 0.5\), the eigenvalues are 1.5 and 0.5; when \(\rho = 1.0\), the eigenvalues are 2.0 and 0. As we can see, when correlation \(\rho\) increases, the difference between the eigenvalues increases. Thus it is the correlation that makes the eigenvalues heterogeneous. The more heterogeneous the eigenvalues, the high the inter-dependence among covenants.

We hence define CovIntdep as the standard deviation of the n eigenvalues

$$CovIntdep = Std(\hat{\lambda }) = \sqrt {Var(\hat{\lambda })}$$
(7)

where \(\hat{\lambda } = [\lambda_{1} ,\lambda_{2} , \ldots ,\lambda_{n} ]\) and \(Var(\hat{\lambda })\) is

$$\text{var} (\hat{\lambda }) = \frac{1}{n - 1}\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {(\lambda_{i} - \bar{\lambda })^{2} } = \frac{1}{n - 1}\left( {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {\lambda_{i}^{2} } - 2\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {\lambda_{i} \bar{\lambda }} + n\bar{\lambda }^{2} } \right)$$
(8)

where \(\bar{\lambda } = \frac{1}{n}\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} {\lambda_{i} }\). Since \(\lambda_{1} ,\lambda_{2} , \cdots ,\lambda_{n}\) are the n eigenvalues of \(\sum_{n}\), they are the roots of the following characteristic polynomial of \(\sum_{n}\)

$$\lambda (\sum_{n} ) = \left| {\lambda I - \sum_{n} } \right| = \left| {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\lambda - 1} & { - \rho_{12} } & \cdots & { - \rho_{1n} } \\ { - \rho_{21} } & {\lambda - 1} & {} & \vdots \\ \vdots & {} & \ddots & {} \\ { - \rho_{n1} } & \cdots & {} & {\lambda - 1} \\ \end{array} } \right| = \lambda^{n} - n\lambda^{n - 1} + a_{n - 2} \lambda^{n - 2} + \cdots + a_{1} \lambda + a_{0}$$
(9)

According to the relationship between the roots and the coefficients of a polynomial, we have \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} {\lambda_{i} } = n\) and \(\sum\limits_{i < j} {\lambda_{i} \lambda_{j} } = a_{n - 2}\). Therefore Eq. (8) can be simplified and expressed in terms of the coefficients of polynomial in the following Eq. (10).Footnote 22

$$\begin{aligned} \text{var} (\hat{\lambda }) & = \frac{1}{n - 1}\left( {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {\lambda_{i}^{2} } - n} \right) = \frac{1}{n - 1}\left[ {\left( {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {\lambda_{i} } } \right)^{2} - 2\sum\limits_{i < j} {\lambda_{i} \lambda_{j} } - n} \right] \\ & = \frac{1}{n - 1}\left( {n^{2} - 2a_{n - 2} - n} \right) = n - \frac{{2a_{n - 2} }}{n - 1} = \frac{{\sum\limits_{i \ne j} {\rho_{ij}^{2} } }}{n - 1} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Therefore our measure

$$CovIntdep = \sqrt {\text{var} (\hat{\lambda })} = \sqrt {\frac{{\sum\limits_{i \ne j} {\rho_{ij}^{2} } }}{n - 1}}$$
(11)

captures the correlations, i.e., \(\rho_{ij} ,(i \ne j)\) between every two debt covenants included in the loan package.

For a 2-D correlation matrix \(\sum_{2} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 & \rho \\ \rho & 1 \\ \end{array} } \right]\), we can calculate CovIntdep 2 from equation C(6),

$$CovIntdep_{2} = \sqrt {\frac{{\sum\limits_{i \ne j} {\rho_{ij}^{2} } }}{n - 1}} = \sqrt {\frac{{2\rho^{2} }}{2 - 1}} = \sqrt 2 \left| \rho \right|$$
(12)

and obviously, CovIntdep 2 increases as the correlation (the absolute value) of the two debt covenants increases.

Similarly we can calculate our measure for 3-D correlation matrix from Eq. (10) in terms of three unique off-diagonal elements, i.e., \(\rho_{12} ,\,\rho_{23} ,\) and \(\rho_{23}\)

$$CovIntdep_{3} = \sqrt {\frac{{\sum\limits_{i \ne j} {\rho_{ij}^{2} } }}{n - 1}} = \sqrt {\frac{{2(\rho_{12}^{2} + \rho_{13}^{2} + \rho_{23}^{2} )}}{3 - 1}} = \sqrt {\rho_{12}^{2} + \rho_{13}^{2} + \rho_{23}^{2} }$$

One concern of our measure is that it is more likely to have inter-dependent debt covenants as the number of debt covenants increases, weakening the results. However, this is not a concern since, in our sample, about 80 % of the loan packages have fewer than 4 debt covenants and 95 % of the loan packages have fewer than 5 debt covenants.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Spiceland, C.P., Yang, L.L. & Zhang, J.H. Accounting quality, debt covenant design, and the cost of debt. Rev Quant Finan Acc 47, 1271–1302 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-015-0538-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-015-0538-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation